Monday, November 10, 2014

Rules, Discretionary Authorities and Slows Productivity Growth, Twenty Seven Million Unemployed or Underemployed, Stagnating Real Wages, United States International Trade, World Cyclical Slow Growth and Global Recession Risk: Part I

 

Rules, Discretionary Authorities and Slows Productivity Growth, Twenty Seven Million Unemployed or Underemployed, Stagnating Real Wages, United States International Trade, World Cyclical Slow Growth and Global Recession Risk

Carlos M. Pelaez

© Carlos M. Pelaez, 2009, 2010, 2011, 2012, 2013, 2014

I Twenty Seven Million Unemployed or Underemployed

IA1 Summary of the Employment Situation

IA2 Number of People in Job Stress

IA3 Long-term and Cyclical Comparison of Employment

IA4 Job Creation

IB Stagnating Real Wages

II Rules, Discretionary Authorities and Slow Productivity Growth

IIA United States International Trade

III World Financial Turbulence

IIIA Financial Risks

IIIE Appendix Euro Zone Survival Risk

IIIF Appendix on Sovereign Bond Valuation

IV Global Inflation

V World Economic Slowdown

VA United States

VB Japan

VC China

VD Euro Area

VE Germany

VF France

VG Italy

VH United Kingdom

VI Valuation of Risk Financial Assets

VII Economic Indicators

VIII Interest Rates

IX Conclusion

References

Appendixes

Appendix I The Great Inflation

IIIB Appendix on Safe Haven Currencies

IIIC Appendix on Fiscal Compact

IIID Appendix on European Central Bank Large Scale Lender of Last Resort

IIIG Appendix on Deficit Financing of Growth and the Debt Crisis

IIIGA Monetary Policy with Deficit Financing of Economic Growth

IIIGB Adjustment during the Debt Crisis of the 1980s

I Twenty Seven Million Unemployed or Underemployed. This section analyzes the employment situation report of the United States of the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS). There are four subsections: IA1 Summary of the Employment Situation; IA2 Number of People in Job Stress; IA3 Long-term and Cyclical Comparison of Employment; and IA4 Job Creation.

IA1 Summary of the Employment Situation. Table I-1 provides summary statistics of the employment situation report of the BLS. The first four rows provide the data from the establishment report of creation of nonfarm payroll jobs and remuneration of workers (for analysis of the differences in employment between the establishment report and the household survey see Abraham, Haltiwanger, Sandusky and Spletzer 2009). Total nonfarm payroll employment seasonally adjusted (SA) increased 214,000 in Oct 2014 and private payroll employment increased 209,000. The average monthly number of nonfarm jobs created from Oct 2012 to Oct 2013 was 199,167 using seasonally adjusted data, while the average number of nonfarm jobs created from Oct 2013 to Oct 2014 was 220,250, or increase by 10.6 percent. The average number of private jobs created in the US from Oct 2012 to Oct 2013 was 202,750, using seasonally adjusted data, while the average from Oct 2013 to Oct 2014 was 215,250, or increase by 6.2 percent. This blog calculates the effective labor force of the US at 163.104 million in Oct 2013 and 164.611 million in Oct 2014 (Table I-4), for growth of 1.507 million at average 125,583 per month. The difference between the average increase of 215,250 new private nonfarm jobs per month in the US from Oct 2013 to Oct 2014 and the 125,583 average monthly increase in the labor force from Oct 2013 to Oct 2014 is 89,667 monthly new jobs net of absorption of new entrants in the labor force. There are 26.554 million in job stress in the US currently. Creation of 89,667 new jobs per month net of absorption of new entrants in the labor force would require 296 months to provide jobs for the unemployed and underemployed (26.554 million divided by 89,667) or 25 years (294 divided by 12). The civilian labor force of the US in Oct 2014 not seasonally adjusted stood at 156.616 million with 8.680 million unemployed or effectively 16.675 million unemployed in this blog’s calculation by inferring those who are not searching because they believe there is no job for them for effective labor force of 164.611 million. Reduction of one million unemployed at the current rate of job creation without adding more unemployment requires 0.9 years (1 million divided by product of 89,667 by 12, which is 1,076,000). Reduction of the rate of unemployment to 5 percent of the labor force would be equivalent to unemployment of only 7.831 million (0.05 times labor force of 156.616 million). New net job creation would be 0.849 million (8.680 million unemployed minus 7.831 million unemployed at rate of 5 percent) that at the current rate would take 0.8 years (0.849 million divided by 1.076). Under the calculation in this blog, there are 16.675 million unemployed by including those who ceased searching because they believe there is no job for them and effective labor force of 164.611 million. Reduction of the rate of unemployment to 5 percent of the labor force would require creating 9.464 million jobs net of labor force growth that at the current rate would take 7.8 years (16.675 million minus 0.05(164.611 million) = 8.444 million divided by 1.076, using LF PART 66.2% and Total UEM in Table I-4). These calculations assume that there are no more recessions, defying United States economic history with periodic contractions of economic activity when unemployment increases sharply. The number employed in Oct 2014 was 147.936 million (NSA) or 0.621 million more people with jobs relative to the peak of 147.315 million in Jul 2007 while the civilian noninstitutional population of ages 16 years and over increased from 231.958 million in Jul 2007 to 248.657 million in Oct 2014 or by 16.699 million. The number employed increased 0.4 percent from Jul 2007 to Oct 2014 while the noninstitutional civilian population of ages of 16 years and over, or those available for work, increased 7.2 percent. The ratio of employment to population in Jul 2007 was 63.5 percent (147.315 million employment as percent of population of 231.958 million). The same ratio in Oct 2014 would result in 157.897 million jobs (0.635 multiplied by noninstitutional civilian population of 248.657 million). There are effectively 9.961 million fewer jobs in Oct 2014 than in Jul 2007, or 157.897 million minus 147.936 million. There is actually not sufficient job creation in merely absorbing new entrants in the labor force because of those dropping from job searches, worsening the stock of unemployed or underemployed in involuntary part-time jobs.

