Monday, August 3, 2020


Contraction of United States GDP at 32.9 Percent SAAR in First Quarter 2020 in the Global Recession, with Output in the US Reaching a High in Feb 2020 (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html), in the Lockdown of Economic Activity in the COVID-19 Event, Mediocre Cyclical United States Growth in the Lost Economic Cycle of the Global Recession with Economic Growth Underperforming Below Trend Worldwide, Contraction of Real Private Fixed Investment at 29.9 Percent SAAR, United States Terms of Trade, Beginning Recovery in United States New House Sales, United States House Prices, World Cyclical Slow Growth, and Government Intervention in Globalization: Part II Charts

Carlos M. Pelaez

© Carlos M. Pelaez, 2009, 2010, 2011, 2012, 2013, 2014, 2015, 2016, 2017, 2018, 2019, 2020.

IA Mediocre Cyclical United States Economic Growth
            IA1 Stagnating Real Private Fixed Investment
IID United States Terms of International Trade
IIA United States Housing Collapse
            IIA1 Sales of New Houses
            IIA2 United States House Prices
III World Financial Turbulence
IV Global Inflation
V World Economic Slowdown
VA United States
VB Japan
VC China
VD Euro Area
VE Germany
VF France
VG Italy
VH United Kingdom
VI Valuation of Risk Financial Assets
VII Economic Indicators
VIII Interest Rates
IX Conclusion
References
Appendixes
Appendix I The Great Inflation
IIIB Appendix on Safe Haven Currencies
IIIC Appendix on Fiscal Compact
IIID Appendix on European Central Bank Large Scale Lender of Last Resort
IIIG Appendix on Deficit Financing of Growth and the Debt Crisis

IA1 Stagnating Real Private Fixed Investment. Table IA1-1 provides quarterly seasonally adjusted annual rates (SAAR) of growth of private fixed investment for the recessions of the 1980s and the current economic cycle. In the cyclical expansion beginning in IQ1983 (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html), real private fixed investment in the United States grew at the average annual rate of 14.7 percent in the first eight quarters from IQ1983 to IVQ1984. Growth rates fell to an average of 2.2 percent in the following eight quarters from IQ1985 to IVQ1986 and to an average of 1.9 percent in the 12 quarters of 1985, 1986 and 1987. The average rate of growth in the four quarters of 1988 was 3.7 percent. There were only four quarters of contraction of private fixed investment from IQ1983 to IVQ1987. The National Bureau of Economic Research dates another cycle from Jul 1990 (IIIQ1981) to Mar 1991 (IQ1991) (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html), showing in Table III-1 with contractions of fixed investment in the final three quarters of 1990 and the first quarter of 1991. There is quite different behavior of private fixed investment in the thirty-six quarters of cyclical expansion from