Sunday, June 7, 2015

Higher Volatility of Asset Prices at Zero Interest Rates, Twenty Five Million Unemployed or Underemployed, Stagnating Real Wages, Rules, Discretionary Authorities and Slow Productivity Growth, Stagnating Real Disposable Income, United States International Trade, World Cyclical Slow Growth and Global Recession Risk: Part II

 

Higher Volatility of Asset Prices at Zero Interest Rates, Twenty Five Million Unemployed or Underemployed, Stagnating Real Wages, Rules, Discretionary Authorities and Slow Productivity Growth, Stagnating Real Disposable Income, United States International Trade, World Cyclical Slow Growth and Global Recession Risk

Carlos M. Pelaez

© Carlos M. Pelaez, 2009, 2010, 2011, 2012, 2013, 2014, 2015

I Twenty Five Million Unemployed or Underemployed

IA1 Summary of the Employment Situation

IA2 Number of People in Job Stress

IA3 Long-term and Cyclical Comparison of Employment

IA4 Job Creation

IB Stagnating Real Wages

II Stagnating Real Disposable Income and Consumption Expenditures

IB1 Stagnating Real Disposable Income and Consumption Expenditures

IB2 Financial Repression

IIA Rules, Discretionary Authorities and Slow Productivity Growth

IIB United States International Trade

IV Global Inflation

V World Economic Slowdown

VA United States

VB Japan

VC China

VD Euro Area

VE Germany

VF France

VG Italy

VH United Kingdom

VI Valuation of Risk Financial Assets

VII Economic Indicators

VIII Interest Rates

IX Conclusion

References

Appendixes

Appendix I The Great Inflation

IIIB Appendix on Safe Haven Currencies

IIIC Appendix on Fiscal Compact

IIID Appendix on European Central Bank Large Scale Lender of Last Resort

IIIG Appendix on Deficit Financing of Growth and the Debt Crisis

IIIGA Monetary Policy with Deficit Financing of Economic Growth

IIIGB Adjustment during the Debt Crisis of the 1980s

I Twenty Five Million Unemployed or Underemployed. This section analyzes the employment situation report of the United States of the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS). There are four subsections: IA1 Summary of the Employment Situation; IA2 Number of People in Job Stress; IA3 Long-term and Cyclical Comparison of Employment; and IA4 Job Creation.

IA1 Summary of the Employment Situation. Table I-1 provides summary statistics of the employment situation report of the BLS. The first four rows provide the data from the establishment report of creation of nonfarm payroll jobs and remuneration of workers (for analysis of the differences in employment between the establishment report and the household survey see Abraham, Haltiwanger, Sandusky and Spletzer 2009). Total nonfarm payroll employment seasonally adjusted (SA) increased 280,000 in May 2015 and private payroll employment increased 262,000. The average monthly number of nonfarm jobs created from May 2013 to May 2014 was 207,750 using seasonally adjusted data, while the average number of nonfarm jobs created from May 2014 to May 2015 was 254,833, or increase by 22.7 percent. The average number of private jobs created in the US from May 2013 to May 2014 was 209,083, using seasonally adjusted data, while the average from May 2014 to May 2015 was 246,500, or increase by 17.9 percent. This blog calculates the effective labor force of the US at 163.926 million in May 2014 and 165.801 million in May 2015 (Table I-4), for growth of 1.875 million at average 156,250 per month. The difference between the average increase of 246,500 new private nonfarm jobs per month in the US from May 2014 to May 2015 and the 156,250 average monthly increase in the labor force from May 2014 to May 2015 is 90,250 monthly new jobs net of absorption of new entrants in the labor force. There are 24.677 million in job stress in the US currently. Creation of 90,250 new jobs per month net of absorption of new entrants in the labor force would require 273 months to provide jobs for the unemployed and underemployed (24.677 million divided by 90,250) or 23 years (273 divided by 12). The civilian labor force of the US in May 2015 not seasonally adjusted stood at 155.719 million with 8.370 million unemployed or effectively 16.452 million unemployed in this blog’s calculation by inferring those who are not searching because they believe there is no job for them for effective labor force of 165.801 million. Reduction of one million unemployed at the current rate of job creation without adding more unemployment requires 0.92 years (1 million divided by product of 90,250 by 12, which is 1,083,000). Reduction of the rate of unemployment to 5 percent of the labor force would be equivalent to unemployment of only 8.290 million (0.05 times labor force of 165.801 million). New net job creation would be 0.080 million (8.370 million unemployed minus 8.290 million unemployed at rate of 5 percent) that at the current rate would take 0.07 years (0.080 million divided by 1.083). Under the calculation in this blog, there are 16.452 million unemployed by including those who ceased searching because they believe there is no job for them and effective labor force of 165.801 million. Reduction of the rate of unemployment to 5 percent of the labor force would require creating 8.804 million jobs net of labor force growth that at the current rate would take 7.5 years (16.452 million minus 0.05(165.801 million) = 8.162 million divided by 1.083, using LF PART 66.2% and Total UEM in Table I-4). These calculations assume that there are no more recessions, defying United States economic history with periodic contractions of economic activity when unemployment increases sharply. The number employed in May 2015 was 149.349 million (NSA) or 2.034 million more people with jobs relative to the peak of 147.315 million in Jul 2007 while the civilian noninstitutional population of ages 16 years and over increased from 231.958 million in Jul 2007 to 250.455 million in May 2015 or by 18.497 million. The number employed increased 1.4 percent from Jul 2007 to May 2015 while the noninstitutional civilian population of ages of 16 years and over, or those available for work, increased 8.0 percent. The ratio of employment to population in Jul 2007 was 63.5 percent (147.315 million employment as percent of population of 231.958 million). The same ratio in May 2015 would result in 159.039 million jobs (0.635 multiplied by noninstitutional civilian population of 250.455 million). There are effectively 9.690 million fewer jobs in May 2015 than in Jul 2007, or 159.039 million minus 149.349 million. There is actually not sufficient job creation in merely absorbing new entrants in the labor force because of those dropping from job searches, worsening the stock of unemployed or underemployed in involuntary part-time jobs.

There is current interest in past theories of “secular stagnation.” Alvin H. Hansen (1939, 4, 7; see Hansen 1938, 1941; for an early critique see Simons 1942) argues:

“Not until the problem of full employment of our productive resources from the long-run, secular standpoint was upon us, were we compelled to give serious consideration to those factors and forces in our economy which tend to make business recoveries weak and anaemic (sic) and which tend to prolong and deepen the course of depressions. This is the essence of secular stagnation-sick recoveries which die in their infancy and depressions which feed on them-selves and leave a hard and seemingly immovable core of unemployment. Now the rate of population growth must necessarily play an important role in determining the character of the output; in other words, the com-position of the flow of final goods. Thus a rapidly growing population will demand a much larger per capita volume of new residential building construction than will a stationary population. A stationary population with its larger proportion of old people may perhaps demand more personal services; and the composition of consumer demand will have an important influence on the quantity of capital required. The demand for housing calls for large capital outlays, while the demand for personal services can be met without making large investment expenditures. It is therefore not unlikely that a shift from a rapidly growing population to a stationary or declining one may so alter the composition of the final flow of consumption goods that the ratio of capital to output as a whole will tend to decline.”

The argument that anemic population growth causes “secular stagnation” in the US (Hansen 1938, 1939, 1941) is as misplaced currently as in the late 1930s (for early dissent see Simons 1942). There is currently population growth in the ages of 16 to 24 years but not enough job creation and discouragement of job searches for all ages (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/fluctuating-valuations-of-financial.html). The proper explanation is not in secular stagnation but in cyclically slow growth. Secular stagnation is merely another case of theory without reality with dubious policy proposals. Subsection IA4 Job Creation analyzes the types of jobs created, which are lower paying than earlier. Average hourly earnings in May 2015 were $24.96 seasonally adjusted (SA), increasing 2.3 percent not seasonally adjusted (NSA) relative to May 2014 and increasing 0.3 percent relative to Apr 2015 seasonally adjusted. In Apr 2015, average hourly earnings seasonally adjusted were $24.88, increasing 2.1 percent relative to Apr 2014 not seasonally adjusted and increasing 0.1 percent seasonally adjusted relative to Mar 2015. These are nominal changes in workers’ wages. The following row “average hourly earnings in constant dollars” provides hourly wages in constant dollars calculated by the BLS or what is called “real wages” adjusted for inflation. Data are not available for May 2015 because the prices indexes of the BLS for May 2015 will only be released on Jun, 2015 (http://www.bls.gov/cpi/), which will be covered in this blog’s comment on Jun 21, 2015, together with world inflation. The second column provides changes in real wages for Apr 2015. Average hourly earnings adjusted for inflation or in constant dollars increased 2.3 percent in Apr 2015 relative to Apr 2014 but have been decreasing during multiple months. World inflation waves in bouts of risk aversion (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/interest-rate-policy-and-dollar.html) mask declining trend of real wages. The fractured labor market of the US is characterized by high levels of unemployment and underemployment together with falling real wages or wages adjusted for inflation (Section I and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/quite-high-equity-valuations-and.html). The following section IB Stagnating Real Wages provides more detailed analysis. Average weekly hours of US workers seasonally adjusted remained virtually unchanged around 34.5. Another headline number widely followed is the unemployment rate or number of people unemployed as percent of the labor force. The unemployment rate calculated in the household survey increased from 5.4 percent in Apr 2015 to 5.5 percent in May 2015, seasonally adjusted. This blog provides with every employment situation report the number of people in the US in job stress or unemployed plus underemployed calculated without seasonal adjustment (NSA) at 24.7 million in May 2015 and 25.6 million in Apr 2015. The final row in Table I-1 provides the number in job stress as percent of the actual labor force calculated at 14.9 percent in May 2015 and 15.4 percent in Apr 2015. Almost one in every five workers in the US is unemployed or underemployed.

There is socio-economic stress in the combination of adverse events and cyclical performance: 

Table I-1, US, Summary of the Employment Situation Report SA

 

May 2015

Apr 2015

New Nonfarm Payroll Jobs

280,000

221,000

New Private Payroll Jobs

262,000

206,000

Average Hourly Earnings

May 15 $24.96 SA

∆% May 15/May 14 NSA: 2.3

∆% May 15/Apr 15 SA: 0.3

Apr 15 $24.88 SA

∆% Apr 15/ Apr 14 NSA: 2.1

∆% Apr 15/Mar 15 SA: 0.1

Average Hourly Earnings in Constant Dollars

 

∆% Apr 2015/Apr 2014 NSA: 2.3

Average Weekly Hours

34.5 SA

34.4 NSA

34.5 SA

34.4 NSA

Unemployment Rate Household Survey % of Labor Force SA

5.5

5.4

Number in Job Stress Unemployed and Underemployed Blog Calculation

24.7 million NSA

25.6 million NSA

In Job Stress as % Labor Force

14.9 NSA

15.4 NSA

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/

The Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) of the US Department of Labor provides both seasonally adjusted (SA) and not-seasonally adjusted (NSA) or unadjusted data with important uses (Bureau of Labor Statistics 2012Feb3; 2011Feb11):

“Most series published by the Current Employment Statistics program reflect a regularly recurring seasonal movement that can be measured from past experience. By eliminating that part of the change attributable to the normal seasonal variation, it is possible to observe the cyclical and other nonseasonal movements in these series. Seasonally adjusted series are published monthly for selected employment, hours, and earnings estimates.”

Requirements of using best available information and updating seasonality factors affect the comparability over time of United States employment data. In the first month of the year, the BLS revises data for several years by adjusting benchmarks and seasonal factors (page 4 at http://www.bls.gov/news.release/pdf/empsit.pdf release of Jan 2015 at http://www.bls.gov/schedule/archives/empsit_nr.htm#2015), which is the case of the data for Jan 2015 released on Feb 6, 2015:

“In accordance with annual practice, the establishment survey data released today have been benchmarked to reflect comprehensive counts of payroll jobs for March 2014. These counts are derived principally from the Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages (QCEW), which enumerates jobs covered by the unemployment insurance tax system. The benchmark process results in revisions to not seasonally adjusted data from April 2013 forward.

Seasonally adjusted data from January 2010 forward are subject to revision. In addition, data for some series prior to 2010, both seasonally adjusted and unadjusted, incorporate revisions. The total nonfarm employment level for March 2014 was revised upward by 91,000 (+67,000 on a not seasonally adjusted basis, or less than 0.05 percent). The average benchmark revision over the past 10 years was plus or minus 0.3 percent. Table A presents revised total nonfarm employment data on a seasonally adjusted basis for January through

December 2014.

An article that discusses the benchmark and post-benchmark revisions and other technical issues can be accessed through the BLS website at www.bls.gov/web/empsit/cesbmart.pdf.

Information on the data released today also may be obtained by calling (202) 691-6555.”

There are also adjustments of population that affect comparability of labor statistics over time (page 5 at http://www.bls.gov/news.release/pdf/empsit.pdf release of Jan 2015 at http://www.bls.gov/schedule/archives/empsit_nr.htm#2015):

“Effective with data for January 2015, updated population estimates have been used in the household survey. Population estimates for the household survey are developed by the U.S. Census Bureau. Each year, the Census Bureau updates the estimates to reflect new information and assumptions about the growth of the population since the previous decennial census. The change in population reflected in the new estimates results from adjustments for net international migration, updated vital statistics and other information, and some methodological changes in the estimation process. In accordance with usual practice, BLS will not revise the official household survey estimates for December 2014 and earlier months. To show the impact of the population adjustments, however, differences in selected December 2014 labor force series based on the old and new population estimates are shown in table B.”

There are also adjustments of benchmarks and seasonality factors for establishment data that affect comparability over time (page 4 at http://www.bls.gov/news.release/pdf/empsit.pdf release of Jan 2015 at http://www.bls.gov/schedule/archives/empsit_nr.htm#2015):

“In accordance with annual practice, the establishment survey data released today [Feb 6, 2015] have been benchmarked to reflect comprehensive counts of payroll jobs for March 2014. These counts are derived principally from the Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages (QCEW), which enumerates jobs covered by the unemployment insurance tax system. The benchmark process results in revisions to not seasonally adjusted data from April 2013 forward. Seasonally adjusted data from January 2010 forward are subject to revision. In addition, data for some series prior to 2010, both seasonally adjusted and unadjusted, incorporate revisions.”

All comparisons over time are affected by yearly adjustments of benchmarks and seasonality factors. All data in this blog comment use revised data released by the BLS on Mar 6, 2015 (http://www.bls.gov/).

IA2 Number of People in Job Stress. There are two approaches to calculating the number of people in job stress. The first approach consists of calculating the number of people in job stress unemployed or underemployed with the raw data of the employment situation report as in Table I-2. The data are seasonally adjusted (SA). The first three rows provide the labor force and unemployed in millions and the unemployment rate of unemployed as percent of the labor force. There is decrease in the number unemployed from 8.575 million in Mar 2015 to 8.549 million in Apr 2015 and increase to 8.674 million in May 2015. The rate of unemployment decreased from 5.5 percent in Mar 2015 to 5.4 percent in Apr 2015 and increased to 5.5 percent in May 2015. An important aspect of unemployment is its persistence for more than 27 weeks with 2.502 million in May 2015, corresponding to 28.8 percent of the unemployed. The longer the period of unemployment the lower are the chances of finding another job with many long-term unemployed ceasing to search for a job. Another key characteristic of the current labor market is the high number of people trying to subsist with part-time jobs because they cannot find full-time employment or part-time for economic reasons. The BLS explains as follows: “these individuals were working part time because their hours had been cut back or because they were unable to find full-time work” (http://www.bls.gov/news.release/pdf/empsit.pdf 2). The number of part-time for economic reasons decreased from 6.705 million in Mar 2015 to 6.580 million in Apr 2015 and increased to 6.652 million in May 2015. Another important fact is the marginally attached to the labor force. The BLS explains as follows: “these individuals were not in the labor force, wanted and were available for work, and had looked for a job sometime in the prior 12 months. They were not counted as unemployed because they had not searched for work in the 4 weeks preceding the survey” (http://www.bls.gov/news.release/pdf/empsit.pdf 2). The number in job stress unemployed or underemployed of 17.188 million in May 2015 is composed of:

· 8.674 million unemployed (of whom 2.502 million, or 28.8 percent, unemployed for 27 weeks or more) compared with 8.549 million unemployed in Apr 2014 (of whom 2.525 million, or 29.5 percent, unemployed for 27 weeks or more),

· 6.652 million employed part-time for economic reasons in May 2015 (who suffered reductions in their work hours or could not find full-time employment) compared with 6.580 million in Apr 2015

· 1.862 million who were marginally attached to the labor force in May 2015 (who were not in the labor force but wanted and were available for work) compared with 2.115 million in Apr 2015

Table I-2, US, People in Job Stress, Millions and % SA

2014

May 2015

Apr 2015

Mar 2015

Labor Force Millions

157.469

157.072

156.906

Unemployed
Millions

8.674

8.549

8.575

Unemployment Rate (unemployed as % labor force)

5.5

5.4

5.5

Unemployed ≥27 weeks
Millions

2.502

2.525

2.563

Unemployed ≥27 weeks %

28.8

29.5

29.9

Part Time for Economic Reasons
Millions

6.652

6.580

6.705

Marginally
Attached to Labor Force
Millions

1.862

2.115

2.055

Job Stress
Millions

17.188

17.244

17,335

In Job Stress as % Labor Force

10.9

11.0

11.0

Job Stress = Unemployed + Part Time Economic Reasons + Marginally Attached Labor Force

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/cps/

Table I-3 repeats the data in Table I-2 but including Feb and additional data. What really matters is the number of people with jobs or the total employed, representing the opportunity for exit from unemployment. The final row of Table I-3 provides people employed as percent of the population or employment to population ratio. The number has remained relatively constant around 59 percent, reaching 59.3 in Feb 2015, 59.3 in Mar 2015, 59.3 in Apr 2015 and 59.4 in May 2015. The employment to population ratio fell from an annual level of 63.1 percent in 2006 to 58.6 percent in 2012, 58.6 percent in 2013 and 59.0 in 2014 with the lowest level at 58.4 percent in 2011.

Table I-3, US, Unemployment and Underemployment, SA, Millions and Percent

 

May 2015

Apr 2015

Mar 2015

Feb 2015

Labor Force

157.469

157.072

156.906

157.002

Participation Rate

62.9

62.8

62.7

62.8

Unemployed

8.674

8.549

8.575

8.705

UNE Rate %

5.5

5.4

5.5

5.5

Part Time Economic Reasons

6.652

6.580

6.705

6.635

Marginally Attached to Labor Force

1.862

2.115

2.055

2.159

In Job Stress

17.188

17.244

17.335

17.499

In Job Stress % Labor Force

10.9

11.0

11.0

11.1

Employed

148.795

148.523

148.331

148.297

Employment % Population

59.4

59.3

59.3

59.3

Job Stress = Unemployed + Part Time Economic Reasons + Marginally Attached Labor Force

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/cps/

The balance of this section considers the second approach. Charts I-1 to I-12 explain the reasons for considering another approach to calculating job stress in the US. Chart I-1 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics provides the level of employment in the US from 2001 to 2015. There was a big drop of the number of people employed from 147.315 million at the peak in Jul 2007 (NSA) to 136.809 million at the trough in Jan 2010 (NSA) with 10.506 million fewer people employed. Recovery has been anemic compared with the shallow recession of 2001 that was followed by nearly vertical growth in jobs. The number employed in May 2015 was 149.349 million (NSA) or 2.034 million more people with jobs relative to the peak of 147.315 million in Jul 2007 while the civilian noninstitutional population of ages 16 years and over increased from 231.958 million in Jul 2007 to 250.455 million in May 2015 or by 18.497 million. The number employed increased 1.4 percent from Jul 2007 to May 2015 while the noninstitutional civilian population of ages of 16 years and over, or those available for work, increased 8.0 percent. The ratio of employment to population in Jul 2007 was 63.5 percent (147.315 million employment as percent of population of 231.958 million). The same ratio in May 2015 would result in 159.039 million jobs (0.635 multiplied by noninstitutional civilian population of 250.455 million). There are effectively 9.690 million fewer jobs in May 2015 than in Jul 2007, or 159.039 million minus 149.349 million. There is actually not sufficient job creation in merely absorbing new entrants in the labor force because of those dropping from job searches, worsening the stock of unemployed or underemployed in involuntary part-time jobs.

clip_image001

Chart I-1, US, Employed, Thousands, SA, 2001-2015

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-2 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics provides 12-month percentage changes of the number of people employed in the US from 2001 to 2015. There was recovery since 2010 but not sufficient to recover lost jobs. Many people in the US who had jobs before the global recession are not working now and many who entered the labor force cannot find employment.

clip_image002

Chart I-2, US, Employed, 12-Month Percentage Change NSA, 2001-2015

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The foundation of the second approach derives from Chart II-3 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics providing the level of the civilian labor force in the US. The civilian labor force consists of people who are available and willing to work and who have searched for employment recently. The labor force of the US grew 9.4 percent from 142.828 million in Jan 2001 to 156.255 million in Jul 2009 but is 0.2 percent higher at 157.719 million in May 2015, all numbers not seasonally adjusted. Chart I-3 shows the flattening of the curve of expansion of the labor force and its decline in 2010 and 2011. The ratio of the labor force of 154.871 million in Jul 2007 to the noninstitutional population of 231.958 million in Jul 2007 was 66.8 percent while the ratio of the labor force of 157.719 million in May 2015 to the noninstitutional population of 250.455 million in May 2015 was 63.0 percent. The labor force of the US in May 2015 corresponding to 66.8 percent of participation in the population would be 167.304 million (0.668 x 250.455). The difference between the measured labor force in May 2015 of 157.719 million and the labor force in May 2015 with participation rate of 66.8 percent (as in Jul 2007) of 167.304 million is 9.585 million. The level of the labor force in the US has stagnated and is 9.585 million lower than what it would have been had the same participation rate been maintained. Millions of people have abandoned their search for employment because they believe there are no jobs available for them. The key issue is whether the decline in participation of the population in the labor force is the result of people giving up on finding another job.

clip_image003

Chart I-3, US, Civilian Labor Force, Thousands, SA, 2001-2015

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-4 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics provides 12-month percentage changes of the level of the labor force in the US. The rate of growth fell almost instantaneously with the global recession and became negative from 2009 to 2011. The labor force of the US collapsed and did not recover. Growth in the beginning of the summer originates in younger people looking for jobs in the summer after graduation or during school recess.

clip_image004

Chart I-4, US, Civilian Labor Force, Thousands, NSA, 12-month Percentage Change, 2001-2015

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-5 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics provides the labor force participation rate in the US or labor force as percent of the population. The labor force participation rate of the US fell from 66.8 percent in Jan 2001 to 63.0 percent NSA in May 2015, all numbers not seasonally adjusted. The annual labor force participation rate for 1979 was 63.7 percent and also 63.7 percent in Nov 1980 during sharp economic contraction. This comparison is further elaborated below. Chart I-5 shows an evident downward trend beginning with the global recession that has continued throughout the recovery beginning in IIIQ2009. The critical issue is whether people left the workforce of the US because they believe there is no longer a job for them.

clip_image005

Chart I-5, Civilian Labor Force Participation Rate, Percent of Population in Labor Force SA, 2001-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-6 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics provides the level of unemployed in the US. The number unemployed rose from the trough of 6.272 million NSA in Oct 2006 to the peak of 16.147 million in Jan 2010, declining to 13.400 million in Jul 2012, 12.696 million in Aug 2012 and 11.741 million in Sep 2012. The level unemployed fell to 11.741 million in Oct 2012, 11.404 million in Nov 2012, 11.844 million in Dec 2012, 13.181 million in Jan 2013, 12.500 million in Feb 2013 and 9.984 million in Dec 2013. The level of unemployment reached 8.370 million in May 2015, all numbers not seasonally adjusted.

clip_image006

Chart I-6, US, Unemployed, Thousands, SA, 2001-2015

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-7 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics provides the rate of unemployment in the US or unemployed as percent of the labor force. The rate of unemployment of the US rose from 4.7 percent in Jan 2001 to 6.5 percent in Jun 2003, declining to 4.1 percent in Oct 2006. The rate of unemployment jumped to 10.6 percent in Jan 2010 and declined to 7.6 percent in Dec 2012 but increased to 8.5 percent in Jan 2013 and 8.1 percent in Feb 2013, falling back to 7.3 percent in May 2013 and 7.8 percent in Jun 2013, all numbers not seasonally adjusted. The rate of unemployment not seasonally adjusted stabilized at 7.7 percent in Jul 2013 and fell to 6.5 percent in Dec 2013 and 5.4 percent in Dec 2014. The rate of unemployment NSA decreased to 5.3 percent in May 2015.

clip_image007

Chart I-7, US, Unemployment Rate, SA, 2001-2015

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-8 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics provides 12-month percentage changes of the level of unemployed. There was a jump of 81.8 percent in Apr 2009 with subsequent decline and negative rates since 2010. On an annual basis, the level of unemployed rose 59.8 percent in 2009 and 26.1 percent in 2008 with increase of 3.9 percent in 2010, decline of 7.3 percent in 2011 and decrease of 9.0 percent in 2012. The annual level of unemployment decreased 8.4 percent in 2013 and fell 16.1 percent in 2014. The level of unemployment fell 11.4 percent in May 2015 relative to a year earlier.