There is current interest in past theories of “secular stagnation.” Alvin H. Hansen (1939, 4, 7; see Hansen 1938, 1941; for an early critique see Simons 1942) argues:

“Not until the problem of full employment of our productive resources from the long-run, secular standpoint was upon us, were we compelled to give serious consideration to those factors and forces in our economy which tend to make business recoveries weak and anaemic (sic) and which tend to prolong and deepen the course of depressions. This is the essence of secular stagnation-sick recoveries which die in their infancy and depressions which feed on them-selves and leave a hard and seemingly immovable core of unemployment. Now the rate of population growth must necessarily play an important role in determining the character of the output; in other words, the com-position of the flow of final goods. Thus a rapidly growing population will demand a much larger per capita volume of new residential building construction than will a stationary population. A stationary population with its larger proportion of old people may perhaps demand more personal services; and the composition of consumer demand will have an important influence on the quantity of capital required. The demand for housing calls for large capital outlays, while the demand for personal services can be met without making large investment expenditures. It is therefore not unlikely that a shift from a rapidly growing population to a stationary or declining one may so alter the composition of the final flow of consumption goods that the ratio of capital to output as a whole will tend to decline.”

The argument that anemic population growth causes “secular stagnation” in the US (Hansen 1938, 1939, 1941) is as misplaced currently as in the late 1930s (for early dissent see Simons 1942). There is currently population growth in the ages of 16 to 24 years but not enough job creation and discouragement of job searches for all ages (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/09/geopolitics-monetary-policy-and.html). The proper explanation is not in secular stagnation but in cyclically slow growth. The US maintained growth at 3.0 percent on average over entire cycles with expansions at higher rates compensating for contractions. Growth at trend in the entire cycle from IVQ2007 to IIIQ2014 would have accumulated to 23.0 percent. GDP in IIIQ2014 would be $18,438.0 billion (in constant dollars of 2009) if the US had grown at trend, which is higher by $2,287.4 billion than actual $16,150.6 billion. There are about two trillion dollars of GDP less than at trend, explaining the 26.6 million unemployed or underemployed equivalent to actual unemployment of 16.1 percent of the effective labor force (Section I and earlier (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/10/world-financial-turbulence-twenty-seven.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/09/competitive-monetary-policy-and.html). US GDP in IIIQ2014 is 12.4 percent lower than at trend. US GDP grew from $14,991.8 billion in IVQ2007 in constant dollars to $16,150.6 billion in IIIQ2014 or 7.7 percent at the average annual equivalent rate of 1.1 percent. Cochrane (2014Jul2) estimates US GDP at more than 10 percent below trend. The US missed the opportunity to grow at higher rates during the expansion and it is difficult to catch up because growth rates in the final periods of expansions tend to decline. The US missed the opportunity for recovery of output and employment always afforded in the first four quarters of expansion from recessions. Zero interest rates and quantitative easing were not required or present in successful cyclical expansions and in secular economic growth at 3.0 percent per year and 2.0 percent per capita as measured by Lucas (2011May). There is cyclical uncommonly slow growth in the US instead of allegations of secular stagnation. There is similar behavior in manufacturing. The long-term trend is growth at average 3.3 percent per year from Jan 1919 to Sep 2014. Growth at 3.3 percent per year would raise the NSA index of manufacturing output from 99.2392 in Dec 2007 to 123.5550 in Sep 2014. The actual index NSA in Sep 2014 is 102.0228, which is 17.4 percent below trend. Manufacturing output grew at average 2.3 percent between Dec 1986 and Dec 2013, raising the index at trend to 115.7028 in Sep 2014. The output of manufacturing at 102.0228 in Sep 2014 is 11.8 percent below trend under this alternative calculation. The output