IIIQ2009 to IIQ2018. The average annual growth rate in the first eight quarters of expansion from IIIQ2009 to IIQ2011 was 4.6 percent, which is significantly lower than 14.7 percent in the first eight quarters of expansion from IQ1983 to IVQ1984. There is only robust growth of private fixed investment in the four quarters of expansion from IIQ2011 to IQ2012 at the average annual rate of 12.8 percent. Growth has fallen from the SAAR of 17.9 percent in IIIQ2011 to 0.6 percent in IIIQ2012, recovering to 7.4 percent in IVQ2012 and increasing to 7.0 percent in IQ2013. The SAAR of fixed investment fell to 7.1 percent in IIIQ2013 and to 5.5 percent in IVQ2013. The SAAR of fixed investment decreased to 4.1 percent in IQ2014. Fixed investment grew at the SAAR of 11.6 percent in IIQ2014 and at 7.9 percent in IIIQ2014. Fixed investment grew at 4.7 percent in IVQ2014, 1.1 percent in IQ2015 and 3.5 percent in IIQ2015. Fixed investment grew at 3.4 percent in IIIQ2015 and fell at 1.1 percent in IVQ2015. Fixed investment increased at 2.0 percent in IQ2016 and increased at 1.5 percent in IIQ2016. Fixed investment increased at 3.2 percent in IIIQ2016 and increased at 2.7 percent in IVQ2016. Fixed investment increased at 7.1 percent in IQ2017 and increased at 1.6 percent in IIQ2017. Fixed investment grew at 1.2 percent in IIIQ2017. Fixed investment grew at 9.5 percent in IVQ2017 and increased at 8.5 percent in IQ2018. Fixed investment grew at 4.4 percent in IIQ2018. Fixed investment increased at 0.8 percent in IIIQ2018 and increased at 2.6 percent in IVQ2018. Fixed investment increased at 2.9 percent in IQ2019 and decreased at 0.4 percent in IIQ2019. Fixed investment decreased at 2.4 percent in IIIQ2019. Fixed investment increased at 1.0 percent in IVQ2019. Fixed investment decreased at 1.4 percent in IQ2020 and decreased at 29.9 percent in IIQ2020 in the global recession, with output in the US reaching a high in Feb 2020 (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html), in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event. Sudeep Reddy and Scott Thurm, writing on “Investment falls off a cliff,” on Nov 18, 2012, published in the Wall Street Journal (http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424127887324595904578123593211825394.html?mod=WSJPRO_hpp_LEFTTopStories) analyze the decline of private investment in the US and inform that a review by the Wall Street Journal of filing and conference calls finds that 40 of the largest publicly traded corporations in the US have announced intentions to reduce capital expenditures in 2012.
Table IA1-1, US, Quarterly Growth Rates of Real Private Fixed Investment, % Annual Equivalent SA
Q
1981
1982
1983
1984
2008
2009
2010
I
3.8
-10.6
9.3
13.2
-6.1
-28.2
-0.2
II
3.2
-12.0
15.9
16.6
-3.2
-13.7
15.4
III
0.2
-9.2
24.4
8.2
-9.7
1.5
2.2
IV
-1.3
0.2
24.3
7.4
-23.9
2.0
7.8