clip_image008

Chart I-8, US, Unemployed, 12-month Percentage Change, NSA, 2001-2015

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-9 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics provides the number of people in part-time occupations because of economic reasons, that is, because they cannot find full-time employment. The number underemployed in part-time occupations not seasonally adjusted rose from 3.732 million in Jan 2001 to 5.270 million in Jan 2004, falling to 3.787 million in Apr 2006. The number underemployed seasonally adjusted jumped to 9.114 million in Nov 2009, falling to 8.174 million in Dec 2011 but increasing to 8.291 million in Jan 2012 and 8.193 million in Feb 2012 but then falling to 7.926 million in Dec 2012 and increasing to 8.087 million in Jul 2013. The number employed part-time for economic reasons seasonally adjusted reached 7.766 million in Dec 2013 and 6.790 million in Dec 2014. The number employed part-time for economic reasons seasonally adjusted reached 6.652 million in May 2015. Without seasonal adjustment, the number employed part-time for economic reasons reached 9.354 million in Dec 2009, declining to 8.918 million in Jan 2012 and 8.166 million in Dec 2012 but increasing to 8.324 million in Jul 2013. The number employed part-time for economic reasons NSA stood at 7.990 million in Dec 2013 and 6.970 million in Dec 2014. The number employed part-time for economic reasons stood at 6.363 million in May 2015. The longer the period in part-time jobs the lower are the chances of finding another full-time job.

clip_image009

Chart I-9, US, Part-Time for Economic Reasons, Thousands, SA, 2001-2015

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-10 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics repeats the behavior of unemployment. The 12-month percentage change of the level of people at work part-time for economic reasons jumped 84.7 percent in Mar 2009 and declined subsequently. The declines have been insufficient to reduce significantly the number of people who cannot shift from part-time to full-time employment. On an annual basis, the number of part-time for economic reasons increased 33.5 percent in 2008 and 51.7 percent in 2009, declining 0.4 percent in 2010, 3.5 percent in 2011 and 5.1 percent in 2012. The annual number of part-time for economic reasons decreased 2.3 percent in 2013 and fell 9.1 percent in 2014. The number of part-time for economic reasons fell 8.6 percent in May 2015 relative to a year earlier.

clip_image010

Chart I-10, US, Part-Time for Economic Reasons NSA 12-Month Percentage Change, 2001-2015

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-11 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics provides the same pattern of the number marginally attached to the labor force jumping to significantly higher levels during the global recession and remaining at historically high levels. The number marginally attached to the labor force not seasonally adjusted increased from 1.295 million in Jan 2001 to 1.691 million in Feb 2004. The number of marginally attached to the labor force fell to 1.299 million in Sep 2006 and increased to 2.609 million in Dec 2010 and 2.800 million in Jan 2011. The number marginally attached to the labor force was 2.540 million in Dec 2011, increasing to 2.809 million in Jan 2012, falling to 2.608 million in Feb 2012. The number marginally attached to the labor force fell to 2.352 million in Mar 2012, 2.363 million in Apr 2012, 2.423 million in May 2012, 2.483 million in Jun 2012, 2.529 million in Jul 2012 and 2.561 million in Aug 2012. The number marginally attached to the labor force fell to 2.517 million in Sep 2012, 2.433 million in Oct 2012, 2.505 million in Nov 2012 and 2.427 million in in Dec 2013. The number marginally attached to the labor force reached 2.260 million in Dec 2014. The number marginally attached to the labor force fell to 1.862 million in May 2015.

clip_image011

Chart I-11, US, Marginally Attached to the Labor Force, Thousands, NSA, 2001-2015

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-12 provides 12-month percentage changes of the marginally attached to the labor force from 2001 to 2015. There was a jump of 56.1 percent in May 2009 during the global recession followed by declines in percentage changes but insufficient negative changes. On an annual basis, the number of marginally attached to the labor force increased in four consecutive years: 15.7 percent in 2008, 37.9 percent in 2009, 11.7 percent in 2010 and 3.5 percent in 2011. The number marginally attached to the labor force fell 2.2 percent on annual basis in 2012 but increased 2.9 percent in the 12 months ending in Dec 2012, fell 13.0 percent in the 12 months ending in Jan 2013, falling 10.7 percent in the 12 months ending in May 2013. The number marginally attached to the labor force increased 4.0 percent in the 12 months ending in Jun 2013 and fell 4.5 percent in the 12 months ending in Jul 2013 and 8.6 percent in the 12 months ending in Aug 2013. The annual number of marginally attached to the labor force fell 6.2 percent in 2013 and fell 6.5 percent in 2014. The number marginally attached to the labor force fell 7.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Dec 2013 and fell 6.9 percent in the 12 months ending in Dec 2014. The number marginally attached to the labor force fell 12.6 percent in the 12 months ending in May 2015.

clip_image012

Chart I-12, US, Marginally Attached to the Labor Force 12-Month Percentage Change, NSA, 2001-2015

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/data/

Table I-4, US, Population, Labor Force and Unemployment, NSA

 

2006

May 2014

Apr 2015

May 2015

POP

229

247,622

250,266

250,455

LF

151

155,841

156,554

157,719

PART%

66.2

62.9

62.6

63.0

EMP

144

146,398

148,587

149,349

EMP/POP%

62.9

59.1

59.4

59.6

UEM

7

9,443

7,966

8,370

UEM/LF Rate%

4.6

6.1

5.1

5.3

NLF

77

91,782

93,712

92,736

LF PART 66.2%

 

163,926

165,676

165,801

NLF UEM

 

8,085

9,122

8,082

Total UEM

 

17,528

17,088

16,452

Total UEM%

 

10.7

10.3

9.9

Part Time Economic Reasons

 

6,960

6,356

6,363

Marginally Attached to LF

 

2,130

2,115

1,862

In Job Stress

 

26,618

25,559

24,677

People in Job Stress as % Labor Force

 

16.2

15.4

14.9

Pop: population; LF: labor force; PART: participation; EMP: employed; UEM: unemployed; NLF: not in labor force; NLF UEM: additional unemployed; Total UEM is UEM + NLF UEM; Total UEM% is Total UEM as percent of LF PART 66.2%; In Job Stress = Total UEM + Part Time Economic Reasons + Marginally Attached to LF

Note: the first column for 2006 is in average millions; the remaining columns are in thousands; NSA: not seasonally adjusted

The labor force participation rate of 66.2% in 2006 is applied to current population to obtain LF PART 66.2%; NLF UEM is obtained by subtracting the labor force with participation of 66.2 percent from the household survey labor force LF; Total UEM is household data unemployment plus NLF UEM; and total UEM% is total UEM divided by LF PART 66.2%

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/cps/

In the analysis of Hansen (1939, 3) of secular stagnation, economic progress consists of growth of real income per person driven by growth of productivity. The “constituent elements” of economic progress are “(a) inventions, (b) the discovery and development of new territory and new resources, and (c) the growth of population” (Hansen 1939, 3). Secular stagnation originates in decline of population growth and discouragement of inventions. According to Hansen (1939, 2), US population grew by 16 million in the 1920s but grew by one half or about 8 million in the 1930s with forecasts at the time of Hansen’s writing in 1938 of growth of around 5.3 million in the 1940s. Hansen (1939, 2) characterized demography in the US as “a drastic decline in the rate of population growth. Hansen’s plea was to adapt economic policy to stagnation of population in ensuring full employment. In the analysis of Hansen (1939, 8), population caused half of the growth of US GDP per year. Growth of output per person in the US and Europe was caused by “changes in techniques and to the exploitation of new natural resources.” In this analysis, population caused 60 percent of the growth of capital formation in the US. Declining population growth would reduce growth of capital formation. Residential construction provided an important share of growth of capital formation. Hansen (1939, 12) argues that market power of imperfect competition discourages innovation with prolonged use of obsolete capital equipment. Trade unions would oppose labor-savings innovations. The combination of stagnating and aging population with reduced innovation caused secular stagnation. Hansen (1939, 12) concludes that there is role for public investments to compensate for lack of dynamism of private investment but with tough tax/debt issues.

The current application of Hansen’s (1938, 1939, 1941) proposition argues that secular stagnation occurs because full employment equilibrium can be attained only with negative real interest rates between minus 2 and minus 3 percent. Professor Lawrence H. Summers (2013Nov8) finds that “a set of older ideas that went under the phrase secular stagnation are not profoundly important in understanding Japan’s experience in the 1990s and may not be without relevance to America’s experience today” (emphasis added). Summers (2013Nov8) argues there could be an explanation in “that the short-term real interest rate that was consistent with full employment had fallen to -2% or -3% sometime in the middle of the last decade. Then, even with artificial stimulus to demand coming from all this financial imprudence, you wouldn’t see any excess demand. And even with a relative resumption of normal credit conditions, you’d have a lot of difficulty getting back to full employment.” The US economy could be in a situation where negative real rates of interest with fed funds rates close to zero as determined by the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) do not move the economy to full employment or full utilization of productive resources. Summers (2013Oct8) finds need of new thinking on “how we manage an economy in which the zero nominal interest rates is a chronic and systemic inhibitor of economy activity holding our economies back to their potential.”

Former US Treasury Secretary Robert Rubin (2014Jan8) finds three major risks in prolonged unconventional monetary policy of zero interest rates and quantitative easing: (1) incentive of delaying action by political leaders; (2) “financial moral hazard” in inducing excessive exposures pursuing higher yields of risker credit classes; and (3) major risks in exiting unconventional policy. Rubin (2014Jan8) proposes reduction of deficits by structural reforms that could promote recovery by improving confidence of business attained with sound fiscal discipline.

Professor John B. Taylor (2014Jan01, 2014Jan3) provides clear thought on the lack of relevance of Hansen’s contention of secular stagnation to current economic conditions. The application of secular stagnation argues that the economy of the US has attained full-employment equilibrium since around 2000 only with negative real rates of interest of minus 2 to minus 3 percent. At low levels of inflation, the so-called full-employment equilibrium of negative interest rates of minus 2 to minus 3 percent cannot be attained and the economy stagnates. Taylor (2014Jan01) analyzes multiple contradictions with current reality in this application of the theory of secular stagnation:

  • Secular stagnation would predict idle capacity, in particular in residential investment when fed fund rates were fixed at 1 percent from Jun 2003 to Jun 2004. Taylor (2014Jan01) finds unemployment at 4.4 percent with house prices jumping 7 percent from 2002 to 2003 and 14 percent from 2004 to 2005 before dropping from 2006 to 2007. GDP prices doubled from 1.7 percent to 3.4 percent when interest rates were low from 2003 to 2005.
  • Taylor (2014Jan01, 2014Jan3) finds another contradiction in the application of secular stagnation based on low interest rates because of savings glut and lack of investment opportunities. Taylor (2009) shows that there was no savings glut. The savings rate of the US in the past decade is significantly lower than in the 1980s.
  • Taylor (2014Jan01, 2014Jan3) finds another contradiction in the low ratio of investment to GDP currently and reduced investment and hiring by US business firms.
  • Taylor (2014Jan01, 2014Jan3) argues that the financial crisis and global recession were caused by weak implementation of existing regulation and departure from rules-based policies.
  • Taylor (2014Jan01, 2014Jan3) argues that the recovery from the global recession was constrained by a change in the regime of regulation and fiscal/monetary policies.

In revealing research, Edward P. Lazear and James R. Spletzer (2012JHJul22) use the wealth of data in the valuable database and resources of the Bureau of Labor Statistics (http://www.bls.gov/data/) in providing clear thought on the nature of the current labor market of the United States. The critical issue of analysis and policy currently is whether unemployment is structural or cyclical. Structural unemployment could occur because of (1) industrial and demographic shifts and (2) mismatches of skills and job vacancies in industries and locations. Consider the aggregate unemployment rate, Y, expressed in terms of share si of a demographic group in an industry i and unemployment rate yi of that demographic group (Lazear and Spletzer 2012JHJul22, 5-6):

Y = ∑isiyi (1)

This equation can be decomposed for analysis as (Lazear and Spletzer 2012JHJul22, 6):

Y = ∑isiy*i + ∑iyis*i (2)

The first term in (2) captures changes in the demographic and industrial composition of the economy ∆si multiplied by the average rate of unemployment y*i , or structural factors. The second term in (2) captures changes in the unemployment rate specific to a group, or ∆yi, multiplied by the average share of the group s*i, or cyclical factors. There are also mismatches in skills and locations relative to available job vacancies. A simple observation by Lazear and Spletzer (2012JHJul22) casts intuitive doubt on structural factors: the rate of unemployment jumped from 4.4 percent in the spring of 2007 to 10 percent in October 2009. By nature, structural factors should be permanent or occur over relative long periods. The revealing result of the exhaustive research of Lazear and Spletzer (2012JHJul22) is:

“The analysis in this paper and in others that we review do not provide any compelling evidence that there have been changes in the structure of the labor market that are capable of explaining the pattern of persistently high unemployment rates. The evidence points to primarily cyclic factors.”

Table I-4b and Chart I-12-b provide the US labor force participation rate or percentage of the labor force in population. It is not likely that simple demographic trends caused the sharp decline during the global recession and failure to recover earlier levels. The civilian labor force participation rate dropped from the peak of 66.9 percent in Jul 2006 to 62.6 percent in Dec 2013, 62.5 percent in Dec 2014 and 63.0 percent in May 2015. The civilian labor force participation rate was 63.7 percent on an annual basis in 1979 and 63.4 percent in Dec 1980 and Dec 1981, reaching even 62.9 percent in both Apr and May 1979. The civilian labor force participation rate jumped with the recovery to 64.8 percent on an annual basis in 1985 and 65.9 percent in Jul 1985. Structural factors cannot explain these sudden changes vividly shown visually in the final segment of Chart I-12b. Seniors would like to delay their retiring especially because of the adversities of financial repression on their savings. Labor force statistics are capturing the disillusion of potential workers with their chances in finding a job in what Lazear and Spletzer (2012JHJul22) characterize as accentuated cyclical factors. The argument that anemic population growth causes “secular stagnation” in the US (Hansen 1938, 1939, 1941) is as misplaced currently as in the late 1930s (for early dissent see Simons 1942). There is currently population growth in the ages of 16 to 24 years but not enough job creation and discouragement of job searches for all ages (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/fluctuating-valuations-of-financial.html). “Secular stagnation” would be a process over many years and not from one year to another. This is merely another case of theory without reality with dubious policy proposals.

Table I-4b, US, Labor Force Participation Rate, Percent of Labor Force in Population, NSA, 1979-2015

Year

Jan

Feb

Mar

Apr

May

Aug

Sep

Oct

Nov

Dec

Annual

1979

62.9

63.0

63.2

62.9

62.9

64.5

63.8

64.0

63.8

63.8

63.7

1980

63.3

63.2

63.2

63.2

63.5

64.5

63.6

63.9

63.7

63.4

63.8

1981

63.2

63.2

63.5

63.6

63.9

64.6

63.5

64.0

63.8

63.4

63.9

1982

63.0

63.2

63.4

63.3

63.9

64.9

64.0

64.1

64.1

63.8

64.0

1983

63.3

63.2

63.3

63.2

63.4

65.1

64.3

64.1

64.1

63.8

64.0

1984

63.3

63.4

63.6

63.7

64.3

65.2

64.4

64.6

64.4

64.3

64.4

1985

64.0

64.0

64.4

64.3

64.6

65.4

64.9

65.1

64.9

64.6

64.8

1986

64.2

64.4

64.6

64.6

65.0

66.1

65.3

65.5

65.4

65.0

65.3

1987

64.7

64.8

65.0

64.9

65.6

66.5

65.5

65.9

65.7

65.5

65.6

1988

65.1

65.2

65.2

65.3

65.5

66.8

65.9

66.1

66.2

65.9

65.9

1989

65.8

65.6

65.7

65.9

66.2

67.2

66.3

66.6

66.7

66.3

66.5

1990

66.0

66.0

66.2

66.1

66.5

67.1

66.4

66.5

66.3

66.1

66.5

1991

65.5

65.7

65.9

66.0

66.0

66.6

66.1

66.1

66.0

65.8

66.2

1992

65.7

65.8

66.0

66.0

66.4

67.2

66.3

66.2

66.2

66.1

66.4

1993

65.6

65.8

65.8

65.6

66.3

67.0

66.1

66.4

66.3

66.2

66.3

1994

66.0

66.2

66.1

66.0

66.5

67.2

66.5

66.8

66.7

66.5

66.6

1995

66.1

66.2

66.4

66.4

66.4

67.1

66.5

66.7

66.5

66.2

66.6

1996

65.8

66.1

66.4

66.2

66.7

67.2

66.8

67.1

67.0

66.7

66.8

1997

66.4

66.5

66.9

66.7

67.0

67.6

67.0

67.1

67.1

67.0

67.1

1998

66.6

66.7

67.0

66.6

67.0

67.3

67.0

67.1

67.1

67.0

67.1

1999

66.7

66.8

66.9

66.7

67.0

67.3

66.8

67.0

67.0

67.0

67.1

2000

66.8

67.0

67.1

67.0

67.0

67.2

66.7

66.9

66.9

67.0

67.1

2001

66.8

66.8

67.0

66.7

66.6

66.8

66.6

66.7

66.6

66.6

66.8

2002

66.2

66.6

66.6

66.4

66.5

66.8

66.6

66.6

66.3

66.2

66.6

2003

66.1

66.2

66.2

66.2

66.2

66.3

65.9

66.1

66.1

65.8

66.2

2004

65.7

65.7

65.8

65.7

65.8

66.2

65.7

66.0

66.1

65.8

66.0

2005

65.4

65.6

65.6

65.8

66.0

66.5

66.1

66.2

66.1

65.9

66.0

2006

65.5

65.7

65.8

65.8

66.0

66.5

66.1

66.4

66.4

66.3

66.2

2007

65.9

65.8

65.9

65.7

65.8

66.1

66.0

66.0

66.1

65.9

66.0

2008

65.7

65.5

65.7

65.7

66.0

66.4

65.9

66.1

65.8

65.7

66.0

2009

65.4

65.5

65.4

65.4

65.5

65.6

65.0

64.9

64.9

64.4

65.4

2010

64.6

64.6

64.8

64.9

64.8

65.0

64.6

64.4

64.4

64.1

64.7

2011

63.9

63.9

64.0

63.9

64.1

64.3

64.2

64.1

63.9

63.8

64.1

2012

63.4

63.6

63.6

63.4

63.8

63.7

63.6

63.8

63.5

63.4

63.7

2013

63.3

63.2

63.1

63.1

63.5

63.4

63.2

62.9

62.9

62.6

63.2

2014

62.5

62.7

62.9

62.6

62.9

63.0

62.8

63.0

62.8

62.5

62.9

2015

62.5

62.5

62.5

62.6

63.0

           

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/cps/

clip_image013

Chart I-12b, US, Labor Force Participation Rate, Percent of Labor Force in Population, NSA, 1979-2015

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/cps/

Broader perspective is provided by Chart I-12c of the US Bureau of Labor Statistics. The United States civilian noninstitutional population has increased along a consistent trend since 1948 that continued through earlier recessions and the global recession from IVQ2007 to IIQ2009 and the cyclical expansion after IIIQ2009.

clip_image014

Chart I-12c, US, Civilian Noninstitutional Population, Thousands, NSA, 1948-2015

Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The labor force of the United States in Chart I-12d has increased along a trend similar to that of the civilian noninstitutional population in Chart I-12c. There is an evident stagnation of the civilian labor force in the final segment of Chart I-12d during the current economic cycle. This stagnation is explained by cyclical factors similar to those analyzed by Lazear and Spletzer (2012JHJul22) that motivated an increasing population to drop out of the labor force instead of structural factors. Large segments of the potential labor force are not observed, constituting unobserved unemployment and of more permanent nature because those afflicted have been seriously discouraged from working by the lack of opportunities.

clip_image015

Chart I-12d, US, Labor Force, Thousands, NSA, 1948-2015

Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The rate of labor force participation of the US is in Chart I-12E from 1948 to 2015. There is sudden decline during the global recession after 2007 without recovery explained by cyclic factors (Lazear and Spletzer 2012JHJul22) as many potential workers stopped their job searches disillusioned that there could be an opportunity for them in sharply contracted labor markets.

clip_image016

Chart I-12E, US, Labor Force Participation Rate, Percent of Labor Force in Population, NSA, 1948-2015

Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

IA3 Long-term and Cyclical Comparison of Employment. There is initial discussion here of long-term employment trends followed by cyclical comparison. Growth and employment creation have been mediocre in the expansion beginning in Jul IIIQ2009 from the contraction between Dec IVQ2007 and Jun IIQ2009 (http://www.nber.org/cycles.html). A series of charts from the database of the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) provides significant insight. Chart I-13 provides the monthly employment level of the US from 1948 to 2015. The number of people employed has trebled. There are multiple contractions throughout the more than six decades but followed by resumption of the strong upward trend. The contraction of employment after 2007 is sharp and followed by a flatter curve of job creation. The United States missed this opportunity of high growth in the initial phase of recovery that historically eliminated unemployment and underemployment created during the contraction. Inferior performance of the US economy and labor markets is the critical current issue of analysis and policy design. Long-term economic performance in the United States consisted of trend growth of GDP at 3 percent per year and of per capita GDP at 2 percent per year as measured for 1870 to 2010 by Robert E Lucas (2011May). The economy returned to trend growth after adverse events such as wars and recessions. The key characteristic of adversities such as recessions was much higher rates of growth in expansion periods that permitted the economy to recover output, income and employment losses that occurred during the contractions. Over the business cycle, the economy compensated the losses of contractions with higher growth in expansions to maintain trend growth of GDP of 3 percent and of GDP per capita of 2 percent. The US maintained growth at 3.0 percent on average over entire cycles with expansions at higher rates compensating for contractions. US economic growth has been at only 2.2 percent on average in the cyclical expansion in the 23 quarters from IIIQ2009 to IQ2015. Boskin (2010Sep) measures that the US economy grew at 6.2 percent in the first four quarters and 4.5 percent in the first 12 quarters after the trough in the second quarter of 1975; and at 7.7 percent in the first four quarters and 5.8 percent in the first 12 quarters after the trough in the first quarter of 1983 (Professor Michael J. Boskin, Summer of Discontent, Wall Street Journal, Sep 2, 2010 http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052748703882304575465462926649950.html). There are new calculations using the revision of US GDP and personal income data since 1929 by the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) (http://bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm) and the second estimate of GDP for IQ2015 (http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/gdp/2015/pdf/gdp1q15_2nd.pdf). The average of 7.7 percent in the first four quarters of major cyclical expansions is in contrast with the rate of growth in the first four quarters of the expansion from IIIQ2009 to IIQ2010 of only 2.7 percent obtained by diving GDP of $14,745.9 billion in IIQ2010 by GDP of $14,355.6 billion in IIQ2009 {[$14,745.9/$14,355.6 -1]100 = 2.7%], or accumulating the quarter on quarter growth rates (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/06/dollar-revaluation-squeezing-corporate.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/dollar-devaluation-and-carry-trade.html). The expansion from IQ1983 to IVQ1985 was at the average annual growth rate of 5.9 percent, 5.4 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1986, 5.2 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1986, 5.0 percent from IQ1983 to IQ1987, 5.0 percent from IQ1983 to IIQ1987, 4.9 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1987, 5.0 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1987, 4.9 percent from IQ1983 to IIQ1988, 4.8 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1988 and at 7.8 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1983 (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/06/dollar-revaluation-squeezing-corporate.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/dollar-devaluation-and-carry-trade.html). The US maintained growth at 3.0 percent on average over entire cycles with expansions at higher rates compensating for contractions. Growth at trend in the entire cycle from IVQ2007 to IQ2015 would have accumulated to 23.9 percent. GDP in IQ2015 would be $18,574.8 billion (in constant dollars of 2009) if the US had grown at trend, which is higher by $2,310.7 billion than actual $16,264.1 billion. There are about two trillion dollars of GDP less than at trend, explaining the 24.7 million unemployed or underemployed equivalent to actual unemployment/underemployment of 14.9 percent of the effective labor force (Section I and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/quite-high-equity-valuations-and.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/04/volatility-of-valuations-of-financial.html). US GDP in IQ2015 is 12.4 percent lower than at trend. US GDP grew from $14,991.8 billion in IVQ2007 in constant dollars to $16,264.1 billion in IQ2015 or 8.5 percent at the average annual equivalent rate of 1.1 percent. Cochrane (2014Jul2) estimates US GDP at more than 10 percent below trend. The US missed the opportunity to grow at higher rates during the expansion and it is difficult to catch up because growth rates in the final periods of expansions tend to decline. The US missed the opportunity for recovery of output and employment always afforded in the first four quarters of expansion from recessions. Zero interest rates and quantitative easing were not required or present in successful cyclical expansions and in secular economic growth at 3.0 percent per year and 2.0 percent per capita as measured by Lucas (2011May). There is cyclical uncommonly slow growth in the US instead of allegations of secular stagnation. There is similar behavior in manufacturing. There is classic research on analyzing deviations of output from trend (see for example Schumpeter 1939, Hicks 1950, Lucas 1975, Sargent and Sims 1977). The long-term trend is growth at average 3.3 percent per year from Apr 1919 to Apr 2015. Growth at 3.3 percent per year would raise the NSA index of manufacturing output from 99.2392 in Dec 2007 to 125.9172 in Apr 2015. The actual index NSA in Apr 2015 is 101.1122, which is 19.7 percent below trend. Manufacturing output grew at average 2.4 percent between Dec 1986 and Dec 2014. Using trend growth of 2.4 percent per year, the index would increase to 118.0899 in Apr 2015. The output of manufacturing at 101.1122 in Apr 2015 is 14.4 percent below trend under this alternative calculation.

clip_image017

Chart I-13, US, Employment Level, Thousands, SA, 1948-2015

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The steep and consistent curve of growth of the US labor force is shown in Chart I-14. The contraction beginning in Dec 2007 flattened the path of the US civilian labor force and with flatter curve during the current expansion.

clip_image018

Chart I-14, US, Civilian Labor Force, SA, 1948-2015, Thousands

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-15 for the period from 1948 to 2015. The labor force participation rate is influenced by numerous factors such as the age of the population. There is no comparable episode in the postwar economy to the sharp collapse of the labor force participation rate in Chart I-15 during the contraction and subsequent expansion after 2007. Aging can reduce the labor force participation rate as many people retire but many may have decided to work longer as their wealth and savings have been significantly reduced. There is an important effect of many people just exiting the labor force because they believe there is no job available for them.

clip_image019

Chart I-15, US, Civilian Labor Force Participation Rate, SA, 1948-2015, %

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The number of unemployed in the US jumped seasonally adjusted from 5.8 million in May 1979 to 12.1 million in Dec 1982, by 6.3 million, or 108.6 percent. The jump not seasonally adjusted was from 5.4 million in May 1979 to 12.5 million in Jan 1983, by 7.1 million or 131.5 percent. The number of unemployed seasonally adjusted jumped from 6.7 million in Mar 2007 to 15.4 million in Oct 2009, by 8.7 million, or 129.9 percent. The number of unemployed not seasonally adjusted jumped from 6.5 million in Apr 2007 to 16.1 million in Jan 2010, by 9.6 million or 147.7 percent. These are the two episodes with steepest increase in the level of unemployment in Chart I-16.

clip_image020

Chart I-16, US, Unemployed, SA, 1948-2015, Thousands

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-17 provides the rate of unemployment of the US from 1948 to 2015. The peak of the series is 10.8 percent in both Nov and Dec 1982. The second highest rates are 10.0 percent in Oct 2009 and 9.9 percent in both Nov and Dec 2009. The unadjusted rate of unemployment reached 5.3 percent in May 2015.

clip_image021

Chart I-17, US, Unemployment Rate, SA, 1948-2015

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-18 provides the number unemployed for 27 weeks and over from 1948 to 2015. The number unemployed for 27 weeks and over jumped from 510,000 in Dec 1978 to 2.885 million in Jun 1983, by 2.4 million, or 465.7 percent. The number of unemployed 27 weeks or over SA jumped from 1.132 million in May 2007 to 6.623 million in Jun 2010, by 5.491 million, or 485.1 percent.

clip_image022

Chart I-18, US, Unemployed for 27 Weeks or More, SA, 1948-2015, Thousands

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The employment-population ratio in Chart I-19 is an important indicator of wellbeing in labor markets, measuring the number of people with jobs. The US employment-population ratio fell from 63.5 in Dec 2006 to 58.6 in Jul 2011 and stands at 59.6 NSA in May 2015. There is no comparable decline followed by stabilization during a cyclical expansion in Chart I-19.

clip_image023

Chart I-19, US, Employment-Population Ratio, 1948-2015

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The number employed part-time for economic reasons in Chart I-20 increased in the recessions and declined during the expansions. In the current cycle, the number employed part-time for economic reasons increased sharply and has not returned to normal levels. Lower growth of economic activity in the expansion after IIIQ2009 failed to reduce the number desiring to work full time but finding only part-time occupations. The lack of full-time jobs is evidently cyclical and not secular.

clip_image024

Chart I-20, US, Part-Time for Economic Reasons, NSA, 1955-2015, Thousands

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Table I-5 provides percentage change of real GDP in the United States in the 1930s, 1980s and 2000s. The recession in 1981-1982 is quite similar on its own to the 2007-2009 recession. In contrast, during the Great Depression in the four years of 1930 to 1933, GDP in constant dollars fell 26.4 percent cumulatively and fell 45.3 percent in current dollars (Pelaez and Pelaez, Financial Regulation after the Global Recession (2009a), 150-2, Pelaez and Pelaez, Globalization and the State, Vol. II (2009b), 205-7 and revisions in http://bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm). Data are available for the 1930s only on a yearly basis. US GDP fell 4.7 percent in the two recessions (1) from IQ1980 to IIIQ1980 and (2) from III1981 to IVQ1981 to IVQ1982 and 4.2 percent cumulatively in the recession from IVQ2007 to IIQ2009. It is instructive to compare the first years of the expansions in the 1980s and the current expansion. GDP grew at 4.6 percent in 1983, 7.3 percent in 1984, 4.2 percent in 1985, 3.5 percent in 1986, 3.5 percent in 1987 and 4.2 percent in 1988. In contrast, GDP grew 2.5 percent in 2010, 1.6 percent in 2011, 2.3 percent in 2012, 2.2 percent in 2013 and 2.4 percent in 2014. Actual annual equivalent GDP growth in the four quarters of 2012, and nine quarters from IQ2013 to IQ2015 is 2.1 percent and 2.7 percent in the four quarters ending in IQ2015. GDP grew at 4.2 percent in 1985, 3.5 percent in 1986, 3.5 percent in 1987 and 4.2 percent in 1988. The forecasts of the central tendency of participants of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) are in the range of 2.3 to 2.7 percent in 2015 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/fomcprojtabl20150318.pdf) with less reliable forecast of 2.3 to 2.7 percent in 2016 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/fomcprojtabl20150318.pdf). Growth of GDP in the expansion from IIIQ2009 to IQ2015 has been at average 2.2 percent in annual equivalent.

Table I-5, US, Percentage Change of GDP in the 1930s, 1980s and 2000s, ∆%

Year

GDP ∆%

Year

GDP ∆%

Year

GDP ∆%

1930

-8.5

1980

-0.2

2000

4.1

1931

-6.4

1981

2.6

2001

1.0

1932

-12.9

1982

-1.9

2002

1.8

1933

-1.3

1983

4.6

2003

2.8

1934

10.8

1984

7.3

2004

3.8

1935

8.9

1985

4.2

2005

3.3

1936

12.9

1986

3.5

2006

2.7

1937

5.1

1987

3.5

2007

1.8

1938

-3.3

1988

4.2

2008

-0.3

1930

8.0

1989

3.7

2009

-2.8

1940

8.8

1990

1.9

2010

2.5

1941

17.7

1991

-0.1

2011

1.6

1942

18.9

1992

3.6

2012

2.3

1943

17.0

1993

2.7

2013

2.2

1944

8.0

1994

4.0

2014

2.4

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

Characteristics of the four cyclical contractions are provided in Table I-6 with the first column showing the number of quarters of contraction; the second column the cumulative percentage contraction; and the final column the average quarterly rate of contraction. There were two contractions from IQ1980 to IIIQ1980 and from IIIQ1981 to IVQ1982 separated by three quarters of expansion. The drop of output combining the declines in these two contractions is 4.7 percent, which is almost equal to the decline of 4.2 percent in the contraction from IVQ2007 to IIQ2009. In contrast, during the Great Depression in the four years of 1930 to 1933, GDP in constant dollars fell 26.4 percent cumulatively and fell 45.3 percent in current dollars (Pelaez and Pelaez, Financial Regulation after the Global Recession (2009a), 150-2, Pelaez and Pelaez, Globalization and the State, Vol. II (2009b), 205-7 and revisions in http://bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm). The comparison of the global recession after 2007 with the Great Depression is entirely misleading.

Table I-6, US, Number of Quarters, GDP Cumulative Percentage Contraction and Average Percentage Annual Equivalent Rate in Cyclical Contractions   

 

Number of Quarters

Cumulative Percentage Contraction

Average Percentage Rate

IIQ1953 to IIQ1954

3

-2.4

-0.8

IIIQ1957 to IIQ1958

3

-3.0

-1.0

IVQ1973 to IQ1975

5

-3.1

-0.6

IQ1980 to IIIQ1980

2

-2.2

-1.1

IIIQ1981 to IVQ1982

4

-2.5

-0.64

IVQ2007 to IIQ2009

6

-4.2

-0.72

Sources: Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

Table I-7 shows the mediocre average annual equivalent growth rate of 2.2 percent of the US economy in the twenty-three quarters of the current cyclical expansion from IIIQ2009 to IQ2015. In sharp contrast, the average growth rate of GDP was:

  • 5.7 percent in the first thirteen quarters of expansion from IQ1983 to IQ1986
  • 5.4 percent in the first fifteen quarters of expansion from IQ1983 to IIIQ1986
  • 5.2 percent in the first sixteen quarters of expansion from IQ1983 to IVQ1986
  • 5.0 percent in the first seventeen quarters of expansion from IQ1983 to IQ1987
  • 5.0 percent in the first eighteen quarters of expansion from IQ1983 to IIQ1987
  • 4.9 percent in the first nineteen quarters of expansion from IQ1983 to IIIQ1987
  • 5.0 percent in the first twenty quarters of expansion from IQ1983 to IVQ1987
  • 4.9 percent in the first twenty-first quarters of expansion from IQ1983 to IQ1988
  • 4.9 percent in the first twenty-two quarters of expansion from IQ1983 to IIQ1988
  • 4.8 percent in the first twenty-three quarters of expansion from IQ1983 to IIIQ1988

The line “average first four quarters in four expansions” provides the average growth rate of 7.7 percent with 7.8 percent from IIIQ1954 to IIQ1955, 9.2 percent from IIIQ1958 to IIQ1959, 6.1 percent from IIIQ1975 to IIQ1976 and 7.8 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1983. The United States missed this opportunity of high growth in the initial phase of recovery. BEA data show the US economy in standstill with annual growth of 2.5 percent in 2010 decelerating to 1.6 percent annual growth in 2011, 2.3 percent in 2012, 2.2 percent in 2013 and 2.4 percent in 2014 (http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm) The expansion from IQ1983 to IQ1986 was at the average annual growth rate of 5.7 percent, 5.2 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1986, 4.9 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1987, 5.0 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1987, 4.9 percent from IQ1983 to IQ1988, 4.9 percent from IQ1983 to IIQ1988, 4.8 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1988 and at 7.8 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1983. GDP grew 2.7 percent in the first four quarters of the expansion from IIIQ2009 to IIQ2010. GDP growth in the four quarters of 2012, the four quarters of 2013, the four quarters of 2014 and IQ2015 accumulated to 7.1 percent. This growth is equivalent to 2.1 percent per year, obtained by dividing GDP in IQ2015 of $16,264.1 billion by GDP in IVQ2011 of $15,190.3 billion and compounding by 4/13: {[($16,264.1/$15,190.3)4/13 -1]100 = 2.1 percent.

Table I-7, US, Number of Quarters, Cumulative Growth and Average Annual Equivalent Growth Rate in Cyclical Expansions

 

Number
of
Quarters

Cumulative Growth

∆%

Average Annual Equivalent Growth Rate

IIIQ 1954 to IQ1957

11

12.8

4.5

First Four Quarters IIIQ1954 to IIQ1955

4

7.8

 

IIQ1958 to IIQ1959

5

10.0

7.9

First Four Quarters

IIIQ1958 to IIQ1959

4

9.2

 

IIQ1975 to IVQ1976

8

8.3

4.1

First Four Quarters IIIQ1975 to IIQ1976

4

6.1

 

IQ1983-IQ1986

IQ1983-IIIQ1986

IQ1983-IVQ1986

IQ1983-IQ1987

IQ1983-IIQ1987

IQ1983 to IIIQ1987

IQ1983 to IVQ1987

IQ1983 to IQ1988

IQ1983 to IIQ1988

IQ1983 to IIIQ1988

13

15

16

17

18

19

20

21

22

23

19.9

21.6

22.3

23.1

24.5

25.6

27.7

28.4

30.1

30.9

5.7

5.4

5.2

5.0

5.0

4.9

5.0

4.9

4.9

4.8

First Four Quarters IQ1983 to IVQ1983

4

7.8

 

Average First Four Quarters in Four Expansions*

 

7.7

 

IIIQ2009 to IQ2015

23

13.2

2.2

First Four Quarters IIIQ2009 to IIQ2010

 

2.7

 

*First Four Quarters: 7.8% IIIQ1954-IIQ1955; 9.2% IIIQ1958-IIQ1959; 6.1% IIIQ1975-IQ1976; 7.8% IQ1983-IVQ1983

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

A group of charts from the database of the Bureau of Labor Statistics facilitates the comparison of employment in the 1980s and 2000s. The long-term charts and tables from I-5 to I-7 in the discussion above confirm the view that the comparison of the current expansion should be with that in the 1980s because of similar dimensions. Chart I-21 provides the level of employment in the US between 1979 and 1989. Employment surged after the contraction and grew rapidly during the decade.

clip_image025

Chart I-21, US, Employed, Thousands, 1979-1989

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-22 provides the level of employment in the US from 2001 to 2015. There is actually not sufficient job creation in merely absorbing new entrants in the labor force because of those dropping from job searches, worsening the stock of unemployed or underemployed in involuntary part-time jobs. Recovery has been anemic compared with the shallow recession of 2001 that was followed by nearly vertical growth in jobs. The number employed in May 2015 was 149.349 million (NSA) or 2.034 million more people with jobs relative to the peak of 147.315 million in Jul 2007 while the civilian noninstitutional population of ages 16 years and over increased from 231.958 million in Jul 2007 to 250.455 million in May 2015 or by 18.497 million. The number employed increased 1.4 percent from Jul 2007 to May 2015 while the noninstitutional civilian population of ages of 16 years and over, or those available for work, increased 8.0 percent. The ratio of employment to population in Jul 2007 was 63.5 percent (147.315 million employment as percent of population of 231.958 million). The same ratio in May 2015 would result in 159.039 million jobs (0.635 multiplied by noninstitutional civilian population of 250.455 million). There are effectively 9.690 million fewer jobs in May 2015 than in Jul 2007, or 159.039 million minus 149.349 million. There is actually not sufficient job creation in merely absorbing new entrants in the labor force because of those dropping from job searches, worsening the stock of unemployed or underemployed in involuntary part-time jobs.

clip_image001[1]

Chart I-22, US, Employed, Thousands, 2001-2015

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

There was a steady upward trend in growth of the civilian labor force between 1979 and 1989 as shown in Chart I-23. There were fluctuations but strong long-term dynamism over an entire decade.

clip_image026

Chart I-23, US, Civilian Labor Force, Thousands, 1979-1989

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The civilian labor force in Chart I-24 grew steadily on an upward trend in the 2000s until it contracted together with the economy after 2007. There has not been recovery during the expansion but rather decline and marginal turn of the year 2011 into expansion in 2012 followed by stability and oscillation into 2013-2015.

clip_image003[1]

Chart I-24, US, Civilian Labor Force, Thousands, 2001-2015

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The rate of participation of the labor force in population stagnated during the stagflation and conquest of inflation in the late 1970s and early 1980s, as shown in Chart I-25. Recovery was vigorous during the expansion and lasted through the remainder of the decade.

clip_image027

Chart I-25, US, Civilian Labor Force Participation Rate, 1979-1989, %

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The rate of participation in the labor force declined after the recession of 2001 followed by stability until 2007, as shown in Chart I-26. The rate of participation in the labor force continued to decline both during the contraction after 2007 and the expansion after 2009 with marginal expansion at the turn of the year into 2012 followed by trend of decline and stability. Sharp decline occurred during the cycle and not secularly.

clip_image005[1]

Chart I-26, US, Civilian Labor Force Participation Rate, 2001-2015, %

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-27 provides the number unemployed during the 1980s. The number unemployed peaked at 12.051 million in Dec 1982 seasonally adjusted and 12.517 in Jan 1983 million not seasonally adjusted, declining to 8.358 million in Dec 1984 seasonally adjusted and 7.978 in Dec 1984 million not seasonally adjusted during the first two years of expansion from the contraction. The number unemployed then fell to 6.667 million in Dec 1989 seasonally adjusted and 6.300 million not seasonally adjusted.

clip_image028

Chart I-27, US, Unemployed Thousands 1979-1989

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-28 provides the number unemployed from 2001 to 2015. Using seasonally adjusted data, the number unemployed rose from 6.727 million in Oct 2006 to 15.352 million in Oct 2009, declining to 13.071 million in Dec 2011 and to 8.688 million in Dec 2014 and 8.549 million in Apr 2015. Using data not seasonally adjusted, the number unemployed rose from 6.272 million in Oct 2006 to 16.147 million in Jan 2010, declining to 11.844 million in Dec 2012, increasing to 13.181 million in Jan 20013 and declining to 9.984 million in Dec 2013. The level of unemployment fell from 10.855 million in Jan 2014 to 8.331 million in Dec 2014. The level of unemployment was 8.370 million in May 2015.

clip_image006[1]

Chart I-28, US, Unemployed Thousands 2001-2015

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The rate of unemployment peaked at 10.8 percent in both Nov and Dec 1982 seasonally adjusted, as shown in Chart I-29. The rate of unemployment dropped sharply during the expansion after 1984 and continued to decline during the rest of the decade to 5.4 percent in Dec 1989. Using not seasonally adjusted data, the rate of unemployment peaked at 11.4 percent in Jan 1983, declining to 7.0 percent in Dec 1984 and 5.1 percent in Dec 1989.

clip_image029

Chart I-29, US, Unemployment Rate, 1979-1989, %

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The rate of unemployment in the US seasonally adjusted jumped from 4.4 percent in May 2007 to 10.0 percent in Oct 2009 and 9.9 percent in both Nov and Dec 2009, as shown in Chart I-30. The rate of unemployment fluctuated at around 9.0 percent in 2011, declining to 7.9 percent in Dec 2012 and 6.7 percent in Dec 2013. The rate of unemployed eased to 5.6 percent in Dec 2014 and 5.5 percent in May 2015.

clip_image007[1]

Chart I-30, US, Unemployment Rate, 2001-2015, %

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The employment population ratio seasonally adjusted fell from around 60.1 in Dec 1979 to 57.1 in both Feb and Mar 1983, as shown in Chart I-31. The employment population ratio seasonally adjusted rose back to 59.9 in Dec 1984 and reached 63.0 later in the decade in Dec 1989. Using not seasonally adjusted data, the employment population ratio dropped from 60.4 percent in Oct 1979 to 56.1 percent in Jan 1983, increasing to 59.8 in Dec 1984 and to 62.9 percent in Dec 1989.

clip_image030

Chart I-31, US, Employment Population Ratio, 1979-1989, %

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The US employment-population ratio seasonally adjusted has fallen from 63.4 in Dec 2006 to 58.6 in Dec 2011, 58.6 in Dec 2012, 58.6 in Dec 2013 and 59.2 in Dec 2014, as shown in Chart I-32. The employment-population ratio reached 59.4 in May 2015. The employment population-ratio has stagnated during the expansion. Using not seasonally adjusted data, the employment population ratio fell from 63.6 percent in Jul 2006 to 57.6 percent in Jan 2011, 58.5 percent in Dec 2012, 58.5 percent in Dec 2013 and 59.1 in Dec 2014. The employment population ratio eased to 59.6 in May 2015.

clip_image031

Chart I-32, US, Employment Population Ratio, 2001-2015, %

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The number unemployed 27 weeks or more rose in Chart I-33 rose from 492,000 NSA in Oct 1979 to 2.978 million in Mar 1983. The level unemployed 27 weeks or more NSA fell to 566,000 in Aug 1989.

clip_image032

Chart I-33, US, Number Unemployed for 27 Weeks or More 1979-1989, SA, Thousands

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The number unemployed for 27 weeks or over, seasonally adjusted, increased sharply during the contraction as shown in Chart I-34 from 1.131 million in Nov 2006 to 6.800 million in Apr 2010 seasonally adjusted. The number of unemployed for 27 weeks remained at around 6 million during the expansion compared with somewhat above 1 million before the contraction, falling to 2.502 million in May 2015 seasonally adjusted and 2.505 million not seasonally adjusted.

clip_image033

Chart I-34, US, Number Unemployed for 27 Weeks or More, 2001-2015, SA, Thousands

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The number of persons working part-time for economic reasons because they cannot find full-time work peaked during the contraction at 6.857 million SA in Oct 1982, as shown in Chart I-35. The number of persons at work part-time for economic reasons fell sharply during the expansion to 5.797 million in Dec 1984 and continued to fall throughout the decade to 4.817 million in Dec 1989 SA and 4.709 million NSA.

clip_image034

Chart I-35, US, Part-Time for Economic Reasons, 1979-1989, Thousands

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The number of people working part-time because they cannot find full-time employment, not seasonally adjusted, increased sharply during the contraction from 3.787 million in Apr 2006, not seasonally adjusted, to 9.354 million in Dec 2009, as shown in Chart I-36. The number of people working part-time because of failure to find an alternative occupation stagnated at a very high level during the expansion, declining to 6.363 million not seasonally adjusted in May 2015.

clip_image009[1]

Chart I-36, US, Part-Time for Economic Reasons, 2001-2015, Thousands

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The number marginally attached to the labor force in Chart I-37 jumped from 1.252 million in Dec 2006 to 2.800 million in Jan 2011, remaining at a high level of 2.540 million in Dec 2011, 2.809 million in Jan 2012 and 2.614 million in Dec 2012. The number marginally attached to the labor force eased to 2.427 million in Dec 2013 and 2.260 million in Dec 2014. The level of marginally attached to the labor force reached 1.862 million in May 2015.

clip_image011[1]

Chart I-37, US, Marginally Attached to the Labor Force, 2001-2015

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

IA4 Job Creation. What is striking about the data in Table I-8 is that the numbers of monthly increases in jobs in 1983 and 1984 are several times higher than in 2010 to 2014. The civilian noninstitutional population grew by 42.3 percent from 174.215 million in 1983 to 247.947 million in 2014 and labor force higher by 39.8 percent, growing from 111.550 million in 1983 to 155.922 million in 2014. Total nonfarm payroll employment seasonally adjusted (SA) increased 280,000 in May 2015 and private payroll employment increased 262,000. The average monthly number of nonfarm jobs created from May 2013 to May 2014 was 207,750 using seasonally adjusted data, while the average number of nonfarm jobs created from May 2014 to May 2015 was 254,833, or increase by 22.7 percent. The average number of private jobs created in the US from May 2013 to May 2014 was 209,083, using seasonally adjusted data, while the average from May 2014 to May 2015 was 246,500, or increase by 17.9 percent. This blog calculates the effective labor force of the US at 163.926 million in May 2014 and 165.801 million in May 2015 (Table I-4), for growth of 1.875 million at average 156,250 per month. The difference between the average increase of 246,500 new private nonfarm jobs per month in the US from May 2014 to May 2015 and the 156,250 average monthly increase in the labor force from May 2014 to May 2015 is 90,250 monthly new jobs net of absorption of new entrants in the labor force. There are 24.677 million in job stress in the US currently. Creation of 90,250 new jobs per month net of absorption of new entrants in the labor force would require 273 months to provide jobs for the unemployed and underemployed (24.677 million divided by 90,250) or 23 years (273 divided by 12). The civilian labor force of the US in May 2015 not seasonally adjusted stood at 155.719 million with 8.370 million unemployed or effectively 16.452 million unemployed in this blog’s calculation by inferring those who are not searching because they believe there is no job for them for effective labor force of 165.801 million. Reduction of one million unemployed at the current rate of job creation without adding more unemployment requires 0.92 years (1 million divided by product of 90,250 by 12, which is 1,083,000). Reduction of the rate of unemployment to 5 percent of the labor force would be equivalent to unemployment of only 8.290 million (0.05 times labor force of 165.801 million). New net job creation would be 0.080 million (8.370 million unemployed minus 8.290 million unemployed at rate of 5 percent) that at the current rate would take 0.07 years (0.080 million divided by 1.083). Under the calculation in this blog, there are 16.452 million unemployed by including those who ceased searching because they believe there is no job for them and effective labor force of 165.801 million. Reduction of the rate of unemployment to 5 percent of the labor force would require creating 8.804 million jobs net of labor force growth that at the current rate would take 7.5 years (16.452 million minus 0.05(165.801 million) = 8.162 million divided by 1.083, using LF PART 66.2% and Total UEM in Table I-4). These calculations assume that there are no more recessions, defying United States economic history with periodic contractions of economic activity when unemployment increases sharply. The number employed in May 2015 was 149.349 million (NSA) or 2.034 million more people with jobs relative to the peak of 147.315 million in Jul 2007 while the civilian noninstitutional population of ages 16 years and over increased from 231.958 million in Jul 2007 to 250.455 million in May 2015 or by 18.497 million. The number employed increased 1.4 percent from Jul 2007 to May 2015 while the noninstitutional civilian population of ages of 16 years and over, or those available for work, increased 8.0 percent. The ratio of employment to population in Jul 2007 was 63.5 percent (147.315 million employment as percent of population of 231.958 million). The same ratio in May 2015 would result in 159.039 million jobs (0.635 multiplied by noninstitutional civilian population of 250.455 million). There are effectively 9.690 million fewer jobs in May 2015 than in Jul 2007, or 159.039 million minus 149.349 million. There is actually not sufficient job creation in merely absorbing new entrants in the labor force because of those dropping from job searches, worsening the stock of unemployed or underemployed in involuntary part-time jobs.