1985


2011
I



3.7


-0.7
II



5.2


9.7
III



-1.6


17.9
IV



7.8


10.6




1986


2012
I



1.1


13.1
II



0.1


8.3
III



-1.8


0.6
IV



3.1


7.4




1987


2013
I



-6.7


7.0
II



6.3


3.3
III



7.1


7.1
IV



-0.2


5.5




1988


2014 
I



0.2


 4.1
II



8.1


 11.6
III



1.9


 7.9
IV



4.8


 4.7




1989


2015
IQ



3.6


1.1
IIQ



0.5


3.5
IIIQ



7.2


3.4
IVQ



-5.1


-1.1




1990


2016
IQ



4.8


2.0
IIQ



-7.7


1.5
IIIQ



-3.2


3.2
IVQ



-9.9


2.7




1991


2017
I



-10.6


7.1
II



1.2


1.6
III



0.5


1.2
IV



1.7


9.5




1992


2018
I



4.5


8.5
II



13.8


4.4
III



4.7


0.8
IV



12.2


2.6
1993






2019
I



3.0


2.9
II



7.4


-0.4
III



6.4


2.4
IV



17.1


1.0
1994






2020
I



4.8


-1.4
II



8.3


-29.9
III



3.3



IV



10.0



Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis https://apps.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm
Chart IA1-1 of the US Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) provides seasonally adjusted annual rates of growth of real private fixed investment from 1980 to 1993. Growth rates recovered sharply during the first eight quarters, which was essential in returning the economy to trend growth and eliminating unemployment and most underemployment accumulated during the contractions. The National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) dates a contraction of the US from IQ1990 (Jul) to IQ1991 (Mar) (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html). The expansion lasted until another contraction beginning in IQ2001 (Mar). US GDP contracted 1.3 percent from the pre-recession peak of $8983.9 billion of chained 2009 dollars in IIIQ1990 to the trough of $8865.6 billion in IQ1991 (https://apps.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm).
Chart IA1-1, US, Real Private Fixed Investment, Seasonally Adjusted Annual Rates Percent Change from Prior Quarter, 1980-1993
Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis
Weak behavior of real private fixed investment from 2007 to 2020 is in Chart IA1-2. Growth rates of real private fixed investment were much lower during the initial phase of the current economic cycle, entered sharp trend of decline and recovered recently, with another decline followed by increase and renewed decline. Fixed investment contracted sharply, at 1.4 percent in IQ2020 and at 29.9 percent in IIQ2020. There is a downward effect in the global recession, with output in the US reaching a high in Feb 2020 (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html), in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event.
Chart IA1-2, US, Real Private Fixed Investment, Seasonally Adjusted Annual Rates Percent Change from Prior Quarter, 2007-2020
Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis
Table IA1-2 provides real private fixed investment at seasonally adjusted annual rates from IVQ2007 to IIQ2020 or for the complete economic cycle. The first column provides the quarter, the second column percentage change relative to IVQ2007, the third column the quarter percentage change in the quarter relative to the prior quarter and the final column percentage change in a quarter relative to the same quarter a year earlier. In IQ1980, real gross private domestic investment in the US was $933.1 billion of chained 2012 dollars, growing to $1,372.1 billion in IVQ1993 or 47.0 percent. The National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) dates a contraction of the US from IQ1990 (Jul) to IQ1991 (Mar) (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html). The expansion lasted until another contraction beginning in IQ2001 (Mar). US GDP contracted 1.3 percent from the pre-recession peak of $8983.9 billion of chained 2009 dollars in IIIQ1990 to the trough of $8865.6 billion in IQ1991 (https://apps.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm). Real gross private domestic investment in the US increased 6.2 percent from $2,653.1 billion in IVQ2007 to $2,817.7 billion in IIQ2020. Real private fixed investment increased 17.4 percent from $2,630.0 billion of chained 2012 dollars in IVQ2007 to $3,088.6 billion in IQ2020. Real gross private domestic investment fell at SAAR 49.0 percent in IIQ2020, and private fixed investment fell at SAAR 29.9 percent in the global recession, with output in the US reaching a high in Feb 2020 (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html), in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event. Private fixed investment fell relative to IVQ2007 in all quarters preceding IVQ2012 and increased 0.8 percent in IIIQ2016, increasing 0.4 percent in IIQ2016 and increasing 0.5 percent in IQ2016. Private fixed investment increased 0.7 percent in IVQ2016. Private fixed investment increased 1.7 percent in IQ2017 and increased 0.4 percent in IIQ2017. Private fixed investment increased 0.3 percent in IIIQ2017 and increased 2.3 percent in IVQ2017. Private fixed investment increased 2.1 percent in IQ2018, increasing 1.1 percent in IIQ2018. Private fixed investment increased 0.2 percent in IIIQ2018, increasing 0.7 percent in IVQ2018. Private fixed investment increased 0.7 percent in IQ2019, decreasing 0.1 percent in IIQ2019. Private fixed investment increased 0.6 percent in IIIQ2019. Private fixed investment increased 0.2 percent in IVQ2019. Private fixed investment decreased 0.3 percent in IQ2020. Private fixed investment decreased 8.5 percent in IIQ2020. Growth of real private investment in Table IA1-2 is mediocre for all but four quarters from IIQ2011 to IQ2012. There is recent robust growth followed by sharp contraction in the global recession, with output in the US reaching a high in Feb 2020 (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html), in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event. The investment decision of United States corporations is fractured in the current economic cycle in preference of cash.
Table IA1-2, US, Real Private Fixed Investment and Percentage Change Relative to IVQ2007 and Prior Quarter, Billions of Chained 2012 Dollars and ∆%