There is current interest in past theories of “secular stagnation.” Alvin H. Hansen (1939, 4, 7; see Hansen 1938, 1941; for an early critique see Simons 1942) argues:

“Not until the problem of full employment of our productive resources from the long-run, secular standpoint was upon us, were we compelled to give serious consideration to those factors and forces in our economy which tend to make business recoveries weak and anaemic (sic) and which tend to prolong and deepen the course of depressions. This is the essence of secular stagnation-sick recoveries which die in their infancy and depressions which feed on them-selves and leave a hard and seemingly immovable core of unemployment. Now the rate of population growth must necessarily play an important role in determining the character of the output; in other words, the com-position of the flow of final goods. Thus a rapidly growing population will demand a much larger per capita volume of new residential building construction than will a stationary population. A stationary population with its larger proportion of old people may perhaps demand more personal services; and the composition of consumer demand will have an important influence on the quantity of capital required. The demand for housing calls for large capital outlays, while the demand for personal services can be met without making large investment expenditures. It is therefore not unlikely that a shift from a rapidly growing population to a stationary or declining one may so alter the composition of the final flow of consumption goods that the ratio of capital to output as a whole will tend to decline.”

The argument that anemic population growth causes “secular stagnation” in the US (Hansen 1938, 1939, 1941) is as misplaced currently as in the late 1930s (for early dissent see Simons 1942). There is currently population growth in the ages of 16 to 24 years but not enough job creation and discouragement of job searches for all ages (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/fluctuating-valuations-of-financial.html). The proper explanation is not in secular stagnation but in cyclically slow growth. The US maintained growth at 3.0 percent on average over entire cycles with expansions at higher rates compensating for contractions. Growth at trend in the entire cycle from IVQ2007 to IQ2015 would have accumulated to 23.9 percent. GDP in IQ2015 would be $18,574.8 billion (in constant dollars of 2009) if the US had grown at trend, which is higher by $2,310.7 billion than actual $16,264.1 billion. There are about two trillion dollars of GDP less than at trend, explaining the 24.7 million unemployed or underemployed equivalent to actual unemployment/underemployment of 14.9 percent of the effective labor force (Section I and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/quite-high-equity-valuations-and.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/04/volatility-of-valuations-of-financial.html). US GDP in IQ2015 is 12.4 percent lower than at trend. US GDP grew from $14,991.8 billion in IVQ2007 in constant dollars to $16,264.1 billion in IQ2015 or 8.5 percent at the average annual equivalent rate of 1.1 percent. Cochrane (2014Jul2) estimates US GDP at more than 10 percent below trend. The US missed the opportunity to grow at higher rates during the expansion and it is difficult to catch up because growth rates in the final periods of expansions tend to decline. The US missed the opportunity for recovery of output and employment always afforded in the first four quarters of expansion from recessions. Zero interest rates and quantitative easing were not required or present in successful cyclical expansions and in secular economic growth at 3.0 percent per year and 2.0 percent per capita as measured by Lucas (2011May). There is cyclical uncommonly slow growth in the US instead of allegations of secular stagnation. There is similar behavior in manufacturing. There is classic research on analyzing deviations of output from trend (see for example Schumpeter 1939, Hicks 1950, Lucas 1975, Sargent and Sims 1977). The long-term trend is growth at average 3.3 percent per year from Apr 1919 to Apr 2015. Growth at 3.3 percent per year would raise the NSA index of manufacturing output from 99.2392 in Dec 2007 to 125.9172 in Apr 2015. The actual index NSA in Apr 2015 is 101.1122, which is 19.7 percent below trend. Manufacturing output grew at average 2.4 percent between Dec 1986 and Dec 2014. Using trend growth of 2.4 percent per year, the index would increase to 118.0899 in Apr 2015. The output of manufacturing at 101.1122 in Apr 2015 is 14.4 percent below trend under this alternative calculation.

Table I-8, US, Monthly Change in Jobs, Number SA

Month

1981

1982

1983

2008

2009

2010

Private

Jan

94

-326

224

15

-796

32

23

Feb

68

-5

-75

-87

-703

-68

-53

Mar

105

-130

172

-79

-824

161

119

Apr

73

-280

276

-213

-684

247

196

May

10

-45

277

-183

-355

518

91

Jun

197

-243

379

-172

-467

-130

126

Jul

112

-342

418

-210

-325

-64

107

Aug

-36

-158

-308

-259

-217

-39

110

Sep

-87

-181

1115

-452

-227

-49

124

Oct

-99

-277

271

-476

-201

248

198

Nov

-209

-123

353

-765

-6

121

131

Dec

-278

-14

356

-696

-283

89

110

     

1984

   

2011

Private

Jan

   

446

   

75

77

Feb

   

481

   

167

218

Mar

   

275

   

206

225

Apr

   

363

   

321

330

May

   

308

   

103

160

Jun

   

379

   

185

186

Jul

   

313

   

117

190

Aug

   

242

   

128

137

Sep

   

310

   

223

287

Oct

   

286

   

183

166

Nov

   

349

   

146

174

Dec

   

128

   

226

246

     

1985

   

2012

Private

Jan

   

266

   

380

381

Feb

   

124

   

247

249

Mar

   

346

   

216

218

Apr

   

196

   

87

110

May

   

274

   

113

122

Jun

   

146

   

35

56

Jul

   

190

   

177

154

Aug

   

193

   

188

160

Sep

   

203

   

144

164

Oct

   

188

   

213

240

Nov

   

209

   

164

186

Dec

   

167

   

293

275

     

1986

   

2013

Private

Jan

   

125

   

205

220

Feb

   

107

   

314

297

Mar

   

94

   

115

139

Apr

   

187

   

187

194

May

   

127

   

219

225

Jun

   

-94

   

127

172

Jul

   

318

   

164

162

Aug

   

114

   

256

213

Sep

   

347

   

150

168

Oct

   

186

   

225

235

Nov

   

186

   

317

303

Dec

   

205

   

109

124

     

1987

   

2014

Private

Jan

   

172

   

166

183

Feb

   

232

   

188

175

Mar

   

249

   

225

223

Apr

   

338

   

330

313

May

   

226

   

236

238

Jun

   

172

   

286

272

Jul

   

347

   

249

243

Aug

   

171

   

213

209

Sep

   

228

   

250

235

Oct

   

492

   

221

218

Nov

   

232

   

423

414

Dec

   

294

   

329

319

     

1988

   

2015

Private

Jan

   

94

   

201

202

Feb

   

453

   

266

261

Mar

   

276

   

119

117

Apr

   

245

   

221

206

May

   

229

   

280

262

Jun

   

363

   

Jul

   

222

   

Aug

   

124

   

Sep

   

339

   

Oct

   

268

   

Nov

   

339

   

Dec

   

290

   

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/

Charts numbered from I-38 to I-41 from the database of the Bureau of Labor Statistics provide a comparison of payroll survey data for the contractions and expansions in the 1980s and after 2007. Chart I-38 provides total nonfarm payroll jobs from 2001 to 2013. The sharp decline in total nonfarm jobs during the contraction after 2007 has been followed by initial stagnation and then inadequate growth in 2012 and 2013-2015 while population growth continued.

clip_image035

Chart I-38, US, Total Nonfarm Payroll Jobs SA 2001-2015

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-39 provides total nonfarm jobs SA from 1979 to 1989. Recovery is strong throughout the decade with the economy growing at trend over the entire economic cycle.

clip_image036

Chart I-39, US, Total Nonfarm Payroll Jobs SA 1979-1989

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Most job creation in the US is by the private sector. Chart I-40 shows the sharp destruction of private payroll jobs during the contraction after 2007. There has been growth after 2010 but insufficient to recover higher levels of employment prevailing before the contraction. At current rates, recovery of employment may spread over several years in contrast with past expansions of the business cycle in the US.

clip_image037

Chart I-40, US, Total Private Payroll Jobs SA 2001-2015

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

In contrast, growth of private payroll jobs in the US recovered vigorously during the expansion in 1983 through 1985, as shown in Chart I-41. Rapid growth of creation of private jobs continued throughout the 1980s.

clip_image038

Chart I-41, US, Total Private Payroll Jobs SA 1979-1989

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Types of jobs created, and not only the pace of job creation, may be important. Aspects of growth of payroll jobs from May 2014 to May 2015, not seasonally adjusted (NSA), are in Table I-9. Total nonfarm employment increased by 3,123,000 (row A, column Change), consisting of growth of total private employment by 3,022,000 (row B, column Change) and increase by 101,000 of government employment (row C, column Change). Monthly average growth of private payroll employment has been 251,833, which is mediocre relative to 24 to 30 million in job stress, while total nonfarm employment has grown on average by only 260,250 per month, which does not significantly reduce job stress with 156,250 new entrants per month in the labor force. These monthly rates of job creation net of the demands of new entrants in the labor force perpetuate unemployment and underemployment. Manufacturing employment increased by 174,000, at the monthly rate of 14,500 while private service providing employment grew by 2,604,000, at the monthly average rate of 217,000. An important feature in Table I-9 is that jobs in professional and business services increased by 686,000 with temporary help services increasing by 175,000. This episode of jobless recovery is characterized by part-time jobs and creation of jobs that are inferior to those that have been lost. Monetary and fiscal stimuli fail to increase consumption in a fractured job market. The segment leisure and hospitality added 451,000 jobs in 12 months. An important characteristic is that the loss of government jobs has stabilized in federal government with increase of 9,000 jobs while states added 30,000 jobs and local government added 62,000 jobs. Local government provides the bulk of government jobs, 14.472 million, while federal government provides 2.735 million and states’ government 5.111 million.

Table I-9, US, Employees in Nonfarm Payrolls Not Seasonally Adjusted, in Thousands

 

May 2014

May 2015

Change

A Total Nonfarm

138,297

142,420

3,123

B Total Private

117,080

120,102

3,022

B1 Goods Producing

19,175

19,593

418

B1a

Manufacturing

12,140

12,314

174

B2 Private service providing

97,905

100,509

2,604

B2a Wholesale Trade

5,827

5,915

88

B2b Retail Trade

15,236

15,571

335

B2c Transportation & Warehousing

4,613

4,743

130

B2d Financial Activities

7,940

8,101

161

B2e Professional and Business Services

19,002

19,688

686

B2e1 Temporary help services

2,730

2,905

175

B2f Health Care & Social Assistance

18,028

18,551

523

B2g Leisure & Hospitality

14,942

15,393

451

C Government

22,217

22,318

101

C1 Federal

2,726

2,735

9

C2 State

5,081

5,111

30

C3 Local

14,410

14,472

62

Note: A = B+C, B = B1 + B2, C=C1 + C2 + C3

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/

Greater detail on the types of jobs created is provided in Table I-10 with data for Apr 2015 and

May 2015. Strong seasonal effects are shown by the significant difference between seasonally adjusted (SA) and not-seasonally-adjusted (NSA) data. The purpose of adjusting for seasonality is to isolate nonseasonal effects. The 280,000 SA total nonfarm jobs created in May 2015 relative to

Apr 2015 actually correspond to increase of 970,000 jobs NSA, as shown in row A. Most of this difference in Jan 2015 is due to the necessary benchmark and seasonal adjustments in the beginning of every year. The 262,000 total private payroll jobs SA created in May 2015 relative to Apr 2015 actually correspond to increase of 995,000 jobs NSA. The analysis of NSA job creation in the prior Table I-9 does show improvement over the 12 months ending in May 2015 that is not clouded by seasonal variations but is inadequate number of jobs created. In fact, the 12-month rate of job creation without seasonal adjustment is stronger indication of marginal improvement in the US job market but that is insufficient in even making a dent in about 30 million people unemployed or underemployed. Benchmark and seasonal adjustments affect comparability of data over time.

Table I-10, US, Employees on Nonfarm Payrolls and Selected Industry Detail, Thousands, SA and NSA

 

Apr    2015 SA

May 2015 SA

Apr    2015 NSA

May   2015 NSA

A Total Nonfarm

141,399

141,679

280

141,450

142,420

970

B Total Private

119,476

119,738

262

119,107

120,102

995

B1 Goods Producing

19,561

19,567

6

19,380

19,593

213

B1a Constr.

6,370

6,387

17

6,255

6,441

186

B Mfg

12,328

12,335

7

12,273

12,314

41

B2 Private Service Providing

99,915

100,171

256

99,727

100,509

782

B2a Wholesale Trade

5,901

5,905

4

5,889

5,915

26

B2b Retail Trade

15,601

15,632

31

15,429

15,571

142

B2c Couriers     & Mess.

591

590

-1

557

562

5

B2d Health-care & Social Assistance

18,462

18,520

58

18,465

18,551

86

B2De Profess. & Business Services

19,613

19,676

63

19,602

19,688

86

B2De1 Temp Help Services

2,883

2,903

20

2,826

2,905

79

B2f Leisure & Hospit.

15,049

15,106

57

14,983

15,393

410

Notes: ∆: Absolute Change; Constr.: Construction; Mess.: Messengers; Temp: Temporary; Hospit.: Hospitality. SA aggregates do not add because of seasonal adjustment.

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/

Chart I-42 provides output of durable manufacturing from 1972 to 2015. Output fell sharply during the global recession, recovering at relatively high pace. Output is lower than extrapolation of trend.

clip_image039

Chart I-42, US, Output of Durable Manufacturing, 1972-2015

Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve

http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/g17/Current/default.htm

Manufacturing jobs not seasonally adjusted increased 174,000 from May 2014 to
May 2015 or at the average monthly rate of 14,500. There are effects of the weaker economy and international trade together with the yearly adjustment of labor statistics. Industrial production decreased 0.3 percent in Apr 2015 and decreased 0.3 percent in Mar 2015 after decreasing 0.1 percent in Feb 2015, with all data seasonally adjusted. The Federal Reserve completed its annual revision of industrial production and capacity utilization on Mar 28, 2014 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/g17/revisions/Current/DefaultRev.htm). The report of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System states (http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/g17/Current/default.htm):

“Industrial production decreased 0.3 percent in April for its fifth consecutive monthly loss. Manufacturing output was unchanged in April after recording an upwardly revised gain of 0.3 percent in March. In April, the index for mining moved down 0.8 percent, its fourth consecutive monthly decrease; a sharp fall in oil and gas well drilling has more than accounted for the overall decline in mining this year. The output of utilities fell 1.3 percent in April. At 105.2 percent of its 2007 average, total industrial production in April was 1.9 percent above its year-earlier level. Capacity utilization for the industrial sector decreased 0.4 percentage point in April to 78.2 percent, a rate that is 1.9 percentage points below its long-run (1972–2014) average.” In the six months ending in Apr 2015, United States national industrial production accumulated change of 0.0 percent at the annual equivalent rate of 0.0 percent, which is lower than growth of 1.9 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr 2015. Excluding growth of 1.1 percent in Nov 2014, growth in the remaining five months from Nov 2014 to Apr 2015 accumulated to minus 1.1 percent or minus 2.6 percent annual equivalent. Industrial production declined in five of the past six months. Industrial production contracted at annual equivalent 2.8 percent in the most recent quarter from Feb 2015 to Apr 2015 and expanded at 2.8 percent in the prior quarter Nov 2014 to Jan 2015. Business equipment accumulated growth of 0.0 percent in the six months from Nov 2014 to Apr 2015 at the annual equivalent rate of 0.0 percent, which is lower than growth of 2.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr 2015. The Fed analyzes capacity utilization of total industry in its report (http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/g17/Current/default.htm): “Capacity utilization for the industrial sector decreased 0.4 percentage point in April to 78.2 percent, a rate that is 1.9 percentage points below its long-run (1972–2014) average.” United States industry apparently decelerated to a lower growth rate followed by possible acceleration and weakening growth in past months.

Manufacturing fell 21.9 from the peak in Jun 2007 to the trough in Apr 2009 and increased by 25.1 percent from the trough in Apr 2009 to Dec 2014. Manufacturing grew 25.7 percent from the trough in Apr 2009 to Apr 2015. Manufacturing output in Apr 2015 is 1.9 percent below the peak in Jun 2007. The US maintained growth at 3.0 percent on average over entire cycles with expansions at higher rates compensating for contractions. Growth at trend in the entire cycle from IVQ2007 to IQ2015 would have accumulated to 23.9 percent. GDP in IQ2015 would be $18,574.8 billion (in constant dollars of 2009) if the US had grown at trend, which is higher by $2,310.7 billion than actual $16,264.1 billion. There are about two trillion dollars of GDP less than at trend, explaining the 24.7 million unemployed or underemployed equivalent to actual unemployment/underemployment of 14.9 percent of the effective labor force (Section I and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/quite-high-equity-valuations-and.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/04/volatility-of-valuations-of-financial.html). US GDP in IQ2015 is 12.4 percent lower than at trend. US GDP grew from $14,991.8 billion in IVQ2007 in constant dollars to $16,264.1 billion in IQ2015 or 8.5 percent at the average annual equivalent rate of 1.1 percent. Cochrane (2014Jul2) estimates US GDP at more than 10 percent below trend. The US missed the opportunity to grow at higher rates during the expansion and it is difficult to catch up because growth rates in the final periods of expansions tend to decline. The US missed the opportunity for recovery of output and employment always afforded in the first four quarters of expansion from recessions. Zero interest rates and quantitative easing were not required or present in successful cyclical expansions and in secular economic growth at 3.0 percent per year and 2.0 percent per capita as measured by Lucas (2011May). There is cyclical uncommonly slow growth in the US instead of allegations of secular stagnation. There is similar behavior in manufacturing. There is classic research on analyzing deviations of output from trend (see for example Schumpeter 1939, Hicks 1950, Lucas 1975, Sargent and Sims 1977). The long-term trend is growth at average 3.3 percent per year from Apr 1919 to Apr 2015. Growth at 3.3 percent per year would raise the NSA index of manufacturing output from 99.2392 in Dec 2007 to 125.9172 in Apr 2015. The actual index NSA in Apr 2015 is 101.1122, which is 19.7 percent below trend. Manufacturing output grew at average 2.4 percent between Dec 1986 and Dec 2014. Using trend growth of 2.4 percent per year, the index would increase to 118.0899 in Apr 2015. The output of manufacturing at 101.1122 in Apr 2015 is 14.4 percent below trend under this alternative calculation. Table I-13 provides national income by industry without capital consumption adjustment (WCCA). “Private industries” or economic activities have share of 87.7 percent in IVQ2014. Most of US national income is in the form of services. In May 2015, there were 142.420 million nonfarm jobs NSA in the US, according to estimates of the establishment survey of the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) (http://www.bls.gov/news.release/empsit.nr0.htm Table B-1). Total private jobs of 120.102 million NSA in May 2015 accounted for 84.3 percent of total nonfarm jobs of 142.420 million, of which 12.314 million, or 10.3 percent of total private jobs and 8.6 percent of total nonfarm jobs, were in manufacturing. Private service-providing jobs were 100.509 million NSA in May 2015, or 70.6 percent of total nonfarm jobs and 83.7 percent of total private-sector jobs. Manufacturing has share of 11.3 percent in US national income in IVQ2014 and durable goods 6.5 percent, as shown in Table I-13. Most income in the US originates in services. Subsidies and similar measures designed to increase manufacturing jobs will not increase economic growth and employment and may actually reduce growth by diverting resources away from currently employment-creating activities because of the drain of taxation.

Table I-13, US, National Income without Capital Consumption Adjustment by Industry, Seasonally Adjusted Annual Rates, Billions of Dollars, % of Total

 

SAAR
IVQ2014

% Total

SAAR IQ2015

% Total

National Income WCCA

15,599.6

100.0

15,891.4

100.0

Domestic Industries

15,407.1

98.8

15,729.4

99.0

Private Industries

13,674.0

87.7

13,985.1

88.0

    Agriculture

167.6

1.1

   

    Mining

266.1

1.7

   

    Utilities

212.8

1.4

   

    Construction

699.9

4.5

   

    Manufacturing

1766.7

11.3

   

       Durable Goods

1019.5

6.5

   

       Nondurable Goods

747.1

4.8

   

    Wholesale Trade

955.8

6.1

   

     Retail Trade

1085.7

7.0

   

     Transportation & WH

478.8

3.1

   

     Information

577.8

3.7

   

     Finance, Insurance, RE

2770.6

17.8

   

     Professional & Business Services

2107.9

13.5

   

     Education, Health Care

1516.3

9.7

   

     Arts, Entertainment

628.4

4.0

   

     Other Services

439.6

2.8

   

Government

1733.1

11.1

1744.3

11.0

Rest of the World

192.5

1.2

162.1

1.0

Notes: SSAR: Seasonally-Adjusted Annual Rate; WCCA: Without Capital Consumption Adjustment by Industry; WH: Warehousing; RE, includes rental and leasing: Real Estate; Art, Entertainment includes recreation, accommodation and food services; BS: business services

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

The NBER dates recessions in the US from peaks to troughs as: IQ80 to IIIQ80, IIIQ81 to IV82 and IVQ07 to IIQ09 (http://www.nber.org/cycles/cyclesmain.html). Table I-12 provides total annual level nonfarm employment in the US for the 1980s and the 2000s, which is different from 12-month comparisons. Nonfarm jobs rose by 4.859 million from 1982 to 1984, or 5.4 percent, and continued rapid growth in the rest of the decade. In contrast, nonfarm jobs are down by 7.661 million in 2010 relative to 2007 and fell by 958,000 in 2010 relative to 2009 even after six quarters of GDP growth. Monetary and fiscal stimuli have failed in increasing growth to rates required for mitigating job stress. The initial growth impulse reflects a flatter growth curve in the current expansion. Nonfarm jobs declined from 137.936 million in 2007 to 136.393 million in 2013, by 1.543 million or 1.1 percent. Nonfarm jobs increased from 137.936 million in 2007 to 139.042 million in 2014, by 1.106 million or 0.8 percent. The US noninstitutional population or in condition to work increased from 231.867 million in 2007 to 247.947 million in 2014, by 16.080 million or 6.9 percent. The ratio of nonfarm jobs of 137.936 million in 2007 to the noninstitutional population of 231.867 was 59.5. Nonfarm jobs in 2014 corresponding to the ratio of 59.5 of nonfarm jobs/noninstitutional population would be 147.528 million (0.595x247.947). The difference between actual nonfarm jobs of 139.042 million in 2014 and nonfarm jobs of 147.528 million that are equivalent to 59.5 percent of the noninstitutional population as in 2007 is 8.486 million. The proper explanation for this loss of work opportunities is not in secular stagnation but in cyclically slow growth. The US maintained growth at 3.0 percent on average over entire cycles with expansions at higher rates compensating for contractions. Growth at trend in the entire cycle from IVQ2007 to IQ2015 would have accumulated to 23.9 percent. GDP in IQ2015 would be $18,574.8 billion (in constant dollars of 2009) if the US had grown at trend, which is higher by $2,310.7 billion than actual $16,264.1 billion. There are about two trillion dollars of GDP less than at trend, explaining the 24.7 million unemployed or underemployed equivalent to actual unemployment/underemployment of 14.9 percent of the effective labor force (Section I and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/quite-high-equity-valuations-and.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/04/volatility-of-valuations-of-financial.html). US GDP in IQ2015 is 12.4 percent lower than at trend. US GDP grew from $14,991.8 billion in IVQ2007 in constant dollars to $16,264.1 billion in IQ2015 or 8.5 percent at the average annual equivalent rate of 1.1 percent. Cochrane (2014Jul2) estimates US GDP at more than 10 percent below trend. The US missed the opportunity to grow at higher rates during the expansion and it is difficult to catch up because growth rates in the final periods of expansions tend to decline. The US missed the opportunity for recovery of output and employment always afforded in the first four quarters of expansion from recessions. Zero interest rates and quantitative easing were not required or present in successful cyclical expansions and in secular economic growth at 3.0 percent per year and 2.0 percent per capita as measured by Lucas (2011May). There is cyclical uncommonly slow growth in the US instead of allegations of secular stagnation. There is similar behavior in manufacturing. There is classic research on analyzing deviations of output from trend (see for example Schumpeter 1939, Hicks 1950, Lucas 1975, Sargent and Sims 1977). The long-term trend is growth at average 3.3 percent per year from Apr 1919 to Apr 2015. Growth at 3.3 percent per year would raise the NSA index of manufacturing output from 99.2392 in Dec 2007 to 125.9172 in Apr 2015. The actual index NSA in Apr 2015 is 101.1122, which is 19.7 percent below trend. Manufacturing output grew at average 2.4 percent between Dec 1986 and Dec 2014. Using trend growth of 2.4 percent per year, the index would increase to 118.0899 in Apr 2015. The output of manufacturing at 101.1122 in Apr 2015 is 14.4 percent below trend under this alternative calculation.

Table I-12, US, Total Nonfarm Employment in Thousands

Year

Total Nonfarm

Year

Total Nonfarm

1980

90,533

2000

132,019

1981

91,297

2001

132,074

1982

89,689

2002

130,628

1983

90,295

2003

130,318

1984

94,548

2004

131,749

1985

97,532

2005

134,005

1986

99,500

2006

136,398

1987

102,116

2007

137,936

1988

105,378

2008

137,170

1989

108,051

2009

131,233

1990

109,527

2010

130,275

1991

108,427

2011

131,842

1992

108,802

2012

134,104

1993

110,935

2013

136,393

1994

114,398

2014

139,042

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/

Chart I-43 provides annual nonfarm jobs in the US not seasonally adjusted from 2000 to 2014. Cyclically slow growth in the expansion since IIIQ2009 has not been sufficient to recover nonfarm jobs. Because of population growth, there are 8.486 million fewer nonfarm jobs in the US in 2014 than in 2007.

clip_image040

Chart I-43, US, Annual Nonfarm Jobs, NSA, Thousands, 2000-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/

Chart I-44 provides annual nonfarm jobs in the US not seasonally adjusted from 1980 to 1993. Much more rapid cyclical growth as in other expansions historically allowed steady and rapid growth of nonfarm job opportunities even with similarly dynamic population growth.

clip_image041

Chart I-44, US, Annual Nonfarm Jobs, NSA, Thousands, 1980-1994

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov

The highest average yearly percentage of unemployed to the labor force since 1940 was 14.6 percent in 1940 followed by 9.9 percent in 1941, 8.5 percent in 1975, 9.7 percent in 1982 and 9.6 percent in 1983 (ftp://ftp.bls.gov/pub/special.requests/lf/aa2006/pdf/cpsaat1.pdf). The rate of unemployment remained at high levels in the 1930s, rising from 3.2 percent in 1929 to 22.9 percent in 1932 in one estimate and 23.6 percent in another with real wages increasing by 16.4 percent (Margo 1993, 43; see Pelaez and Pelaez, Regulation of Banks and Finance (2009b), 214-5). There are alternative estimates of 17.2 percent or 9.5 percent for 1940 with real wages increasing by 44 percent. Employment declined sharply during the 1930s. The number of hours worked remained in 1939 at 29 percent below the level of 1929 (Cole and Ohanian 1999). Private hours worked fell in 1939 to 25 percent of the level in 1929. The policy of encouraging collusion through the National Industrial Recovery Act (NIRA), to maintain high prices, together with the National Labor Relations Act (NLRA), to maintain high wages, prevented the US economy from recovering employment levels until Roosevelt abandoned these policies toward the end of the 1930s (for review of the literature analyzing the Great Depression see Pelaez and Pelaez, Regulation of Banks and Finance (2009b), 198-217).

The Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) makes yearly revisions of its establishment survey (Harris 2011BA):

“With the release of data for January 2011, the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) introduced its annual revision of national estimates of employment, hours, and earnings from the Current Employment Statistics (CES) monthly survey of nonfarm establishments.  Each year, the CES survey realigns its sample-based estimates to incorporate universe counts of employment—a process known as benchmarking.  Comprehensive counts of employment, or benchmarks, are derived primarily from unemployment insurance (UI) tax reports that nearly all employers are required to file with State Workforce Agencies.”

The number of not seasonally adjusted total private jobs in the US in Dec 2010 is 108.464 million, declining to 106.079 million in Jan 2011, or by 2.385 million, because of the adjustment of a different benchmark and not actual job losses. The not seasonally adjusted number of total private jobs in Dec 1984 is 80.250 million, declining to 78.704 million in Jan 1985, or by 1.546 million for the similar adjustment. Table I-13 attempts to measure job losses and gains in the recessions and expansions of 1981-1985 and 2007-2011. The final ten rows provide job creation from May 1983 to May 1984 and from May 2010 to May 2011, that is, at equivalent stages of the recovery from two comparable strong recessions. The row “Change ∆%” for May 1983 to May 1984 shows an increase of total nonfarm jobs by 4.9 percent and of 5.9 percent for total private jobs. The row “Change ∆%” for May 2010 to May 2011 shows an increase of total nonfarm jobs by 0.7 percent and of 1.7 percent for total private jobs. The last two rows of Table 7 provide a calculation of the number of jobs that would have been created from May 2010 to May 2011 if the rate of job creation had been the same as from May 1983 to May 1984. If total nonfarm jobs had grown between May 2010 and May 2011 by 4.9 percent, as between May 1983 and May 1984, 6.409 million jobs would have been created in the past 12 months for a difference of 5.457 million more total nonfarm jobs relative to 0.952 million jobs actually created. If total private jobs had grown between May 2010 and May 2011 by 5.9 percent as between May 1983 and May 1984, 6.337 million private jobs would have been created for a difference of 4.539 million more total private jobs relative to 1.798 million jobs actually created.

Table I-13, US, Total Nonfarm and Total Private Jobs Destroyed and Subsequently Created in Two Recessions IIIQ1981-IVQ1982 and IVQ2007-IIQ2009, Thousands and Percent

 

Total Nonfarm Jobs

Total Private Jobs

06/1981 #

92,288

75,969

11/1982 #

89,482

73,260

Change #

-2,806

-2,709

Change ∆%

-3.0

-3.6

12/1982 #

89,383

73,185

05/1984 #

94,471

78,049

Change #

5,088

4,864

Change ∆%

5.7

6.6

11/2007 #

139,090

116,291

05/2009 #

131,626

108,601

Change %

-7,464

-7,690

Change ∆%

-5.4

-6.6

12/2009 #

130,178

107,338

05/2011 #

131,753

108,494

Change #

1,575

1,156

Change ∆%

1.2

1.1

05/1983 #

90,005

73,667

05/1984 #

94,471

78,049

Change #

4,466

4,382

Change ∆%

4.9

5.9

05/2010 #

130,801

107,405

05/2011 #

131,753

109,203

Change #

952

1,798

Change ∆%

0.7

1.7

Change # by ∆% as in 05/1984 to 05/1985

6,409*

6,337**

Difference in Jobs that Would Have Been Created

5,457 =
6,409-952

4,539 =
6,337-1,798

*[(130,801x1.049)-130,801] = 6,409 thousand

**[(107,405)x1.059 – 107,405] = 6,337 thousand

Source: http://www.bls.gov/data/

IB Stagnating Real Wages. The wage bill is the product of average weekly hours times the earnings per hour. Table IB-1 provides the estimates by the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) of earnings per hour seasonally adjusted, increasing from $24.34/hour in Mar 2014 to $24.86/hour in Mar 2015, or by 2.1 percent. There has been disappointment about the pace of wage increases because of rising food and energy costs that inhibit consumption and thus sales and similar concern about growth of consumption that accounts for about 68.6 percent of GDP (Table I-10 at http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/06/dollar-revaluation-squeezing-corporate.html). Growth of consumption by decreasing savings by means of controlling interest rates in what is called financial repression may not be lasting and sound for personal finances (See Pelaez and Pelaez, Globalization and the State, Vol. II (2008c), 81-6, Pelaez (1975), Section IB and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/dollar-devaluation-and-carry-trade.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/04/volatility-of-valuations-of-financial.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/03/global-competitive-devaluation-rules.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/02/job-creation-and-monetary-policy-twenty.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/12/valuations-of-risk-financial-assets.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/11/valuations-of-risk-financial-assets.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/11/growth-uncertainties-mediocre-cyclical.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/09/geopolitical-and-financial-risks.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/08/fluctuating-financial-valuations.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/06/financial-indecision-mediocre-cyclical.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/06/financial-instability-mediocre-cyclical.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/03/financial-uncertainty-mediocre-cyclical.html

http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/02/mediocre-cyclical-united-states.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/12/collapse-of-united-states-dynamism-of.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/11/global-financial-risk-mediocre-united.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/09/mediocre-and-decelerating-united-states.html

http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/09/increasing-interest-rate-risk.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/08/risks-of-steepening-yield-curve-and.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/06/tapering-quantitative-easing-policy-and.html

http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/06/mediocre-united-states-economic-growth.html

http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/04/mediocre-and-decelerating-united-states.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/03/mediocre-gdp-growth-at-16-to-20-percent.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/12/mediocre-and-decelerating-united-states_24.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/12/mediocre-and-decelerating-united-states.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/09/historically-sharper-recoveries-from.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/09/collapse-of-united-states-dynamism-of.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/07/recovery-without-jobs-stagnating-real.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/mediocre-recovery-without-jobs.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/04/mediocre-growth-with-high-unemployment.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/04/mediocre-economic-growth-falling-real.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/03/mediocre-economic-growth-flattening.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/01/mediocre-economic-growth-financial.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/12/slow-growth-falling-real-disposable.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/11/us-growth-standstill-falling-real.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/10/slow-growth-driven-by-reducing-savings.html). Average hourly earnings seasonally adjusted increased 0.3 percent from $24.88 in Apr 2015 to $24.96 in May 2015. Average private weekly earnings increased $19.24 from $841.88 in May 2014 to $861.12 in May 2015 or 2.3 percent and increased from $858.36 in

Apr 2015 to $861.12 in May 2015 or 0.3 percent. The inflation-adjusted wage bill can only be calculated for Apr, which is the most recent month for which there are estimates of the consumer price index. Earnings per hour (not-seasonally-adjusted (NSA)) rose from $24.40 in Apr 2014 to $24.92 in Apr 2015 or by 2.1 percent (http://www.bls.gov/data/; see Table IB-3 below). Data NSA are more suitable for comparison over a year. Average weekly hours NSA were 34.4 in Apr 2014 and 34.4 in Apr 2015 (http://www.bls.gov/data/; see Table IB-2 below). The wage bill increased 2.1 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr 2015:

{[(wage bill in Apr 2015)/(wage bill in Apr 2014)]-1}100 =

{[($24.92x34.4)/($24.40x34.4)]-1]}100

= {[($857.25)/($839.36]-1}100 = 2.1%

CPI inflation was minus 0.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr 2015 (http://www.bls.gov/cpi/) for an inflation-adjusted wage-bill change of 2.2 percent :{[(1.021/0.998)-1]100 = 2.3 %} (see Table IB-5 below for Apr 2015 with minor rounding difference). The wage bill for Apr 2015 before inflation adjustment increased 2.3 percent relative to the wage bill for May 2014:

{[(wage bill in May 2015)/(wage bill in May 2014)]-1}100 =

{[($24.87x34.4)/($24.31x34.4)]-1]}100

= {[$855.52)/$836.26]-1}100 = 2.3%

Average hourly earnings increased 2.3 percent from May 2014 to May 2015 {[($24.87/$24.31) – 1]100 = 2.3%} while hours worked changed 0.0 percent {[(34.4/34.4) – 1]100 = 0.0%}. The increase of the wage bill is the product of the increase of hourly earnings of 2.3 percent and change of hours worked of 0.0 percent {[(1.023x1.000) -1]100 = 2.3%}.

Energy and food price increases are similar to a “silent tax” that is highly regressive, harming the most those with lowest incomes. There are concerns that the wage bill would deteriorate in purchasing power because of renewed raw materials shocks in the form of increases in prices of commodities such as the 31.1 percent steady increase in the DJ-UBS Commodity Index from Jul 2, 2010 to Sep 2, 2011. The charts of four commodity price indexes by Bloomberg show steady increase since Jul 2, 2010 that was interrupted briefly only in Nov 2010 with the sovereign issues in Europe triggered by Ireland; in Mar 2011 by the earthquake and tsunami in Japan; and in the beginning of May 2011 by the decline in oil prices and sovereign risk difficulties in Europe (http://www.bloomberg.com/markets/commodities/futures/). Renewed risk aversion because of the sovereign risks in Europe had reduced the rate of increase of the DJ UBS commodity index to 10.2 percent on May 2, 2014, relative to Jul 2, 2010 (see Table VI-4) but there has been a shift in investor preferences into equities. Inflation has been rising in waves with carry trades driven by zero interest rates to commodity futures during periods of risk appetite with interruptions during risk aversion (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/interest-rate-policy-and-dollar.html). Inflation-adjusted wages fall sharply during carry trades from zero interest rates to long positions in commodity futures during periods of risk appetite.

Table IB-1, US, Earnings per Hour and Average Weekly Hours SA

Earnings per Hour

May 2014

Mar 2015

Apr 2015

May 2015

Total Private

$24.11

$24.85

$24.88

$24.96

Goods Producing

$25.61

$26.05

$26.09

$26.12

Service Providing

$24.11

$24.56

$24.60

$24.69

Average Weekly Earnings

       

Total Private

$841.88

$857.33

$858.36

$861.12

Goods Producing

$1,039.77

$1,052.42

$1,051.43

$1,052.64

Service Providing

$802.86

$820.30

$819.18

$824.65

Average Weekly Hours

       

Total Private

34.5

34.5

34.5

34.5

Goods Producing

40.6

40.4

40.3

40.3

Service Providing

33.3

33.4

33.3

33.4

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/

Average weekly hours in Table IB-2 fell from 34.9 in Dec 2007 at the beginning of the contraction to 33.8 in Jun 2009, which was the last month of the contraction. Average weekly hours rose to 34.4 in Dec 2011 and oscillated to 34.9 in Dec 2012 and 34.7 in Dec 2013. Average weekly hours of all employees decreased to 34.6 in Dec 2014 and 34.4 in May 2015.

Table IB-2, US, Average Weekly Hours of All Employees, NSA 2006-2015

Year

Jan

Feb

Mar

Apr

May

Jun

Jul

Aug

Sep

Oct

Nov

Dec

Annual

2006

   

34.2

34.6

34.3

34.6

34.9

34.6

34.5

34.9

34.4

34.6

 

2007

34.1

34.1

34.3

34.7

34.4

34.7

34.9

34.7

35.0

34.5

34.5

34.9

34.6

2008

34.1

34.2

34.7

34.4

34.4

34.9

34.5

34.6

34.4

34.4

34.6

34.1

34.4

2009

33.8

34.2

33.9

33.6

33.7

33.8

33.8

34.3

33.7

33.8

34.2

33.9

33.9

2010

33.7

33.6

33.8

34.0

34.4

34.1

34.2

34.7

34.1

34.3

34.2

34.2

34.1

2011

34.2

34.0

34.1

34.2

34.6

34.4

34.4

34.4

34.4

34.8

34.3

34.4

34.4

2012

34.5

34.2

34.2

34.6

34.2

34.4

34.8

34.5

34.9

34.3

34.3

34.9

34.5

2013

34.0

34.2

34.3

34.3

34.3

34.9

34.3

34.5

34.9

34.4

34.4

34.7

34.4

2014

34.0

34.4

34.7

34.4

34.4

34.9

34.5

34.6

34.5

34.5

34.9

34.6

34.5

2015

34.2

34.6

34.7

34.4

34.4

               

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/

Chart IB-1 provides average weekly hours monthly from Mar 2006 to May 2014. Average weekly hours remained relatively stable in the period before the contraction and fell sharply during the contraction as business could not support lower production with the same labor input. Average weekly hours rose rapidly during the expansion; stabilized at a level below that prevailing before the contraction; and are around the level before the contraction.

clip_image042

Chart IB-1, US, Average Weekly Hours of All Employees, SA 2006-2015

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Calculations of inflation-adjusted average hourly earnings using BLS data are in Table IB-3. The final column of Table IB-3 (“12-Month Real ∆%”) provides inflation-adjusted average hourly earnings of all employees in the US. Average hourly earnings rose above inflation throughout the first nine months of 2007 just before the global recession that began in the final quarter of 2007 when average hourly earnings began to lose to inflation. In contrast, average hourly earnings of all US workers have risen less than inflation in four months in 2010 and in all but the first month in 2011 and the loss accelerated at 1.8 percent in Sep 2011, declining to a real loss of 1.1 percent in Feb 2012 and 0.6 percent in Mar 2012. There was a gain of 0.5 percent in Apr 2012 in inflation-adjusted average hourly earnings but another fall of 0.6 percent in May 2012 followed by increases of 0.3 percent in Jun and 1.0 percent in Jul 2012. Real hourly earnings stagnated in the 12 months ending in Aug 2012 with increase of only 0.1 percent, and increased 0.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Sep 2012. Real hourly earnings fell 1.3 percent in Oct 2012 and gained 1.0 percent in Dec 2012 but declined 0.3 percent in Jan 2013 and stagnated at change of 0.1 percent in Feb 2013. Real hourly earnings increased 0.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Mar 2013 and 0.2 percent in Apr 2013, increasing 0.6 percent in May 2013. In Jun 2013, real hourly earnings increased 1.0 percent relative to Jun 2012. Real hourly earnings fell 0.6 percent in the 12 months ending in Jul 2013 and increased 0.8 percent in the 12 months ending in Aug 2013. Real hourly earnings increased 1.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Oct 2013 and 1.0 percent in Nov 2013. Real hourly earnings increased 0.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Dec 2013. Real hourly earnings increased 0.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Jan 2014 and 1.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Feb 2014. Real hourly earnings increased 1.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Mar 2014. Real hourly earnings changed 0.0 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr 2014. Real hourly earnings stagnated at 0.0 percent in the 12 months ending in May 2014. Real hourly earnings fell 0.1 percent in the 12 months ending in Jun 2014. Real hourly earnings increased 0.1 percent in the 12 months ending in Jul 2014 and increased 0.5 percent in the 12 months ending in Aug 2014. Real hourly earnings fell 0.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Sep 2014 and increased 0.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Oct 2014. Real hourly earnings increased 1.5 percent in the 12 months ending in Nov 2014. Real hourly earnings increased 0.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Dec 2014 and increased 2.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Jan 2015. Real hourly earnings increased 2.0 percent in the 12 months ending in Feb 2015 and 2.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Mar 2015. Real hourly earnings increased 2.1 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr 2015. Real hourly earnings are oscillating in part because of world inflation waves caused by carry trades from zero interest rates to commodity futures (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/interest-rate-policy-and-dollar.html) and in part because of the collapse of hiring (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/fluctuating-valuations-of-financial.html) originating in weak economic growth (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/06/dollar-revaluation-squeezing-corporate.html).

Table IB-3, US, Average Hourly Earnings Nominal and Inflation Adjusted, Dollars and % NSA

 

AHE ALL

12 Month-
Nominal
∆%

∆% 12 Month CPI

12-Month
Real ∆%

2007

       

Jan*

$20.69*

4.2*

2.1

2.1*

Feb*

$20.77*

4.1*

2.4

1.7*

Mar

$20.80

3.6

2.8

0.8

Apr

$21.03

3.3

2.6

0.7

May

$20.82

3.8

2.7

1.1

Jun

$20.81

3.8

2.7

1.1

Jul

$20.97

3.4

2.4

1.0

Aug

$20.83

3.5

2.0

1.5

Sep

$21.17

4.0

2.8

1.2

Oct

$21.05

2.6

3.5

-0.9

Nov

$21.12

3.3

4.3

-1.0

Dec

$21.35

3.6

4.1

-0.5

2010

       

Jan

$22.53

2.0

2.6

-0.6

Feb

$22.59

1.4

2.1

-0.7

Mar

$22.49

1.1

2.3

-1.2

Apr

$22.54

1.8

2.2

-0.4

May

$22.61

2.5

2.0

0.5

Jun

$22.35

1.7

1.1

0.6

Jul

$22.42

1.8

1.2

0.6

Aug

$22.55

1.7

1.1

0.6

Sep

$22.61

1.8

1.1

0.7

Oct

$22.70

1.9

1.2

0.7

Nov

$22.70

1.1

1.1

0.0

Dec

$22.77

1.7

1.5

0.2

2011

       

Jan

$23.17

2.8

1.6

1.2

Feb

$23.00

1.8

2.1

-0.3

Mar

$22.91

1.9

2.7

-0.8

Apr

$22.97

1.9

3.2

-1.3

May

$23.07

2.0

3.6

-1.5

Jun

$22.82

2.1

3.6

-1.4

Jul

$22.95

2.4

3.6

-1.2

Aug

$22.86

1.4

3.8

-2.3

Sep

$23.06

2.0

3.9

-1.8

Oct

$23.31

2.7

3.5

-0.8

Nov

$23.16

2.0

3.4

-1.4

Dec

$23.22

2.0

3.0

-1.0

2012

       

Jan

$23.57

1.7

2.9

-1.2

Feb

$23.41

1.8

2.9

-1.1

Mar

$23.40

2.1

2.7

-0.6

Apr

$23.62

2.8

2.3

0.5

May

$23.33

1.1

1.7

-0.6

Jun

$23.28

2.0

1.7

0.3

Jul

$23.49

2.4

1.4

1.0

Aug

$23.27

1.8

1.7

0.1

Sep

$23.68

2.7

2.0

0.7

Oct

$23.52

0.9

2.2

-1.3

Nov

$23.59

1.9

1.8

0.1

Dec

$23.85

2.7

1.7

1.0

2013

       

Jan

$23.88

1.3

1.6

-0.3

Feb

$23.91

2.1

2.0

0.1

Mar

$23.84

1.9

1.5

0.4

Apr

$23.92

1.3

1.1

0.2

May

$23.80

2.0

1.4

0.6

Jun

$23.93

2.8

1.8

1.0

Jul

$23.81

1.4

2.0

-0.6

Aug

$23.80

2.3

1.5

0.8

Sep

$24.17

2.1

1.2

0.9

Oct

$24.04

2.2

1.0

1.2

Nov

$24.11

2.2

1.2

1.0

Dec

$24.30

1.9

1.5

0.4

2014

       

Jan

$24.35

2.0

1.6

0.4

Feb

$24.58

2.8

1.1

1.7

Mar

$24.50

2.8

1.5

1.3

Apr

$24.40

2.0

2.0

0.0

May

$24.31

2.1

2.1

0.0

Jun

$24.42

2.0

2.1

-0.1

Jul

$24.31

2.1

2.0

0.1

Aug

$24.33

2.2

1.7

0.5

Sep

$24.50

1.4

1.7

-0.3

Oct

$24.53

2.0

1.7

0.3

Nov

$24.79

2.8

1.3

1.5

Dec

$24.60

1.2

0.8

0.4

2015

       

Jan

$24.89

2.2

-0.1

2.3

Feb

$25.06

2.0

0.0

2.0

Mar

$25.02

2.1

-0.1

2.2

Apr

$24.92

2.1

0.0

2.1

May

$24.87

2.3

-0.2

 

Note: AHE ALL: average hourly earnings of all employees; CPI: consumer price index; Real: adjusted by CPI inflation; NA: not available

*AHE of production and nonsupervisory employees because of unavailability of data for all employees for Jan-Feb 2006

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/

Calculations of inflation-adjusted average hourly earnings by the BLS are in Table IB-4. Average hourly earnings rose above inflation throughout the first nine months of 2007 just before the global recession that began in the final quarter of 2007 when average hourly earnings began to lose to inflation. In contrast, average hourly earnings of all US workers have risen less than inflation in five months in 2010 and in all but the first month in 2011 and the loss accelerated at 1.8 percent in Sep 2011, declining to a real loss of 1.1 percent in Feb 2012 and 0.5 percent in Mar 2012. There was a gain of 0.6 percent in Apr 2012 in inflation-adjusted average hourly earnings but another fall of 0.6 percent in May 2012 followed by increases of 0.3 percent in Jun and 0.9 percent in Jul 2012. Real hourly earnings stagnated in the 12 months ending in Aug 2012 with increase of only 0.1 percent, and increased 0.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Sep 2012. Real hourly earnings fell 1.2 percent in Oct 2012 and gained 1.0 percent in Dec 2012 but declined 0.3 percent in Jan 2013 and stagnated at change of 0.2 percent in Feb 2013. Real hourly earnings increased 0.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Mar 2013 and 0.2 percent in Apr 2013, increasing 0.7 percent in May 2013. In Jun 2013, real hourly earnings increased 1.1 percent relative to Jun 2012. Real hourly earnings fell 0.6 percent in the 12 months ending in Jul 2013 and increased 0.8 percent in the 12 months ending in Aug 2013. Real hourly earnings increased 1.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Oct 2013 and 0.9 percent in Nov 2013. Real hourly earnings increased 0.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Dec 2013. Real hourly earnings increased 0.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Jan 2014 and 1.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Feb 2014. Real hourly earnings increased 1.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Mar 2014. Real hourly changed 0.0 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr 2014. Real hourly changed 0.0 percent in the 12 months ending in May 2014. Real hourly earnings changed 0.0 percent in the 12 months ending in Jun 2014. Real hourly earnings increased 0.1 percent in the 12 months ending in Jul 2014 and increased 0.5 percent in the 12 months ending in Aug 2014. Real hourly earnings fell 0.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Sep 2014 and increased 0.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Oct 2014. Real hourly earnings increased 1.5 percent in the 12 months ending in Nov 2014 and 0.5 percent in the 12 months ending in Dec 2014. Real hourly earnings increased 2.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Jan 2015 and increased 2.0 percent in the 12 months ending in Feb 2014. Real hourly earnings increased 2.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Mar 2015 and increased 2.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr 2013. Real hourly earnings are oscillating in part because of world inflation waves caused by carry trades from zero interest rates to commodity futures (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/interest-rate-policy-and-dollar.html) and in part because of the collapse of hiring (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/fluctuating-valuations-of-financial.html) originating in weak economic growth (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/06/dollar-revaluation-squeezing-corporate.html).