Real PFI, Billions Chained 2012
 Dollars
∆% Relative to IVQ2007
∆% Relative to Prior Quarter
∆%
over
Year Earlier
IVQ2007
2630.0
NA
-1.0
-1.1
IQ2008
2589.1
-1.6
-1.6
-2.6
IIQ2008
2567.9
-2.4
-0.8
-3.8
IIIQ2008
2503.0
-4.8
-2.5
-5.7
IV2008
2337.8
-11.1
-6.6
-11.1
IQ2009
2151.9
-18.2
-8.0
-16.9
IIQ2009
2073.9
-21.1
-3.6
-19.2
IIIQ2009
2081.6
-20.9
0.4
-16.8
IVQ2009
2092.0
-20.5
0.5
-10.5
IQ2010
2091.0
-20.5
0.0
-2.8
IIQ2010
2167.1
-17.6
3.6
4.5
IIIQ2010
2178.7
-17.2
0.5
4.7
IVQ2010
2220.0
-15.6
1.9
6.1
IQ2011
2216.2
-15.7
-0.2
6.0
IIQ2011
2268.0
-13.8
2.3
4.7
IIIQ2011
2363.3
-10.1
4.2
8.5
IVQ2011
2423.7
-7.8
2.6
9.2
IQ2012
2499.4
-5.0
3.1
12.8
IIQ2012
2549.8
-3.0
2.0
12.4
IIIQ2012
2553.6
-2.9
0.1
8.1
IVQ2012
2599.4
-1.2
1.8
7.2
IQ2013
2643.9
0.5
1.7
5.8
IIQ2013
2665.3
1.3
0.8
4.5
IIIQ2013
2711.3
3.1
1.7
6.2
IVQ2013
2748.0
4.5
1.4
5.7
IQ2014
2775.6
5.5
1.0
5.0
IIQ2014
2852.8
8.5
2.8
7.0
IIIQ2014
2907.3
10.5
1.9
7.2
IVQ2014
2941.2
11.8
1.2
7.0
IQ2015
2949.5
12.1
0.3
6.3
IIQ2015
2974.9
13.1
0.9
4.3
IIIQ2015
2999.8
14.1
0.8
3.2
IVQ2015
2991.8
13.8
-0.3
1.7
IQ2016
3006.8
14.8
0.5
1.9
IIQ2016
3018.0
14.8
0.4
1.4
IIIQ2016
3041.8
15.7
0.8
1.4
IVQ2016
3062.2
16.4
0.7
2.4
IQ2017
3115.5
18.5
1.7
3.6
IIQ2017
3127.7
18.9
0.4
3.6
IIIQ2017
3137.1
19.3
0.3
3.1
IVQ2017
3209.2
22.0
2.3
4.8
IQ2018
3275.2
24.5
2.1
5.1
IIQ2018
3310.6
25.9
1.1
5.8
IIIQ2018
3317.0
26.1
0.2
5.7
IVQ2018
3338.7
26.9
0.7
4.0
IQ2019
3362.3
27.8
0.7
2.7
IIQ2019
3358.6
27.7
-0.1
1.4
IIIQ2019
3378.9
28.5
0.6
1.9
IVQ2019
3387.2
28.8
0.2
1.5
IQ2020
3375.4
28.3
-0.3
0.4
IIQ2020
3088.6
17.4
-8.5
-8.0
PFI: Private Fixed Investment
Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis https://apps.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm
Chart IA1-3 provides real private fixed investment in chained dollars of 2009 from 2007 to 2020. Real private fixed investment increased 17.4 percent from $2,630.0 billion of chained 2012 dollars in IVQ2007 to $3,088.6 billion in IIQ2020. Real private fixed investment decreased at SAAR 29.9 percent in IIQ2020 after decreasing at SAAR 1.4 percent in IQ2020.
Chart IA1-3, US, Real Private Fixed Investment, Billions of Chained 2009 Dollars, 2007 to 2020
Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis
Chart IA1-4 provides real gross private domestic investment in chained dollars of 2012 from 1980 to 1993. Real gross private domestic investment climbed 47.0 percent to $1,372.1 billion of 2012 dollars in IIIQ1993 above the level of $933.1 billion in IQ1980. The National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) dates a contraction of the US from IQ1990 (Jul) to IQ1991 (Mar) (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html). The expansion lasted until another contraction beginning in IQ2001 (Mar). US GDP contracted 1.3 percent from the pre-recession peak of $8983.9 billion of chained 2009 dollars in IIIQ1990 to the trough of $8865.6 billion in IQ1991 (https://apps.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm).
Chart IA1-4, US, Real Gross Private Domestic Investment, Billions of Chained 2009 Dollars at Seasonally Adjusted Annual Rate, 1980-1993
Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis
Chart IA1-5 provides real gross private domestic investment in the United States in billions of chained dollars of 2012 from 2007 to 2020. Real gross private domestic investment reached a level of $2,817.7 billion in IIQ2020, which was 6.2 percent higher than the level of $2,653.1 billion in IVQ2007 (https://apps.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm).
Chart IA1-5, US, Real Gross Private Domestic Investment, Billions of Chained 2009 Dollars at Seasonally Adjusted Annual Rate, 2007-2020
Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis https://apps.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm
Table IA1-3 shows that the share of gross private domestic investment in GDP has decreased from 20.3 percent in IIQ2000 and 19.7 percent in IIQ2006 to 16.0 percent in IIQ2020. There are declines in percentage shares in GDP of all components with sharp reduction of residential investment from 4.7 percent in IIQ2000 and 6.2 percent in IIQ2006 to 4.0 percent in IIQ2020. The share of fixed investment in GDP fell from 19.4 percent in IIQ2000 and 19.2 percent in IIQ2006 to 17.6 percent in IIQ2020.
Table IA1-3, Percentage Shares of Gross Private Domestic Investment and Components in Gross Domestic Product, % of GDP