Table IB-4, US, Average Hourly Earnings of All Employees NSA in Constant Dollars of 1982-1984

Year

Jan

Feb

Mar

Apr

May

Sep

Oct

Nov

Dec

2006

   

10.05

10.10

9.91

10.03

10.16

10.14

10.21

2007

10.22

10.21

10.13

10.17

10.01

10.15

10.07

10.05

10.16

2008

10.11

10.11

10.10

9.99

9.90

9.93

10.05

10.36

10.46

2009

10.46

10.50

10.46

10.38

10.31

10.29

10.31

10.38

10.37

2010

10.40

10.42

10.33

10.34

10.36

10.35

10.38

10.37

10.39

2011

10.52

10.39

10.25

10.21

10.21

10.16

10.29

10.24

10.29

2012

10.40

10.28

10.20

10.27

10.15

10.23

10.17

10.25

10.39

∆%12M

-1.1

-1.1

-0.5

0.6

-0.6

0.7

-1.2

0.3

1.0

2013

10.37

10.30

10.24

10.29

10.22

10.32

10.29

10.34

10.43

∆%12M

-0.3

0.2

0.4

0.2

0.7

0.9

1.2

0.9

0.4

2014

10.41

10.47

10.37

10.29

10.22

10.29

10.33

10.50

10.48

∆%12M

0.4

1.7

1.3

0.0

0.0

-0.3

0.4

1.5

0.5

2015

10.65

10.68

10.60

10.53

         

∆%12M

2.3

2.0

2.2

2.3

         

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/

Chart IB-2 of the US Bureau of Labor Statistics plots average hourly earnings of all US employees in constant 1982-1984 dollars with evident decline from annual earnings of $10.34 in 2009 and $10.35 in 2010 to $10.24 in 2011 and $10.24 again in 2012 or loss of 1.1 percent (data in http://www.bls.gov/data/). Annual real hourly earnings increased 0.5 percent in 2013 relative to 2012 and increased 0.5 percent in 2014 relative to 2013. The economic welfare or wellbeing of United States workers deteriorated in a recovery without hiring (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/interest-rate-policy-and-dollar.html), stagnating/declining real wages and 24.7 million unemployed or underemployed (Section I and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/quite-high-equity-valuations-and.html) because of mediocre economic growth (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/06/dollar-revaluation-squeezing-corporate.html).

clip_image043

Chart IB-2, US, Average Hourly Earnings of All Employees in Constant Dollars of 1982-1984, SA 2006-2015

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/

Chart IB-3 provides 12-month percentage changes of average hourly earnings of all employees in constant dollars of 1982-1984, that is, adjusted for inflation. There was sharp contraction of inflation-adjusted average hourly earnings of US employees during parts of 2007 and 2008. Rates of change in 12 months became positive in parts of 2009 and 2010 but then became negative again in 2011 and into 2012 with temporary increase in Apr 2012 that was reversed in May with another gain in Jun and Jul 2012 followed by stagnation in Aug 2012. There was marginal gain in Sep 2012 with sharp decline in Oct 2012, stagnation in Nov 2012, increase in Dec 2012 and renewed decrease in Jan 2013 with near stagnation in Feb 2013 followed by mild increase in Mar-Apr 2013. Hourly earnings adjusted for inflation increased in Jun 2013 and fell in Jul 2013, increasing in Aug-Dec 2013 and Jan-Mar 2014. Average hourly earnings stagnated in Apr-May 2014 and rebounded mildly in Jul 2014, increasing in Aug 2014 and decreasing in Sep 2014. Average hourly earnings adjusted for inflation increased in Oct-Dec 2014 and Jan 2015, decreasing in Feb 2015 and increasing in Mar-Apr 2015.

clip_image044

Chart IB-3, Average Hourly Earnings of All Employees NSA 12-Month Percent Change, 1982-1984 Dollars, NSA 2007-2015

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/

Average weekly earnings of all US employees in the US in constant dollars of 1982-1984 from the dataset of the US Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) are provided in Table IB-5. Average weekly earnings fell 3.2 percent after adjusting for inflation in the 12 months ending in Aug 2011, decreased 0.9 percent in the 12 months ending in Sep 2011 and increased 0.6 percent in the 12 months ending in Oct 2011. Average weekly earnings fell 1.0 percent in the 12 months ending in Nov 2011 and 0.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Dec 2011. Average weekly earnings declined 0.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Jan 2012 and 0.5 percent in the 12 months ending in Feb 2012. Average weekly earnings in constant dollars were virtually flat in Mar 2012 relative to Mar 2011, decreasing 0.2 percent. Average weekly earnings in constant dollars increased 1.7 percent in Apr 2012 relative to Apr 2011 but fell 1.7 percent in May 2012 relative to May 2011, increasing 0.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Jun 2012 and 2.1 percent in the 12 months ending in Jul 2012. Real weekly earnings increased 0.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Aug 2012 and 2.1 percent in the 12 months ending in Sep 2012. Real weekly earnings fell 2.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Oct 2012 and increased 0.1 percent in the 12 months ending in Nov 2012 and 2.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Dec 2012. Real weekly earnings fell 1.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Jan 2013 and virtually stagnated with gain of 0.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Feb 2013, increasing 0.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Mar 2013. Real weekly earnings fell 0.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr 2013 and increased 0.9 percent in the 12 months ending in May 2013. Average weekly earnings increased 2.5 percent in the 12 months ending in Jun 2013 and fell 2.0 percent in the 12 months ending in Jul 2013. Real weekly earnings increased 0.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Aug 2013, 0.9 percent in the 12 months ending in Sep 2013 and 1.5 percent in the 12 months ending in Oct 2013. Average weekly earnings increased 1.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Nov 2013 and fell 0.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Dec 2013. Average weekly earnings increased 0.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Jan 2014 and 2.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Feb 2014. Average weekly earnings increased 2.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Mar 2014 and 0.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr 2014. Average weekly earnings in constant dollars increased 0.3 percent in the 12 months ending in May 2014 and changed 0.0 percent in the 12 months ending in Jun 2014. Real average weekly earnings increased 0.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Jul 2014 and 0.8 percent in the 12 months ending in Aug 2014. Real weekly earnings decreased 1.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Sep 2014 and increased 0.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Oct 2014. Average weekly earnings increased 3.0 percent in the 12 months ending in Nov 2014 and increased 0.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Dec 2014. Average weekly earnings increased 2.9 percent in the 12 months ending in Jan 2015 and increased 2.6 percent in the 12 months ending in Feb 2015. Average weekly earnings adjusted for inflation increased 2.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Mar 2015 and increased 2.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr 2015. Table I-5 confirms the trend of deterioration of purchasing power of average weekly earnings in 2011 and into 2013 with oscillations according to carry trades causing world inflation waves (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/04/global-portfolio-reallocations-squeeze.html). On an annual basis, average weekly earnings in constant 1982-1984 dollars increased from $349.34 in 2007 to $354.19 in 2013, by 1.4 percent or at the average rate of 0.2 percent per year (data in http://www.bls.gov/data/). Annual average weekly earnings in constant dollars of $353.11 in 2010 were virtually unchanged at $353.00 in 2012. Annual average weekly earnings increased from $349.34 in 2007 to $356.96 in 2014 or by 2.2 at the average rate of 0.3 percent. Those who still work bring back home a paycheck that buys fewer high-quality goods than a year earlier. The fractured US job market does not provide an opportunity for advancement as in past booms following recessions because of poor job creation with 24.7 million unemployed or underemployed (Section I and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/quite-high-equity-valuations-and.html) in a recovery without hiring (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/interest-rate-policy-and-dollar.html) because of mediocre economic growth (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/06/dollar-revaluation-squeezing-corporate.html).

Table IB-5, US, Average Weekly Earnings of All Employees in Constant Dollars of 1982-1984, NSA 2007-2015

Year

Jan

Feb

Mar

Apr

Nov

Dec

2006

   

343.54

349.61

348.95

353.20

2007

348.55

348.04

347.42

353.07

346.68

354.76

2008

344.58

345.89

350.37

343.80

358.50

356.85

2009

353.62

358.93

354.45

348.86

355.07

351.48

2010

350.39

350.20

349.29

351.53

354.81

355.29

2011

359.82

353.35

349.60

349.29

351.14

353.95

2012

358.75

351.67

348.87

355.19

351.46

362.53

∆%12M

-0.3

-0.5

-0.2

1.7

0.1

2.4

2013

352.58

352.21

351.29

352.84

355.85

361.82

∆%12M

-1.7

0.2

0.7

-0.7

1.2

-0.2

2014

353.93

360.14

359.79

354.05

366.36

362.49

∆%12M

0.4

2.3

2.4

0.3

3.0

0.2

2015

364.23

369.41

367.69

362.32

   

∆%12M

2.9

2.6

2.2

2.3

   

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/

Chart IB-4 provides average weekly earnings of all employees in constant dollars of 1982-1984. The same pattern emerges of sharp decline during the contraction, followed by recovery in the expansion and continuing fall with oscillations caused by carry trades from zero interest rates into commodity futures from 2010 to 2011 and into 2012-2015. The increase in the final segment is mostly because of collapse of commodity prices in reversals of carry trade exposures.

clip_image045

Chart IB-4, US, Average Weekly Earnings of All Employees in Constant Dollars of 1982-1984, SA 2006-2015

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/

Chart IB-5 provides 12-month percentage changes of average weekly earnings of all employees in the US in constant dollars of 1982-1984. There is the same pattern of contraction during the global recession in 2008 and then again trend of deterioration in the recovery without hiring and inflation waves. (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/interest-rate-policy-and-dollar.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/04/global-portfolio-reallocations-squeeze.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/03/dollar-revaluation-and-financial-risk.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/03/irrational-exuberance-mediocre-cyclical.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/01/competitive-currency-conflicts-world.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/12/patience-on-interest-rate-increases.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/11/squeeze-of-economic-activity-by-carry.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/10/financial-oscillations-world-inflation.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/09/world-inflation-waves-squeeze-of.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/08/monetary-policy-world-inflation-waves.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/07/world-inflation-waves-united-states.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/06/valuation-risks-world-inflation-waves.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/05/world-inflation-waves-squeeze-of.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/04/imf-view-world-inflation-waves-squeeze.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/03/interest-rate-risks-world-inflation.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/01/world-inflation-waves-interest-rate.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/12/tapering-quantitative-easing-mediocre.html

http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/11/risks-of-zero-interest-rates-world.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/10/world-inflation-waves-regional-economic.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/08/duration-dumping-and-peaking-valuations.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/07/tapering-quantitative-easing-policy-and.html

http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/06/paring-quantitative-easing-policy-and.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/05/word-inflation-waves-squeeze-of.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/04/world-inflation-waves-squeeze-of.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/04/recovery-without-hiring-ten-million.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/04/mediocre-and-decelerating-united-states.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/02/world-inflation-waves-united-states.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/12/recovery-without-hiring-forecast-growth.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/11/united-states-unsustainable-fiscal.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/09/recovery-without-hiring-world-inflation.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012_09_01_archive.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/07/world-inflation-waves-financial.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/destruction-of-three-trillion-dollars.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/05/world-inflation-waves-monetary-policy.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/recovery-without-hiring-continuance-of.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/04/fractured-labor-market-with-hiring.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/03/global-financial-and-economic-risk.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/02/world-inflation-waves-united-states.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/01/world-inflation-waves-united-states.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/01/recovery-without-hiring-united-states.html

http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/09/recovery-without-hiring-world-inflation.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012_09_01_archive.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/07/world-inflation-waves-financial.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/05/world-inflation-waves-monetary-policy.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/recovery-without-hiring-continuance-of.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/04/fractured-labor-market-with-hiring.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/03/global-financial-and-economic-risk.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/02/world-inflation-waves-united-states.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/01/world-inflation-waves-united-states.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/01/recovery-without-hiring-united-states.html).

clip_image046

Chart IB-5, US, Average Weekly Earnings of All Employees NSA in Constant Dollars of 1982-1984 12-Month Percent Change, NSA 2007-2015

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/

  II IB Stagnating Real Disposable Income and Consumption Expenditures. The Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) provides important revisions and enhancements of data on personal income and outlays since 1929 (http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm). There are waves of changes in personal income and expenditures in Table IB-1 that correspond somewhat to inflation waves observed worldwide (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/interest-rate-policy-and-dollar.html) because of the influence through price indexes. Data are distorted in Nov and Dec 2012 by the rush to realize income of all forms in anticipation of tax increases beginning in Jan 2013. There is major distortion in Jan 2013 because of higher contributions in payrolls to government social insurance that caused sharp reduction in personal income and disposable personal income. The Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) explains as follows (page 3 http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2013/pdf/pi0313.pdf):

“The February and January [2013] changes in disposable personal income (DPI) mainly reflected the effect of special factors in January, such as the expiration of the “payroll tax holiday” and the acceleration of bonuses and personal dividends to November and to December [2012] in anticipation of changes in individual tax rates.”

In the first wave in Jan-Apr 2011 with relaxed risk aversion, nominal personal income (NPI) increased at the annual equivalent rate of 8.1 percent, nominal disposable personal income (NDPI) at 5.2 percent and nominal personal consumption expenditures (NPCE) at 5.9 percent. Real disposable income (RDPI) increased at the annual equivalent rate of 1.2 percent and real personal consumption expenditures (RPCE) rose at annual equivalent 1.5 percent. In the second wave in May-Aug 2011 under risk aversion, NPI rose at annual equivalent 4.9 percent, NPDI at 4.9 percent and NPCE at 3.7 percent. RDPI increased at 1.8 percent annual equivalent and RPCE at 0.9 percent annual equivalent. With mixed shocks of risk aversion in the third wave from Sep to Dec 2011, NPI rose at 2.4 percent annual equivalent, NDPI at 2.4 percent and NPCE at 2.1 percent. RDPI increased at 1.5 percent annual equivalent and RPCE at 1.5 percent annual equivalent. In the fourth wave from Jan to Mar 2012, NPI increased at 9.6 percent annual equivalent, NDPI at 8.7 percent and NPCE at 6.2 percent. Real disposable income (RDPI) is more dynamic in the revisions, growing at 5.7 percent annual equivalent and RPCE at 3.7 percent. The policy of repressing savings with zero interest rates stimulated growth of nominal consumption (NPCE) at the annual equivalent rate of 6.2 percent and real consumption (RPCE) at 3.7 percent. In the fifth wave in Apr-Jul 2012, NPI increased at annual equivalent 0.9 percent, NDPI at 0.9 percent and RDPI at 0.0 percent. Financial repression failed to stimulate consumption with NPCE growing at 2.1 percent annual equivalent and RPCE at 1.8 percent. In the sixth wave in Aug-Oct 2012, in another wave of carry trades into commodity futures, NPI increased at 7.9 percent annual equivalent and NDPI increased at 7.0 percent while real disposable income (RDPI) increased at 3.7 percent annual equivalent. NPCE increased at 4.9 percent and RPCE at 1.2 percent. Data for Nov-Dec 2012 have illusory increases: “Personal income in November and December was boosted by accelerated and special dividend payments to persons and by accelerated bonus payments and other irregular pay in private wages and salaries in anticipation of changes in individual income tax rates. Personal income in December was also boosted by lump-sum social security benefit payments” (page 2 at http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2013/pdf/pi1212.pdf). In the seventh wave, anticipations of tax increases in Jan 2013 caused exceptional income gains that increased personal income to annual equivalent 28.3 percent in Nov-Dec 2012, nominal disposable income at 27.5 percent and real disposable personal income at 28.3 percent with likely effects on nominal personal consumption that increased at 2.4 percent and real personal consumption at 3.0 percent with subdued prices. The numbers in parentheses show that without the exceptional effects NDPI (nominal disposable personal income) increased at 5.5 percent and RDPI (real disposable personal income) at 8.7 percent. In the eighth wave, nominal personal income fell 5.1 percent in Jan 2013 or at the annual equivalent rate of decline of 46.6 percent; nominal disposable personal income fell 5.8 percent or at the annual equivalent rate of decline of 51.2 percent; real disposable income fell 5.9 percent or at the annual rate of decline of 51.8 percent; nominal personal consumption expenditures increased 0.5 percent or at the annual equivalent rate of 6.2 percent; and real personal consumption expenditures increased 0.4 percent or at the annual equivalent rate of 4.9 percent. The savings rate fell significantly from 10.5 percent in Dec 2012 to 4.5 percent in Jan 2013. The Bureau of Economic Analysis explains as follows (http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2013/pdf/pi0113.pdf 3):

“Contributions for government social insurance -- a subtraction in calculating personal income -- increased $126.7 billion in January, compared with an increase of $6.3 billion in December. The

January estimate reflected increases in both employer and employee contributions for government social insurance. The January estimate of employee contributions for government social insurance reflected the expiration of the “payroll tax holiday,” that increased the social security contribution rate for employees and self-employed workers by 2.0 percentage points, or $114.1 billion at an annual rate. For additional information, see FAQ on “How did the expiration of the payroll tax holiday affect personal income for January 2013?” at www.bea.gov. The January estimate of employee contributions for government social insurance also reflected an increase in the monthly premiums paid by participants in the supplementary medical insurance program, in the hospital insurance provisions of the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act, and in the social security taxable wage base; together, these changes added $12.8 billion to January. As noted above, employer contributions were boosted $5.9 billion in January, so the total contribution of special factors to the January change in contributions for government social insurance was $132.8 billion”

Further explanation is provided by the Bureau of Economic Analysis (http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2013/pdf/pi0213.pdf 2-3):

“Contributions for government social insurance -- a subtraction in calculating personal income --increased $6.4 billion in February, compared with an increase of $126.8 billion in January. The

January estimate reflected increases in both employer and employee contributions for government social insurance. The January estimate of employee contributions for government social insurance reflected the expiration of the “payroll tax holiday,” that increased the social security contribution rate for employees and self-employed workers by 2.0 percentage points, or $114.1 billion at an annual rate. For additional information, see FAQ on “How did the expiration of the payroll tax holiday affect personal income for January 2013?” at www.bea.gov. The January estimate of employee contributions for government social insurance also reflected an increase in the monthly premiums paid by participants in the supplementary medical insurance program, in the hospital insurance provisions of the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act, and in the social security taxable wage base; together, these changes added $12.9 billion to January. Employer contributions were boosted $5.9 billion in January, which reflected increases in the social security taxable wage base (from $110,100 to $113,700), in the tax rates paid by employers to state unemployment insurance, and in employer contributions for the federal unemployment tax and for pension guaranty. The total contribution of special factors to the January change in contributions for government social insurance was $132.9 billion. The January change in disposable personal income (DPI) mainly reflected the effect of special factors, such as the expiration of the “payroll tax holiday” and the acceleration of bonuses and personal dividends to December in anticipation of changes in individual tax rates. Excluding these special factors and others, which are discussed more fully below, DPI increased $46.8 billion in February, or 0.4 percent, after increasing $15.8 billion, or 0.1 percent, in January.”

The increase was provided in the “fiscal cliff” law H.R. 8 American Taxpayer Relief Act of 2012 (http://www.gpo.gov/fdsys/pkg/BILLS-112hr8eas/pdf/BILLS-112hr8eas.pdf). In the ninth wave in Feb-Mar 2013, nominal personal income increased at 7.4 percent and nominal disposable income at 6.8 percent annual equivalent, while real disposable income increased at 5.5 percent annual equivalent. Nominal personal consumption expenditures grew at 4.3 percent annual equivalent and real personal consumption expenditures at 2.4 percent annual equivalent. The savings rate collapsed from 7.1 percent in Oct 2012, 8.2 percent in Nov 2012 and 10.5 percent in Dec 2012 to 4.5 percent in Jan 2013, 4.7 percent in Feb 2013 and 4.9 percent in Mar 2013. In the tenth wave from Apr to Sep 2013, personal income grew at 3.7 percent annual equivalent, nominal disposable income increased at annual equivalent 3.9 percent and nominal personal consumption expenditures at 3.2 percent. Real disposable income grew at 2.8 percent annual equivalent and real personal consumption expenditures at 2.2 percent. In the eleventh wave, nominal personal income fell at 1.2 percent annual equivalent in Oct 2013, nominal disposable income at 2.4 percent and real disposable income at 3.5 percent. Nominal personal consumption expenditures increased at 4.9 percent annual equivalent and real personal consumption expenditures at 3.7 percent. In the twelfth wave, nominal personal income increased at 3.7 percent annual equivalent in Nov 2013, nominal disposable income at 2.4 percent and nominal personal consumption expenditures at 7.4 percent. Real disposable income increased at annual equivalent 1.2 percent and real personal consumption expenditures at 6.2 percent. In the thirteenth wave, nominal personal income changed at 0.0 percent annual equivalent in Dec 2013 and nominal disposable income fell at 1.2 percent while real disposable income fell at 2.4 percent annual equivalent. Nominal personal consumption expenditures increased at 1.2 percent annual equivalent and 0.0 percent for real personal consumption expenditures. In the fourteenth wave, nominal personal income increased at 7.0 percent annual equivalent in Jan-Mar 2014, nominal disposable income at 7.4 percent and nominal consumption expenditures at 4.1 percent. Real disposable personal income increased at 6.2 percent and real personal consumption expenditures at 2.8 percent. In the fifteenth wave, nominal personal income increased at 3.9 percent in annual equivalent in Apr-Aug 2014 and nominal disposable income at 3.9 percent. Real disposable income increased at 2.2 percent in annual equivalent in Apr-Aug 2014. Nominal personal consumption increased at 4.4 percent annual equivalent in Apr-Aug 2014 and real personal consumption expenditures increased at 2.7 percent. In the sixteenth wave, nominal personal income increased at 4.6 percent annual equivalent in Sep-Dec 20154, nominal disposable income at 3.7 percent and nominal personal consumption at 2.4 percent. Real disposable income increased at 4.6 percent in Sep-Dec 2014 and real personal consumption expenditure at 3.7 percent. In the seventeenth wave, nominal personal income increased at 4.3 percent annual equivalent in Jan-Feb 2015 and nominal disposable income at 5.5 percent while nominal personal consumption expenditures fell at 1.2 percent. Real disposable income increased at 5.5 percent and real personal consumption expenditures at 0.6 percent. In the eighteenth wave, nominal personal income (NPI) and nominal disposable personal income (NDPI) increased at 2.4 percent annual equivalent in Mar-Apr 2015. Real disposable income (RDPI) fell at 2.4 percent. Nominal consumption expenditures (NPCE) increased at 3.0 percent and real personal consumption expenditures (RPCE) increased at 2.4 percent.

The United States economy has grown at the average yearly rate of 3 percent per year and 2 percent per year in per capita terms from 1870 to 2010, as measured by Lucas (2011May). An important characteristic of the economic cycle in the US has been rapid growth in the initial phase of expansion after recessions.

Inferior performance of the US economy and labor markets is the critical current issue of analysis and policy design. Long-term economic performance in the United States consisted of trend growth of GDP at 3 percent per year and of per capita GDP at 2 percent per year as measured for 1870 to 2010 by Robert E Lucas (2011May). The economy returned to trend growth after adverse events such as wars and recessions. The key characteristic of adversities such as recessions was much higher rates of growth in expansion periods that permitted the economy to recover output, income and employment losses that occurred during the contractions. Over the business cycle, the economy compensated the losses of contractions with higher growth in expansions to maintain trend growth of GDP of 3 percent and of GDP per capita of 2 percent. The US maintained growth at 3.0 percent on average over entire cycles with expansions at higher rates compensating for contractions. US economic growth has been at only 2.2 percent on average in the cyclical expansion in the 23 quarters from IIIQ2009 to IQ2015. Boskin (2010Sep) measures that the US economy grew at 6.2 percent in the first four quarters and 4.5 percent in the first 12 quarters after the trough in the second quarter of 1975; and at 7.7 percent in the first four quarters and 5.8 percent in the first 12 quarters after the trough in the first quarter of 1983 (Professor Michael J. Boskin, Summer of Discontent, Wall Street Journal, Sep 2, 2010 http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052748703882304575465462926649950.html). There are new calculations using the revision of US GDP and personal income data since 1929 by the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) (http://bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm) and the second estimate of GDP for IQ2015 (http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/gdp/2015/pdf/gdp1q15_2nd.pdf). The average of 7.7 percent in the first four quarters of major cyclical expansions is in contrast with the rate of growth in the first four quarters of the expansion from IIIQ2009 to IIQ2010 of only 2.7 percent obtained by diving GDP of $14,745.9 billion in IIQ2010 by GDP of $14,355.6 billion in IIQ2009 {[$14,745.9/$14,355.6 -1]100 = 2.7%], or accumulating the quarter on quarter growth rates (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/06/dollar-revaluation-squeezing-corporate.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/dollar-devaluation-and-carry-trade.html). The expansion from IQ1983 to IVQ1985 was at the average annual growth rate of 5.9 percent, 5.4 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1986, 5.2 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1986, 5.0 percent from IQ1983 to IQ1987, 5.0 percent from IQ1983 to IIQ1987, 4.9 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1987, 5.0 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1987, 4.9 percent from IQ1983 to IIQ1988, 4.8 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1988 and at 7.8 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1983 (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/06/dollar-revaluation-squeezing-corporate.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/dollar-devaluation-and-carry-trade.html). The US maintained growth at 3.0 percent on average over entire cycles with expansions at higher rates compensating for contractions. Growth at trend in the entire cycle from IVQ2007 to IQ2015 would have accumulated to 23.9 percent. GDP in IQ2015 would be $18,574.8 billion (in constant dollars of 2009) if the US had grown at trend, which is higher by $2,310.7 billion than actual $16,264.1 billion. There are about two trillion dollars of GDP less than at trend, explaining the 24.7 million unemployed or underemployed equivalent to actual unemployment/underemployment of 14.9 percent of the effective labor force (Section I and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/quite-high-equity-valuations-and.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/04/volatility-of-valuations-of-financial.html). US GDP in IQ2015 is 12.4 percent lower than at trend. US GDP grew from $14,991.8 billion in IVQ2007 in constant dollars to $16,264.1 billion in IQ2015 or 8.5 percent at the average annual equivalent rate of 1.1 percent. Cochrane (2014Jul2) estimates US GDP at more than 10 percent below trend. The US missed the opportunity to grow at higher rates during the expansion and it is difficult to catch up because growth rates in the final periods of expansions tend to decline. The US missed the opportunity for recovery of output and employment always afforded in the first four quarters of expansion from recessions. Zero interest rates and quantitative easing were not required or present in successful cyclical expansions and in secular economic growth at 3.0 percent per year and 2.0 percent per capita as measured by Lucas (2011May). There is cyclical uncommonly slow growth in the US instead of allegations of secular stagnation. There is similar behavior in manufacturing. There is classic research on analyzing deviations of output from trend (see for example Schumpeter 1939, Hicks 1950, Lucas 1975, Sargent and Sims 1977). The long-term trend is growth at average 3.3 percent per year from Apr 1919 to Apr 2015. Growth at 3.3 percent per year would raise the NSA index of manufacturing output from 99.2392 in Dec 2007 to 125.9172 in Apr 2015. The actual index NSA in Apr 2015 is 101.1122, which is 19.7 percent below trend. Manufacturing output grew at average 2.4 percent between Dec 1986 and Dec 2014. Using trend growth of 2.4 percent per year, the index would increase to 118.0899 in Apr 2015. The output of manufacturing at 101.1122 in Apr 2015 is 14.4 percent below trend under this alternative calculation.

Table IB-1, US, Percentage Change from Prior Month Seasonally Adjusted of Personal Income, Disposable Income and Personal Consumption Expenditures %

 

NPI

NDPI

RDPI

NPCE

RPCE

2015

         

Apr

0.4

0.4

0.3

0.0

0.0

Mar

0.0

0.0

-0.2

0.5

0.4

AE ∆% Mar-Apr

2.4

2.4

0.6

3.0

2.4

Feb

0.4

0.4

0.3

0.1

0.0

Jan

0.3

0.2

0.6

-0.3

0.1

AE ∆% Jan-Feb

4.3

3.7

5.5

-1.2

0.6

2014

         

Dec

0.4

0.3

0.6

-0.2

0.1

Nov

0.5

0.4

0.5

0.4

0.5

Oct

0.4

0.4

0.3

0.4

0.4

Sep

0.2

0.1

0.1

0.2

0.2

AE ∆% Sep-Dec

4.6

3.7

4.6

2.4

3.7

Aug

0.4

0.3

0.4

0.6

0.7

Jul

0.3

0.2

0.1

0.2

0.1

Jun

0.4

0.4

0.2

0.5

0.3

May

0.3

0.4

0.2

0.3

0.1

Apr

0.2

0.3

0.1

0.2

-0.1

AE ∆% Apr-Sep

3.9

3.9

2.2

4.4

2.7

Mar

0.6

0.6

0.5

0.8

0.6

Feb

0.6

0.6

0.5

0.4

0.4

Jan

0.5

0.6

0.5

-0.2

-0.3

AE ∆% Jan-Mar

7.0

7.4

6.2

4.1

2.8

2013

         

Dec

0.0

-0.1

-0.2

0.1

0.0

AE ∆% Dec

0.0

-1.2

-2.4

1.2

0.0

Nov

0.3

0.2

0.1

0.6

0.5

AE ∆% Nov

3.7

2.4

1.2

7.4

6.2

Oct

-0.1

-0.2

-0.3

0.4

0.3

AE ∆% Oct

-1.2

-2.4

-3.5

4.9

3.7

Sep

0.4

0.4

0.3

0.4

0.3

Aug

0.4

0.4

0.4

0.2

0.2

Jul

0.0

0.0

-0.1

0.2

0.1

Jun

0.4

0.5

0.2

0.5

0.2

May

0.4

0.5

0.4

0.3

0.2

Apr

0.2

0.1

0.2

0.0

0.1

AE ∆% Apr-Sep

3.7

3.9

2.8

3.2

2.2

Mar

0.3

0.3

0.4

0.1

0.1

Feb

0.9

0.8

0.5

0.6

0.3

AE ∆% Feb-Mar

7.4

6.8

5.5

4.3

2.4

Jan

-5.1

-5.8 (0.1)a

-5.9

0.5

0.4

AE ∆% Jan

-46.6

-51.2 (3.7)a

-51.8

6.2

4.9

2012

         

∆% Jan-Dec 2012***

9.0

8.6

7.0

3.9

2.3

Dec

2.8

2.8 (0.3)*

2.8 (0.5)*

0.2

0.2

Nov

1.4

1.3 (0.6)*

1.4 (0.9)*

0.2

0.3

AE ∆% Nov-Dec

28.3

27.5 (5.5)*

28.3 (8.7)*

2.4

3.0

Oct

0.8

0.8

0.6

0.2

-0.1

Sep

0.9

0.8

0.5

0.7

0.4

Aug

0.2

0.1

-0.2

0.3

0.0

AE ∆% Aug-Oct

7.9

7.0

3.7

4.9

1.2

Jul

-0.2

-0.2

-0.3

0.4

0.4

Jun

0.2

0.2

0.1

0.0

0.0

May

0.0

0.0

0.0

0.0

0.0

Apr

0.3

0.3

0.2

0.3

0.2

AE ∆% Apr-Jul

0.9

0.9

0.0

2.1

1.8

Mar

0.5

0.4

0.2

0.1

-0.1

Feb

0.8

0.7

0.5

0.7

0.5

Jan

1.0

1.0

0.7

0.7

0.5

AE ∆% Jan-Mar

9.6

8.7

5.7

6.2

3.7

2011

         

∆% Jan-Dec 2011*

5.1

4.1

1.2

4.3

1.8

Dec

0.8

0.8

0.8

0.0

0.0

Nov

0.0

0.0

-0.1

0.0

-0.1

Oct

0.1

0.1

0.1

0.3

0.3

Sep

-0.1

-0.1

-0.3

0.4

0.3

AE ∆% Sep-Dec

2.4

2.4

1.5

2.1

1.5

Aug

0.2

0.2

-0.1

0.2

-0.1

Jul

0.6

0.6

0.4

0.5

0.3

Jun

0.5

0.5

0.4

0.2

0.2

May

0.3

0.3

-0.1

0.3

-0.1

AE ∆% May-Aug

4.9

4.9

1.8

3.7

0.9

Apr

0.2

0.2

-0.3

0.4

0.0

Mar

0.3

0.2

-0.1

0.7

0.3

Feb

0.6

0.6

0.3

0.4

0.1

Jan

1.5

0.7

0.5

0.4

0.1

AE ∆% Jan-Apr

8.1

5.2

1.2

5.9

1.5

2010

         

∆% Jan-Dec 2010**

4.9

4.3

2.9

4.4

2.9

Dec

0.9

0.9

0.7

0.3

0.1

Nov

0.5

0.5

0.3

0.5

0.4

Oct

0.5

0.5

0.2

0.7

0.5

IVQ2010∆%

1.9

1.8

1.2

1.5

1.0

IVQ2010 AE ∆%

7.9

7.4

4.9

6.2

4.1

Notes: *Excluding exceptional income gains in Nov and Dec 2012 because of anticipated tax increases in Jan 2013 ((page 2 at http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2013/pdf/pi1212.pdf). a Excluding employee contributions for government social insurance (pages 1-2 at http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2013/pdf/pi0113.pdf )Excluding NPI: current dollars personal income; NDPI: current dollars disposable personal income; RDPI: chained (2005) dollars DPI; NPCE: current dollars personal consumption expenditures; RPCE: chained (2005) dollars PCE; AE: annual equivalent; IVQ2010: fourth quarter 2010; A: annual equivalent

Percentage change month to month seasonally adjusted

*∆% Dec 2011/Dec 2010 **∆% Dec 2010/Dec 2009 *** ∆% Dec 2012/Dec 2011

Source: US Bureau of Economic http://bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

The rates of growth of real disposable income decline in the final quarter of 2013 because of the increases in the last two months of 2012 in anticipation of the tax increases of the “fiscal cliff” episode. The increase was provided in the “fiscal cliff” law H.R. 8 American Taxpayer Relief Act of 2012 (http://www.gpo.gov/fdsys/pkg/BILLS-112hr8eas/pdf/BILLS-112hr8eas.pdf).

The 12-month rate of increase of real disposable income fell to 0.0 percent in Oct 2013 and minus 1.3 percent in Nov 2013 partly because of the much higher level in late 2012 in anticipation of incomes to avoid increases in taxes in 2013. Real disposable income fell 4.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Dec 2013 primarily because of the much higher level in late 2012 in anticipation of income to avoid increases in taxes in 2013. Real disposable income increased 2.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Jan 2014, partly because of the low level in Jan 2013 after anticipation of incomes in late 2012 in avoiding the fiscal cliff episode. Real disposable income increased 3.5 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr 2015.

RPCE growth decelerated less sharply from close to 3 percent in IVQ 2010 to 2.6 percent in Apr 2015. Subdued growth of RPCE could affect revenues of business. Growth rates of personal consumption have weakened. Goods and especially durable goods have been driving growth of PCE as shown by the much higher 12-month rates of growth of real goods PCE (RPCEG) and durable goods real PCE (RPCEGD) than services real PCE (RPCES). Growth of consumption of goods and, in particular, of consumer durable goods drives the faster expansion of the economy while growth of consumption of services is much more moderate. The 12-month rates of growth of RPCEGD have fallen from around 10 percent and even higher in several months from Sep 2010 to Feb 2011 to the range of 5.3 to 10.1 percent from Apr 2014 to Apr 2015. RPCEG growth rates have fallen from around 5 percent late in 2010 and early Jan-Feb 2011 to the range of 2.8 to 5.2 percent from Apr 2014 to Apr 2015. In Apr 2015, RPCEG increased 2.8 percent in 12 months and RPCEGD 5.3 percent while RPCES increased 2.6 percent. There are limits to sustained growth based on financial repression in an environment of weak labor markets and real labor remuneration.

Table IB-2, Real Disposable Personal Income and Real Personal Consumption Expenditures

Percentage Change from the Same Month a Year Earlier %

 

RDPI

RPCE

RPCEG

RPCEGD

RPCES

2015

         

Apr

3.5

2.7

2.8

5.3

2.6

Mar

3.2

2.7

3.2

5.5

2.5

Feb

3.9

3.0

3.5

7.1

2.7

Jan

4.1

3.4

5.2

10.1

2.4

2014

         

Dec

4.0

2.9

4.2

8.9

2.3

Nov

3.1

2.8

4.2

7.9

2.1

Oct

2.7

2.8

3.8

7.4

2.3

Sep

2.1

2.7

3.7

8.5

2.2

Aug

2.3

2.9

4.4

8.4

2.1

Jul

2.3

2.4

3.3

7.0

1.9

Jun

2.1

2.4

3.5

7.0

1.8

May

2.1

2.3

3.2

7.2

1.9

Apr

2.3

2.4

3.8

6.5

1.7

Mar

2.4

2.5

3.8

8.2

1.9

Feb

2.3

2.0

2.1

3.5

2.0

Jan

2.3

1.9

1.2

2.0

2.3

2013

         

Dec

-4.2

2.7

3.1

3.5

2.4

Nov

-1.3

2.9

3.9

6.8

2.4

Oct

0.0

2.7

3.8

7.4

2.2

Sep

0.9

2.3

3.2

5.0

1.9

Aug

1.1

2.4

3.3

7.7

2.0

Jul

0.6

2.2

3.7

7.5

1.5

Jun

0.4

2.5

3.8

8.1

1.8

May

0.4

2.3

3.5

7.5

1.7

Apr

0.0

2.1

2.7

6.8

1.8

Mar

0.0

2.3

2.9

5.8

1.9

Feb

-0.2

2.0

3.3

7.0

1.4

Jan

-0.1

2.2

3.8

8.0

1.5

2012

         

Dec

7.0

2.3

3.8

8.8

1.6

Nov

4.8

2.0

3.1

8.2

1.5

Oct

3.2

1.6

2.2

5.4

1.3

Sep

2.7

1.9

3.5

8.5

1.1

Aug

1.9

1.8

3.5

8.7

0.9

Jul

2.0

1.8

2.8

7.3

1.3

Jun

2.7

1.7

2.6

8.4

1.2

May

3.0

1.9

3.0

7.6

1.3

Apr

2.9

1.8

2.4

6.5

1.5

Mar

2.4

1.5

2.2

5.8

1.2

Feb

2.1

1.9

2.4

6.9

1.7

Jan

1.8

1.5

1.8

5.8

1.4

Dec 2011

1.6

1.2

1.4

5.0

1.1

Dec 2010

2.9

2.9

4.7

8.4

2.1

Notes: RDPI: real disposable personal income; RPCE: real personal consumption expenditures (PCE); RPCEG: real PCE goods; RPCEGD: RPCEG durable goods; RPCES: RPCE services

Numbers are percentage changes from the same month a year earlier

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis http://bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

Chart IB-1 shows US real personal consumption expenditures (RPCE) between 1999 and 2015. There is an evident drop in RPCE during the global recession in 2007 to 2009 but the slope is flatter during the current recovery than in the period before 2007.

clip_image047

Chart IB-1, US, Real Personal Consumption Expenditures, Quarterly Seasonally Adjusted at Annual Rates 1999-2015

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

Percent changes from the prior period in seasonally adjusted annual equivalent quarterly rates (SAAR) of real personal consumption expenditures (RPCE) are provided in Chart IB-2 from 1995 to 2015. The average rate could be visualized as a horizontal line. Although there are not yet sufficient observations, it appears from Chart IB-2 that the average rate of growth of RPCE was higher before the recession than during the past twenty-three quarters of expansion that began in IIIQ2009.

clip_image048

Chart IB-2, Percent Change from Prior Period in Real Personal Consumption Expenditures, Quarterly Seasonally Adjusted at Annual Rates 1995-2015

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

Personal income and its disposition are shown in Table IB-3. The latest estimates and revisions have changed movements in five forms. (1) Increase in Apr 2015 of personal income by $59.4 billion or 0.4 percent and increase of disposable income of $48.8 billion or 0.4 percent with increase of wages and salaries of 0.2 percent. (2) Increase of personal income of $717.7 billion from Dec 2013 to Dec 2014 or 5.0 percent while disposable income increased $601.1 billion or 4.8 percent. Wages and salaries increased $414.0 billion or 5.7 percent. (3) Decrease of personal income of $302.9 billion from Dec 2012 to Dec 2013 or by 2.1 percent and decrease of disposable income of $397.7 billion or by 3.1 percent. Wages and salaries increased $30.8 billion from Dec 2012 to Dec 2013 or by 0.4 percent. Large part of these declines occurred because of the comparison of high levels in late 2012 in anticipation of tax increases in 2013. In 2012, personal income increased $1203.0 billion or 9.0 percent while wages and salaries increased 7.5 percent and disposable income 8.6 percent. Significant part of these gains occurred in Dec 2012 in anticipation of incomes because of tax increases beginning in Jan 2013. (4) Increase of $651.3 billion of personal income in 2011 or by 5.1 percent with increase of salaries of 2.7 percent and disposable income of 4.1 percent. (5) Increase of the rate of savings as percent of disposable income from 5.9 percent in Dec 2010 to 6.4 percent in Dec 2011, decreasing to 4.1 percent in Dec 2013. The savings rate increased to 5.0 percent in Dec 2014, 5.2 percent in Mar 2015 and 5.6 percent in Apr 2015.

Table IB-3, US, Personal Income and its Disposition, Seasonally Adjusted at Annual Rates USD Billions

 

Personal
Income

Wages &
Salaries

Personal
Taxes

DPI

Savings
Rate %

Apr       2015

15,211.7

7,719.3

1,858.3

13,353.4

5.6

Mar      2015

15,152.3

7,701.6

1,847.7

13,304.6

5.2

Change Apr 2015/     

Mar 2015

59.4 ∆% 0.4

17.7 ∆%

0.2

10.6 ∆% 0.6

48.8 ∆% 0.4

 

Dec 2014

15,037.7

7,628.1

1,811.7

13,225.9

5.0

Change Dec 2014/Dec 2013

717.7 ∆% 5.0

414.0 ∆% 5.7

116.4 ∆% 6.9

601.1 ∆% 4.8

 

Dec 2013

14,320.0

7,214.1

1,695.3

12,624.8

4.1

Dec 2012

14,622.9

7,183.3

1,600.4

13,022.5

10.5

Change Dec 2013/ Dec 2012

-302.9 ∆% -2.1

30.8 ∆% 0.4

94.9 ∆%

5.9

-397.7 ∆% -3.1

 

Change Dec 2012/ Dec 2011

1203.0 ∆% 9.0

500.4 ∆% 7.5

169.1 ∆% 11.8

1033.9 ∆% 8.6

 

Dec 2011

13,419.9

6,682.9

1,431.3

11,988.6

6.4

Dec 2010

12,768.6

6,506.0

1,254.2

11,514.5

5.9

Change Dec 2011/ Dec 2010

651.3 ∆%

5.1

176.9  ∆% 2.7

177.1     ∆% 14.1

474.1    ∆% 4.1

 

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

The Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) provides a wealth of revisions and enhancements of US personal income and outlays since 1929 (http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm). Table IB-4 provides growth rates of real disposable income and real disposable income per capita in the long-term and selected periods. Real disposable income consists of after-tax income adjusted for inflation. Real disposable income per capita is income per person after taxes and inflation. There is remarkable long-term trend of growth of real disposable income of 3.2 percent per year on average from 1929 to 2014 and 2.0 percent in real disposable income per capita. Real disposable income increased at the average yearly rate of 3.7 percent from 1947 to 1999 and real disposable income per capita at 2.3 percent. These rates of increase broadly accompany rates of growth of GDP. Institutional arrangements in the United States provided the environment for growth of output and income after taxes, inflation and population growth. There is significant break of growth by much lower 2.3 percent for real disposable income on average from 1999 to 2014 and 1.4 percent in real disposable per capita income. Real disposable income grew at 3.5 percent from 1980 to 1989 and real disposable per capita income at 2.6 percent. In contrast, real disposable income grew at only 1.5 percent on average from 2006 to 2014 and real disposable income per capita at 0.7 percent. The United States has interrupted its long-term and cyclical dynamism of output, income and employment growth. Recovery of this dynamism could prove to be a major challenge. Cyclical uncommonly slow growth explains weakness in the current whole cycle instead of the allegation of secular stagnation.

Table IB-4, Average Annual Growth Rates of Real Disposable Income (RDPI) and Real Disposable Income per Capita (RDPIPC), Percent per Year 

RDPI Average ∆%

 

     1929-2014

3.2

     1947-1999

3.7

     1999-2014

2.3

     1999-2006

3.2

     1980-1989

3.5

     2006-2014

1.5

RDPIPC Average ∆%

 

     1929-2014

2.0

     1947-1999

2.3

     1999-2014

1.4

     1999-2006

2.2

     1980-1989

2.6

     2006-2014

0.7

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

Chart IB-3 provides personal income in the US between 1980 and 1989. These data are not adjusted for inflation that was still high in the 1980s in the exit from the Great Inflation of the 1960s and 1970s (see http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/05/slowing-growth-global-inflation-great.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/04/new-economics-of-rose-garden-turned.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/03/is-there-second-act-of-us-great.html and Appendix I The Great Inflation; see Taylor 1993, 1997, 1998LB, 1999, 2012FP, 2012Mar27, 2012Mar28, 2012JMCB and http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/rules-versus-discretionary-authorities.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/07/financial-irrational-exuberance.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/07/world-inflation-waves-united-states.html). Personal income grew steadily during the 1980s after recovery from two recessions from Jan IQ1980 to Jul IIIQ1980 and from Jul IIIQ1981 to Nov IVQ1982.

clip_image049

Chart IB-3, US, Personal Income, Billion Dollars, Quarterly Seasonally Adjusted at Annual Rates, 1980-1989

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

A different evolution of personal income is shown in Chart IB-4. Personal income also fell during the recession from Dec IVQ2007 to Jun IIQ2009 (http://www.nber.org/cycles.html). Growth of personal income during the expansion has been tepid even with the new revisions. In IVQ2012, nominal disposable personal income grew at the SAAR of 13.8 percent and real disposable personal income at 11.8 percent (Table 2.1 http://bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm). The BEA explains as follows: “Personal income in November and December was boosted by accelerated and special dividend payments to persons and by accelerated bonus payments and other irregular pay in private wages and salaries in anticipation of changes in individual income tax rates. Personal income in December was also boosted by lump-sum social security benefit payments” (page 2 at http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2013/pdf/pi1212.pdf pages 1-2 at http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2013/pdf/pi0113.pdf). The Bureau of Economic Analysis explains as (http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2013/pdf/pi0213.pdf 2-3): “The January estimate of employee contributions for government social insurance reflected the expiration of the “payroll tax holiday,” that increased the social security contribution rate for employees and self-employed workers by 2.0 percentage points, or $114.1 billion at an annual rate. For additional information, see FAQ on “How did the expiration of the payroll tax holiday affect personal income for January 2013?” at www.bea.gov. The January estimate of employee contributions for government social insurance also reflected an increase in the monthly premiums paid by participants in the supplementary medical insurance program, in the hospital insurance provisions of the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act, and in the social security taxable wage base.”

The increase was provided in the “fiscal cliff” law H.R. 8 American Taxpayer Relief Act of 2012 (http://www.gpo.gov/fdsys/pkg/BILLS-112hr8eas/pdf/BILLS-112hr8eas.pdf).

In IQ2013, personal income fell at the SAAR of minus 8.6 percent; real personal income excluding current transfer receipts at minus 11.9 percent; and real disposable personal income at minus 12.6 percent (Table 6 at http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2014/pdf/pi1014.pdf). The BEA explains as follows (page 3 at http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2013/pdf/pi0313.pdf):

“The February and January changes in disposable personal income (DPI) mainly reflected the effect of special factors in January, such as the expiration of the “payroll tax holiday” and the acceleration of bonuses and personal dividends to November and to December in anticipation of changes in individual tax rates.”

In IIQ2013, personal income grew at 4.5 percent, real personal income excluding current transfer receipts at 4.6 percent and real disposable income at 3.8 percent (http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2014/pdf/pi1114.pdf). In IIIQ2013, personal income grew at 3.3 percent, real personal income excluding current transfers at 1.5 percent and real disposable income at 2.0 percent (Table 6 at http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2015/pdf/pi0215.pdf). In IVQ2013, personal income grew at 1.8 percent and real disposable income at 0.2 percent (Table 6 at http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2015/pdf/pi0415.pdf). In IQ2014, personal income grew at 4.9 percent in nominal terms and 3.2 percent in real terms excluding current transfer receipts while nominal disposable income grew at 4.8 percent and real disposable income at 3.4 percent (http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2015/pdf/pi0415.pdf). In IIQ2014, personal income grew at 4.9 percent and 2.2 percent in real terms excluding current transfers. Nominal disposable income grew at 5.5 percent and at 3.1 percent in real terms (http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2015/pdf/pi0415.pdf). In IIIQ2014, personal income grew at 4.2 percent, real personal income excluding current transfers at 2.7 percent and real disposable personal income at 2.4 percent (http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2015/pdf/pi0415.pdf). In IVQ2014, personal income grew at 4.6 percent in nominal terms and at 5.5 percent in real terms excluding current transfers while nominal disposable income grew at 3.7 percent in nominal terms and at 4.1 percent in real terms (http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2015/pdf/pi0415.pdf). In IQ2015, nominal personal income grew at 4.1 percent and at 5.3 percent in real terms excluding current transfer receipts while nominal disposable income grew at 3.2 percent and at 5.3 percent in real terms (http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2015/pdf/pi0415.pdf).

clip_image050

Chart IB-4, US, Personal Income, Current Billions of Dollars, Quarterly Seasonally Adjusted at Annual Rates, 2007-2015

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

Real or inflation-adjusted disposable personal income is provided in Chart IB-5 from 1980 to 1989. Real disposable income after allowing for taxes and inflation grew steadily at high rates during the entire decade.

clip_image051

Chart IB-5, US, Real Disposable Income, Billions of Chained 2009 Dollars, Quarterly Seasonally Adjusted at Annual Rates 1980-1989

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

Chart IB-6 provides real disposable income from 2007 to 2015. In IQ2013, personal income fell at the SAAR of minus 8.6 percent; real personal income excluding current transfer receipts at minus 11.9 percent; and real disposable personal income at minus 12.6 percent (Table 6 at http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2014/pdf/pi1014.pdf). The BEA explains as follows (page 3 at http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2013/pdf/pi0313.pdf):

“The February and January changes in disposable personal income (DPI) mainly reflected the effect of special factors in January, such as the expiration of the “payroll tax holiday” and the acceleration of bonuses and personal dividends to November and to December in anticipation of changes in individual tax rates.”