IIQ2020
IIQ2006
IIQ2000
Gross Private Domestic Investment
16.0
19.7
20.3
  Fixed Investment
17.6
19.2
19.4
     Nonresidential
13.6
12.9
14.6
          Structures
3.0
3.1
3.1
          Equipment
          and Software
5.4
6.2
7.6
          Intellectual
           Property
5.2
3.6
4.0
     Residential
4.0
6.2
4.7
   Change in Private Inventories
-1.7
0.5
0.9
Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis https://apps.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm
Finer detail is provided by the quarterly share of residential investment in GDP from 1979 to 2020 in Chart IA1-11. There was protracted growth of that share, accelerating sharply into 2006 followed with nearly vertical drop. The explanation of the sharp contraction of United States housing can probably be found in the origins of the financial crisis and global recession. Let V(T) represent the value of the firm’s equity at time T and B stand for the promised debt of the firm to bondholders and assume that corporate management, elected by equity owners, is acting on the
interests of equity owners. Robert C. Merton (1974, 453) states:
“On the maturity date T, the firm must either pay the promised payment of B to the debtholders or else the current equity will be valueless. Clearly, if at time T, V(T) > B, the firm should pay the bondholders because the value of equity will be V(T) – B > 0 whereas if they do not, the value of equity would be zero. If V(T) ≤ B, then the firm will not make the payment and default the firm to the bondholders because otherwise the equity holders would have to pay in additional money and the (formal) value of equity prior to such payments would be (V(T)- B) < 0.”
Pelaez and Pelaez (The Global Recession Risk (2007), 208-9) apply this analysis to the US housing market in 2005-2006 concluding:
“The house market [in 2006] is probably operating with low historical levels of individual equity. There is an application of structural models [Duffie and Singleton 2003] to the individual decisions on whether or not to continue paying a mortgage. The costs of sale would include realtor and legal fees. There could be a point where the expected net sale value of the real estate may be just lower than the value of the mortgage. At that point, there would be an incentive to default. The default vulnerability of securitization is unknown.”
There are multiple important determinants of the interest rate: “aggregate wealth, the distribution of wealth among investors, expected rate of return on physical investment, taxes, government policy and inflation” (Ingersoll 1987, 405). Aggregate wealth is a major driver of interest rates (Ingersoll 1987, 406). Unconventional monetary policy, with zero fed funds rates and flattening of long-term yields by quantitative easing, causes uncontrollable effects on risk taking that can have profound undesirable effects on financial stability. Excessively aggressive and exotic monetary policy is the main culprit and not the inadequacy of financial management and risk controls.
The net worth of the economy depends on interest rates. In theory, “income is generally defined as the amount a consumer unit could consume (or believe that it could) while maintaining its wealth intact” (Friedman 1957, 10). Income, Y, is a flow that is obtained by applying a rate of return, r, to a stock of wealth, W, or Y = rW (Ibid). According to a subsequent restatement: “The basic idea is simply that individuals live for many years and that therefore the appropriate constraint for consumption decisions is the long-run expected yield from wealth r*W. This yield was named permanent income: Y* = r*W” (Darby 1974, 229), where * denotes permanent. The simplified relation of income and wealth can be restated as:
W = Y/r (1)
Equation (1) shows that as r goes to zero, r →0, W grows without bound, W→∞.