In IIQ2013, personal income grew at 4.5 percent, real personal income excluding current transfer receipts at 4.6 percent and real disposable income at 3.8 percent (http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2014/pdf/pi1114.pdf). In IIIQ2013, personal income grew at 3.3 percent, real personal income excluding current transfers at 1.5 percent and real disposable income at 2.0 percent (Table 6 at http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2015/pdf/pi0215.pdf). In IVQ2013, personal income grew at 1.8 percent and real disposable income at 0.2 percent (Table 6 at http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2015/pdf/pi0415.pdf). In IQ2014, personal income grew at 4.9 percent in nominal terms and 3.2 percent in real terms excluding current transfer receipts while nominal disposable income grew at 4.8 percent and real disposable income at 3.4 percent (http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2015/pdf/pi0415.pdf). In IIQ2014, personal income grew at 4.9 percent and 2.2 percent in real terms excluding current transfers. Nominal disposable income grew at 5.5 percent and at 3.1 percent in real terms (http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2015/pdf/pi0415.pdf). In IIIQ2014, personal income grew at 4.2 percent, real personal income excluding current transfers at 2.7 percent and real disposable personal income at 2.4 percent (http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2015/pdf/pi0415.pdf). In IVQ2014, personal income grew at 4.6 percent in nominal terms and at 5.5 percent in real terms excluding current transfers while nominal disposable income grew at 3.7 percent in nominal terms and at 4.1 percent in real terms (http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2015/pdf/pi0415.pdf). In IQ2015, nominal personal income grew at 4.1 percent and at 5.3 percent in real terms excluding current transfer receipts while nominal disposable income grew at 3.2 percent and at 5.3 percent in real terms (http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2015/pdf/pi0415.pdf).

clip_image052

Chart IB-6, US, Real Disposable Income, Billions of Chained 2009 Dollars, Quarterly Seasonally Adjusted at Annual Rates, 2007-2015

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

Chart IB-7 provides percentage quarterly changes in real disposable income from the preceding period at seasonally adjusted annual rates from 1980 to 1989. Rates of changes were high during the decade with few negative changes.

clip_image053

Chart IB-7, US, Real Disposable Income Percentage Change from Preceding Period at Quarterly Seasonally-Adjusted Annual Rates, 1980-1989

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

Chart IB-8 provides percentage quarterly changes in real disposable income from the preceding period at seasonally adjusted annual rates from 2007 to 2015. There has been a period of positive rates followed by decline of rates and then negative and low rates in 2011. Recovery in 2012 has not reproduced the dynamism of the brief early phase of expansion. In IVQ2012, nominal disposable personal income grew at the SAAR of 13.8 percent and real disposable personal income at 11.8 percent (Table 2.1 http://bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm). The BEA explains as: “Personal income in November and December was boosted by accelerated and special dividend payments to persons and by accelerated bonus payments and other irregular pay in private wages and salaries in anticipation of changes in individual income tax rates. Personal income in December was also boosted by lump-sum social security benefit payments” (page 2 at http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2013/pdf/pi1212.pdf). The BEA explains as follows (page 3 at http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2013/pdf/pi0313.pdf):

“The February and January changes in disposable personal income (DPI) mainly reflected the effect of special factors in January, such as the expiration of the “payroll tax holiday” and the acceleration of bonuses and personal dividends to November and to December in anticipation of changes in individual tax rates.”

In IIQ2013, personal income grew at 4.5 percent, real personal income excluding current transfer receipts at 4.6 percent and real disposable income at 3.8 percent (http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2014/pdf/pi1114.pdf). In IIIQ2013, personal income grew at 3.3 percent, real personal income excluding current transfers at 1.5 percent and real disposable income at 2.0 percent (Table 6 at http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2015/pdf/pi0215.pdf). In IVQ2013, personal income grew at 1.8 percent and real disposable income at 0.2 percent (Table 6 at http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2015/pdf/pi0415.pdf). In IQ2014, personal income grew at 4.9 percent in nominal terms and 3.2 percent in real terms excluding current transfer receipts while nominal disposable income grew at 4.8 percent and real disposable income at 3.4 percent (http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2015/pdf/pi0415.pdf). In IIQ2014, personal income grew at 4.9 percent and 2.2 percent in real terms excluding current transfers. Nominal disposable income grew at 5.5 percent and at 3.1 percent in real terms (http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2015/pdf/pi0415.pdf). In IIIQ2014, personal income grew at 4.2 percent, real personal income excluding current transfers at 2.7 percent and real disposable personal income at 2.4 percent (http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2015/pdf/pi0415.pdf). In IVQ2014, personal income grew at 4.6 percent in nominal terms and at 5.5 percent in real terms excluding current transfers while nominal disposable income grew at 3.7 percent in nominal terms and at 4.1 percent in real terms (http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2015/pdf/pi0415.pdf). In IQ2015, nominal personal income grew at 4.1 percent and at 5.3 percent in real terms excluding current transfer receipts while nominal disposable income grew at 3.2 percent and at 5.3 percent in real terms (http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2015/pdf/pi0415.pdf).

clip_image054

Chart, IB-8, US, Real Disposable Income, Percentage Change from Preceding Period at Seasonally-Adjusted Annual Rates, 2007-2015

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

The Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) estimates US personal income in Mar 2015 at the seasonally adjusted annual rate of $15,211.7 billion, as shown in Table IB-3 above (see Table 1 at http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2015/pdf/pi0415.pdf). The major portion of personal income is compensation of employees of $9,543.5 billion, or 62.7 percent of the total. Wages and salaries are $7,719.3 billion, of which $6,479.6 billion by private industries and supplements to wages and salaries of $1,824.2 billion (contributions to social insurance are $567.1 billion). In Oct 1988 (at the comparable month after the end of the 23rd quarter of cyclical expansion), US personal income was $4,382.9 billion at SAAR (http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm). Compensation of employees was $3,027.5 billion, or 69.1 percent of the total. Wages and salaries were $2,503.2 billion of which $2,044.6 billion by private industries. Supplements to wages and salaries were $524.3 billion with employer contributions to pension and insurance funds of $335.2 billion and $189.0 billion to government social insurance. Chart IB-9 provides US wages and salaries by private industries in the 1980s. Growth was robust after the interruption of the recessions.

clip_image055

Chart IB-9, US, Wages and Salaries, Private Industries, Quarterly, Seasonally Adjusted at Annual Rates Billions of Dollars, 1980-1989

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

The Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) estimates US personal income in Apr 2015 at the seasonally adjusted annual rate of $15,211.7 billion, as shown in Table IB-3 above (see Table 1 at http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2015/pdf/pi0415.pdf). The major portion of personal income is compensation of employees of $9,543.5 billion, or 62.7 percent of the total. Wages and salaries are $7,719.3 billion, of which $6,479.6 billion by private industries and supplements to wages and salaries of $1,824.2 billion (contributions to social insurance are $567.1 billion). In Oct 1988 (at the comparable month after the end of the 23rd quarter of cyclical expansion), US personal income was $4,382.9 billion at SAAR (http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm). Compensation of employees was $3,027.5 billion, or 69.1 percent of the total. Wages and salaries were $2,503.2 billion of which $2,044.6 billion by private industries. Supplements to wages and salaries were $524.3 billion with employer contributions to pension and insurance funds of $335.2 billion and $189.0 billion to government social insurance. Chart IB-10 provides US wages and salaries by private industries from 2007 to 2014. Growth was mediocre in the weak expansion phase after IIIQ2009.

clip_image056

Chart IB-10, US, Wage and Salary Disbursement, Private Industries, Quarterly, Seasonally Adjusted at Annual Rates, Billions of Dollars 2007-2015

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

Chart IB-11 provides finer detail with monthly wages and salaries of private industries from 2007 to 2015. Anticipations of income in late 2012 to avoid tax increases in 2013 cloud comparisons.

clip_image057

Chart IB-11, US, Wages and Salaries, Private Industries, Monthly, Seasonally Adjusted at Annual Rates, Billions of Dollars 2007-2015

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

Chart IB-12 provides monthly real disposable personal income per capita from 1980 to 1989. This is the ultimate measure of wellbeing in receiving income by obtaining the value per inhabitant. The measure cannot adjust for the distribution of income. Real disposable personal income per capita grew rapidly during the expansion after 1983 and continued growing during the rest of the decade.

clip_image058

Chart IB-12, US, Real Disposable Per Capita Income, Monthly, Seasonally Adjusted at Annual Rates, Chained 2009 Dollars 1980-1989

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

Table IB-5 provides the comparison between the cycle of the 1980s and the current cycle. Real per capita disposable income (RDPI-PC) increased 23.6 percent from Dec 1979 to Oct 1988. In the comparable period in the current cycle from Dec 2007 to Apr 2015, real per capita disposable income increased 6.7 percent.

Table IB-5, Percentage Changes of Real Disposable Personal Income Per Capita

Month

RDPI-PC ∆% 12/79

RDPI-PC ∆% YOY

Month

RDPI-PC ∆% 12/07

RDPI-PC ∆% YOY

11/1982

2.4

0.6

6/2009

-0.6

-2.4

12/1982

2.9

1.3

9/2009

-1.3

-0.6

12/1983

7.8

4.8

6/2010

-0.4

0.2

12/1987

20.4

2.7

6/2014

4.2

1.4

1/1988

20.6

2.6

7/2014

4.2

1.6

2/1988

21.2

2.6

8/2014

4.5

1.6

3/1988

21.6

2.9

9/2014

4.5

1.4

4/1988

21.9

7.4

10/2014

4.8

1.9

5/1988

22.0

3.3

11/2014

5.3

2.4

6/1988

22.4

3.9

12/2014

5.8

3.2

7/1988

22.7

4.0

1/2015

6.4

3.4

8/1988

23.0

3.8

2/2015

6.6

3.1

9/1988

23.1

4.0

3/2015

6.4

2.5

10/1988

23.6

3.9

4/2015

6.7

2.7

RDPI: Real Disposable Personal Income; RDPI-PC, Real Disposable Personal Income Per Capita

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

National Bureau of Economic Research

http://www.nber.org/cycles.html

Chart IB-13 provides monthly real disposable personal income per capita from 2007 to 2015. There was initial recovery from the drop during the global recession followed by stagnation.

clip_image059

Chart IB-13, US, Real Disposable Per Capita Income, Monthly, Seasonally Adjusted at Annual Rates, Chained 2009 Dollars 2007-2015

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

Table IB-6 provides data for analysis of the current cycle. Real disposable income (RDPI) increased 13.0 percent from Dec 2007 to Apr 2015 (column RDPI ∆% 12/07). In the same period, real disposable income per capita increased 6.7 percent (column RDPI-PC ∆% 12/07). The annual equivalent rate of increase of real disposable income per capita is 1.0 percent, only a fraction of 2.0 percent on average from 1929 to 2014, and 1.9 percent for real disposable income, much lower than 3.2 percent on average from 1929 to 2014.

Table IB-6, Percentage Changes of Real Disposable Personal Income and Real Disposable Personal Income Per Capita

Month

RDPI
∆% 12/07

RDPI ∆% Month

RDPI ∆% YOY

RDPI-PC ∆% 12/07

RDPI-PC ∆% Month

RDPI-PC ∆% YOY

6/09

0.8

-1.7

-1.5

-0.6

-1.8

-2.4

9/09

0.3

0.1

0.3

-1.3

0.1

-0.6

6/10

1.8

0.0

1.0

-0.4

0.0

0.2

12/10

3.4

0.7

2.9

0.7

0.6

2.1

6/11

4.2

0.4

2.3

1.2

0.4

1.5

12/11

5.0

0.8

1.6

1.6

0.7

0.8

6/12

6.9

0.1

2.7

3.1

0.1

1.9

10/12

7.7

0.6

3.2

3.5

0.5

2.5

11/12

9.2

1.4

4.8

4.9

1.4

4.1

12/12

12.3

2.8

7.0

7.9

2.8

6.2

6/13

7.4

0.2

0.4

2.7

0.1

-0.3

12/13

7.6

-0.2

-4.2

2.5

-0.3

-4.9

1/14

8.1

0.5

2.3

3.0

0.4

1.6

2/14

8.6

0.5

2.3

3.4

0.4

1.6

3/14

9.1

0.5

2.4

3.8

0.4

1.7

4/14

9.2

0.1

2.3

3.9

0.1

1.5

5/14

9.4

0.2

2.1

4.0

0.1

1.3

6/14

9.7

0.2

2.1

4.2

0.2

1.4

7/14

9.8

0.1

2.3

4.2

0.1

1.6

8/14

10.2

0.4

2.3

4.5

0.3

1.6

9/14

10.3

0.1

2.1

4.5

0.0

1.4

10/14

10.6

0.3

2.7

4.8

0.3

1.9

11/14

11.2

0.5

3.1

5.3

0.5

2.4

12/14

11.8

0.6

4.0

5.8

0.5

3.2

1/15

12.5

0.6

4.1

6.4

0.6

3.4

2/15

12.8

0.3

3.9

6.6

0.2

3.1

3/15

12.6

-0.2

3.2

6.4

-0.2

2.5

4/15

13.0

0.3

3.5

6.7

0.3

2.7

RDPI: Real Disposable Personal Income; RDPI-PC, Real Disposable Personal Income Per Capita

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis  http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

National Bureau of Economic Research

http://www.nber.org/cycles.html

IA2 Financial Repression. McKinnon (1973) and Shaw (1974) argue that legal restrictions on financial institutions can be detrimental to economic development. “Financial repression” is the term used in the economic literature for these restrictions (see Pelaez and Pelaez, Globalization and the State, Vol. II (2008b), 81-6; for historical analysis see Pelaez 1975). Theory and evidence support the role of financial institutions in efficiency and growth (Pelaez and Pelaez, Financial Regulation after the Global Recession (2009a), 22-6, Pelaez and Pelaez, Regulation of Banks and Finance (2009b), 37-44). Excessive official regulation frustrates financial development required for growth (Haber 2011). Emphasis on disclosure can reduce bank fragility and corruption, empowering investors to enforce sound governance (Barth, Caprio and Levine 2006). Banking was important in facilitating economic growth in historical periods (Cameron 1961, 1967, 1972; Cameron et al. 1992). Banking is also important currently because small- and medium-size business may have no other form of financing than banks in contrast with many options for larger and more mature companies that have access to capital markets. Calomiris and Haber (2014) find that broad voting rights and institutions restricting coalitions of bankers and populists ensure stable banking systems and access to credit. Interest rate ceilings on deposits and loans have been commonly used. The Banking Act of 1933 imposed prohibition of payment of interest on demand deposits and ceilings on interest rates on time deposits. These measures were justified by arguments that the banking panic of the 1930s was caused by competitive rates on bank deposits that led banks to engage in high-risk loans (Friedman, 1970, 18; see Pelaez and Pelaez, Regulation of Banks and Finance (2009b), 74-5). The objective of policy was to prevent unsound loans in banks. Savings and loan institutions complained of unfair competition from commercial banks that led to continuing controls with the objective of directing savings toward residential construction. Friedman (1970, 15) argues that controls were passive during periods when rates implied on demand deposit were zero or lower and when Regulation Q ceilings on time deposits were above market rates on time deposits. The Great Inflation or stagflation of the 1960s and 1970s changed the relevance of Regulation Q.

Most regulatory actions trigger compensatory measures by the private sector that result in outcomes that are different from those intended by regulation (Kydland and Prescott 1977). Banks offered services to their customers and loans at rates lower than market rates to compensate for the prohibition to pay interest on demand deposits (Friedman 1970, 24). The prohibition of interest on demand deposits was eventually lifted in recent times. In the second half of the 1960s, already in the beginning of the Great Inflation (DeLong 1997), market rates rose above the ceilings of Regulation Q because of higher inflation. Nobody desires savings allocated to time or savings deposits that pay less than expected inflation. This is a fact currently with zero interest rates and consumer price inflation of 0.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr 2015 (http://www.bls.gov/cpi/) but rising during waves of carry trades from zero interest rates to commodity futures exposures (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/05/interest-rate-policy-and-dollar.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/04/global-portfolio-reallocations-squeeze.html). Funding problems motivated compensatory measures by banks. Money-center banks developed the large certificate of deposit (CD) to accommodate increasing volumes of loan demand by customers. As Friedman (1970, 25) finds:

“Large negotiable CD’s were particularly hard hit by the interest rate ceiling because they are deposits of financially sophisticated individuals and institutions who have many alternatives. As already noted, they declined from a peak of $24 billion in mid-December, 1968, to less than $12 billion in early October, 1969.”

Banks created different liabilities to compensate for the decline in CDs. As Friedman (1970, 25; 1969) explains:

“The most important single replacement was almost surely ‘liabilities of US banks to foreign branches.’ Prevented from paying a market interest rate on liabilities of home offices in the United States (except to foreign official institutions that are exempt from Regulation Q), the major US banks discovered that they could do so by using the Euro-dollar market. Their European branches could accept time deposits, either on book account or as negotiable CD’s at whatever rate was required to attract them and match them on the asset side of their balance sheet with ‘due from head office.’ The head office could substitute the liability ‘due to foreign branches’ for the liability ‘due on CDs.”

Friedman (1970, 26-7) predicted the future:

“The banks have been forced into costly structural readjustments, the European banking system has been given an unnecessary competitive advantage, and London has been artificially strengthened as a financial center at the expense of New York.”

In short, Depression regulation exported the US financial system to London and offshore centers. What is vividly relevant currently from this experience is the argument by Friedman (1970, 27) that the controls affected the most people with lower incomes and wealth who were forced into accepting controlled-rates on their savings that were lower than those that would be obtained under freer markets. As Friedman (1970, 27) argues:

“These are the people who have the fewest alternative ways to invest their limited assets and are least sophisticated about the alternatives.”

Chart IB-14 of the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) provides quarterly savings as percent of disposable income or the US savings rate from 1980 to 2014. There was a long-term downward sloping trend from 12 percent in the early 1980s to 2.0 percent in Jul 2005. The savings rate then rose during the contraction and in the expansion. In 2011 and into 2012 the savings rate declined as consumption is financed with savings in part because of the disincentive or frustration of receiving a few pennies for every $10,000 of deposits in a bank. The savings rate increased in the final segment of Chart IB-14 in 2012 because of the “fiscal cliff” episode followed by another decline because of the pain of the opportunity cost of zero remuneration for hard-earned savings.

clip_image060

Chart IB-14, US, Personal Savings as a Percentage of Disposable Personal Income, Quarterly, 1980-2015

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

Chart IB-14A provides the US personal savings rate, or personal savings as percent of disposable personal income, on an annual basis from 1929 to 2014. The US savings rate shows decline from around 10 percent in the 1960s to around 5 percent currently.

clip_image061

Chart IB-14A, US, Personal Savings as a Percentage of Disposable Personal Income, Annual, 1929-2014

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

Table IB-7 provides personal savings as percent of disposable income and annual change of real disposable personal income in selected years since 1930. Savings fell from 4.4 percent of disposable personal income in 1930 to minus 0.8 percent in 1933 while real disposable income contracted 6.3 percent in 1930 and 2.9 percent in 1933. Savings as percent of disposable personal income swelled during World War II to 27.9 percent in 1944 with increase of real disposable income of 3.1 percent. Savings as percent of personal disposable income fell steadily over decades from 11.5 percent in 1982 to 2.5 percent in 2005. Savings as percent of disposable personal income was 4.9 percent in 2013 while real disposable income fell 0.2 percent. The savings rate was 4.9 percent of GDP in 2014 with growth of real disposable income of 2.5 percent. The average ratio of savings as percent of disposable income fell from 9.3 percent in 1980 to 1989 to 5.3 percent on average from 2007 to 2014. Real disposable income grew on average at 3.5 percent from 1980 to 1989 and at 1.5 percent on average from 2007 to 2014.

Table IB-7, US, Personal Savings as Percent of Disposable Personal Income, Annual, Selected Years 1929-1913

 

Personal Savings as Percent of Disposable Personal Income

Annual Change of Real Disposable Personal Income

1930

4.4

-6.3

1933

-0.8

-2.9

1944

27.9

3.1

1947

6.3

-4.1

1954

10.3

1.4

1958

11.4

1.1

1960

10.0

2.6

1970

12.6

4.6

1975

13.0

2.5

1982

11.5

2.1

1989

7.8

3.0

1992

8.9

4.3

2002

5.0

3.1

2003

4.8

2.7

2004

4.6

3.6

2005

2.5

1.5

2006

3.3

4.0

2007

3.0

2.1

2008

4.9

1.5

2009

6.1

-0.4

2010

5.6

1.0

2011

6.0

2.5

2012

7.2

3.0

2013

4.9

-0.2

2014

4.9

2.5

Average Savings Ratio

   

1980-1989

9.3

 

2007-2014

5.3

 

Average Yearly ∆% Real Disposable Income

   

1980-1989

 

3.5

2007-2014

 

1.5

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

Chart IB-15 of the US Bureau of Economic Analysis provides personal savings as percent of personal disposable income, or savings ratio, from Jan 2007 to Apr 2015. The uncertainties caused by the global recession resulted in sharp increase in the savings ratio that peaked at 7.9 percent in May 2008 (http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm). The second peak occurred at 8.1 percent in May 2009. There was another rising trend until 5.9 percent in Jun 2010 and then steady downward trend until 5.6 percent in Nov 2011. This was followed by an upward trend with 7.1 percent in Jun 2012 but decline to 6.4 percent in Aug 2012 followed by jump to 10.5 percent in Dec 2012. Swelling realization of income in Oct-Dec 2012 in anticipation of tax increases in Jan 2013 caused the jump of the savings rate to 10.5 percent in Dec 2012. The BEA explains as “Personal income in November and December was boosted by accelerated and special dividend payments to persons and by accelerated bonus payments and other irregular pay in private wages and salaries in anticipation of changes in individual income tax rates. Personal income in December was also boosted by lump-sum social security benefit payments” (page 2 at http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2013/pdf/pi1212.pdf). There was a reverse effect in Jan 2013 with decline of the savings rate to 4.5 percent. Real disposable personal income fell 5.9 percent and real disposable per capita income fell from $38,699 in Dec 2012 to $36.378 in Jan 2013 or by 6.0 percent (http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm), which is explained by the Bureau of Economic Analysis as follows (page 3 http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/pi/2013/pdf/pi0213.pdf):

“Contributions for government social insurance -- a subtraction in calculating personal income --increased $6.4 billion in February, compared with an increase of $126.8 billion in January. The

January estimate reflected increases in both employer and employee contributions for government social insurance. The January estimate of employee contributions for government social insurance reflected the expiration of the “payroll tax holiday,” that increased the social security contribution rate for employees and self-employed workers by 2.0 percentage points, or $114.1 billion at an annual rate. For additional information, see FAQ on “How did the expiration of the payroll tax holiday affect personal income for January 2013?” at www.bea.gov. The January estimate of employee contributions for government social insurance also reflected an increase in the monthly premiums paid by participants in the supplementary medical insurance program, in the hospital insurance provisions of the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act, and in the social security taxable wage base; together, these changes added $12.9 billion to January. Employer contributions were boosted $5.9 billion in January, which reflected increases in the social security taxable wage base (from $110,100 to $113,700), in the tax rates paid by employers to state unemployment insurance, and in employer contributions for the federal unemployment tax and for pension guaranty. The total contribution of special factors to the January change in contributions for government social insurance was $132.9 billion.”

clip_image062

Chart IB-15, US, Personal Savings as a Percentage of Disposable Income, Monthly 2007-2015

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

Table IB-8 provides personal saving as percent of disposable income, change of real disposable income relative to Dec 2007 (RDPI ∆% 12/07), monthly percentage change of real disposable income (RDPI ∆% month) and percentage change of real disposable income in a month relative to the same month a year earlier (RDPI ∆% YOY). The ratio of personal saving to disposable income eased to 5.6 percent in Apr 2015 with cumulative growth of real disposable income of 13.0 percent since Dec 2007 at the rate of 1.9 percent annual equivalent, which is much lower than 3.2 percent over the long term from 1929 to 2014.

Table IB-8, US, Savings Ratio and Real Disposable Income, % and ∆%

 

Personal Saving as % Disposable Income

RDPI ∆% 12/07

RDPI ∆% Month

RDPI ∆% YOY

May 2008

7.9

5.1

4.8

5.7

May 2009

8.1

2.5

1.6

-2.5

Jun 2010

5.9

1.8

0.0

1.0

Nov 2011

5.6

4.2

-0.1

1.5

Jun 2012

7.1

6.9

0.1

2.7

Aug 2012

6.4

6.5

-0.2

1.9

Dec 2012

10.5

12.3

2.8

7.0

Jan 2013

4.5

5.6

-5.9

-0.1

Feb 2013

4.7

6.2

0.5

-0.2

Mar 2013

4.9

6.5

0.4

0.0

Apr 2013

5.1

6.8

0.2

0.0

May 2013

5.2

7.2

0.4

0.4

Jun 2013

5.3

7.4

0.2

0.4

Jul 2013

5.1

7.3

-0.1

0.6

Aug 2013

5.3

7.7

0.4

1.1

Sep 2013

5.2

8.0

0.3

0.9

Oct 2013

4.7

7.7

-0.3

0.0

Nov 2013

4.3

7.8

0.1

-1.3

Dec 2013

4.1

7.6

-0.2

-4.2

Jan 2014

4.9

8.1

0.5

2.3

Feb 2014

5.0

8.6

0.5

2.3

Mar 2014

4.8

9.1

0.5

2.4

Apr 2014

5.0

9.2

0.1

2.3

May 2014

5.1

9.4

0.2

2.1

Jun 2014

5.1

9.7

0.2

2.1

Jul 2014

5.1

9.8

0.1

2.3

Aug 2014

4.7

10.2

0.4

2.3

Sep 2014

4.6

10.3

0.1

2.1

Oct 2014

4.6

10.6

0.3

2.7

Nov 2014

4.5

11.2

0.5

3.1

Dec 2014

5.0

11.8

0.6

4.0

Jan 2015

5.5

12.5

0.6

4.1

Feb 2015

5.7

12.8

0.3

3.9

Mar 2015

5.2

12.6

-0.2

3.2

Apr 2015

5.6

13.0

0.3

3.5

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

© Carlos M. Pelaez, 2009, 2010, 2011, 2012, 2013, 2014, 2015.

No comments:

Post a Comment