Lowering the interest rate near the zero bound in 2003-2004 caused the illusion of permanent increases in wealth or net worth in the balance sheets of borrowers and also of lending institutions, securitized banking and every financial institution and investor in the world. The discipline of calculating risks and returns was seriously impaired. The objective of monetary policy was to encourage borrowing, consumption and investment but the exaggerated stimulus resulted in a financial crisis of major proportions as the securitization that had worked for a long period was shocked with policy-induced excessive risk, imprudent credit, high leverage and low liquidity by the incentive to finance everything overnight at close to zero interest rates, from adjustable rate mortgages (ARMS) to asset-backed commercial paper of structured investment vehicles (SIV).
The consequences of inflating liquidity and net worth of borrowers were a global hunt for yields to protect own investments and money under management from the zero interest rates and unattractive long-term yields of Treasuries and other securities. Monetary policy distorted the calculations of risks and returns by households, business and government by providing central bank cheap money. Short-term zero interest rates encourage financing of everything with short-dated funds, explaining the SIVs created off-balance sheet to issue short-term commercial paper to purchase default-prone mortgages that were financed in overnight or short-dated sale and repurchase agreements (Pelaez and Pelaez, Financial Regulation after the Global Recession, 50-1, Regulation of Banks and Finance, 59-60, Globalization and the State Vol. I, 89-92, Globalization and the State Vol. II, 198-9, Government Intervention in Globalization, 62-3, International Financial Architecture, 144-9). ARMS were created to lower monthly mortgage payments by benefitting from lower short-dated reference rates. Financial institutions economized in liquidity that was penalized with near zero interest rates. There was no perception of risk because the monetary authority guaranteed a minimum or floor price of all assets by maintaining low interest rates forever or equivalent to writing an illusory put option on wealth. Subprime mortgages were part of the put on wealth by an illusory put on house prices. The housing subsidy of $221 billion per year created the impression of ever increasing house prices. The suspension of auctions of 30-year Treasuries was designed to increase demand for mortgage-backed securities, lowering their yield, which was equivalent to lowering the costs of housing finance and refinancing. Fannie and Freddie purchased or guaranteed $1.6 trillion of nonprime mortgages and worked with leverage of 75:1 under Congress-provided charters and lax oversight. The combination of these policies resulted in high risks because of the put option on wealth by near zero interest rates, excessive leverage because of cheap rates, low liquidity because of the penalty in the form of low interest rates and unsound credit decisions because the put option on wealth by monetary policy created the illusion that nothing could ever go wrong, causing the credit/dollar crisis and global recession (Pelaez and Pelaez, Financial Regulation after the Global Recession, 157-66, Regulation of Banks, and Finance, 217-27, International Financial Architecture, 15-18, The Global Recession Risk, 221-5, Globalization and the State Vol. II, 197-213, Government Intervention in Globalization, 182-4).
Chart IA1-11, US, Percentage Share of Residential Investment in Gross Domestic Product, Quarterly, 1979-2020
Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis
Chart IA1-13 provides the percentage share of intellectual property investment in GDP on a quarterly basis from 1979 to 2019.
Chart IA1-13, US, Percentage Share of Intellectual Property Investment in Gross Domestic Product, Quarterly, 1979-2020
Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis
© Carlos M. Pelaez, 2009, 2010, 2011, 2012, 2013, 2014, 2015, 2016, 2017, 2018, 2019, 2020.

No comments:

Post a Comment