of manufacturing at 101.5145 in Aug 2014 is 13.8 percent below trend under this alternative calculation. Secular stagnation is merely another case of theory without reality with dubious policy proposals. Subsection IA4 Job Creation analyzes the types of jobs created, which are lower paying than earlier. Average hourly earnings in Oct 2014 were $24.57 seasonally adjusted (SA), increasing 2.0 percent not seasonally adjusted (NSA) relative to Oct 2013 and increasing 0.1 percent relative to Sep 2014 seasonally adjusted. In Sep 2014, average hourly earnings seasonally adjusted were $24.54, increasing 1.4 percent relative to Sep 2013 not seasonally adjusted and changing 0.0 percent seasonally adjusted relative to Aug 2014. These are nominal changes in workers’ wages. The following row “average hourly earnings in constant dollars” provides hourly wages in constant dollars calculated by the BLS or what is called “real wages” adjusted for inflation. Data are not available for Sep 2013 because the prices indexes of the BLS for Oct 2014 will only be released on Nov 20, 2014 (http://www.bls.gov/cpi/), which will be covered in this blog’s comment on Nov 23, 2014, together with world inflation. The second column provides changes in real wages for Sep 2014. Average hourly earnings adjusted for inflation or in constant dollars decreased 0.3 percent in Sep 2014 relative to Sep 2013 but have been decreasing during multiple months. World inflation waves in bouts of risk aversion (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/10/financial-oscillations-world-inflation.html) mask declining trend of real wages. The fractured labor market of the US is characterized by high levels of unemployment and underemployment together with falling real wages or wages adjusted for inflation (Section I and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/10/world-financial-turbulence-twenty-seven.html). The following section IB Stagnating Real Wages provides more detailed analysis. Average weekly hours of US workers seasonally adjusted remained virtually unchanged at 34.5. Another headline number widely followed is the unemployment rate or number of people unemployed as percent of the labor force. The unemployment rate calculated in the household survey decreased from 5.9 percent in Sep 2014 to 5.8 percent in Oct 2014, seasonally adjusted. This blog provides with every employment situation report the number of people in the US in job stress or unemployed plus underemployed calculated without seasonal adjustment (NSA) at 26.6 million in Oct 2014 and 26.5 million in Sep 2014. The final row in Table I-1 provides the number in job stress as percent of the actual labor force calculated at 16.1 percent in Oct 2014 and 16.1 percent in Oct 2014. Almost one in every five workers in the US is unemployed or underemployed. There is socio-economic stress in the combination of adverse events and cyclical performance: 

Table I-1, US, Summary of the Employment Situation Report SA

 

Oct 2014

Sep 2014

New Nonfarm Payroll Jobs

214,000

256,000

New Private Payroll Jobs

209,000

244,000

Average Hourly Earnings

Oct 14 $24.57 SA

∆% Oct 14/ Oct 13 NSA: 2.0

∆% Oct 14/Sep 14 SA: 0.1

Sep 14 $24.54 SA

∆% Sep 14/Sep 13 NSA: 1.4

∆% Sep 14/Aug 13 SA: 0.0

Average Hourly Earnings in Constant Dollars

 

∆% Sep 2014/Sep 2013 NSA: -0.3

Average Weekly Hours

34.6 SA

34.5 NSA

34.5 SA

34.5 NSA

Unemployment Rate Household Survey % of Labor Force SA

5.8

5.9

Number in Job Stress Unemployed and Underemployed Blog Calculation

26.6 million NSA

26.5 million NSA

In Job Stress as % Labor Force

16.1 NSA

16.1 NSA

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/

The Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) of the US Department of Labor provides both seasonally adjusted (SA) and not-seasonally adjusted (NSA) or unadjusted data with important uses (Bureau of Labor Statistics 2012Feb3; 2011Feb11):

“Most series published by the Current Employment Statistics program reflect a regularly recurring seasonal movement that can be measured from past experience. By eliminating that part of the change attributable to the normal seasonal variation, it is possible to observe the cyclical and other nonseasonal movements in these series. Seasonally adjusted series are published monthly for selected employment, hours, and earnings estimates.”

Requirements of using best available information and updating seasonality factors affect the comparability over time of United States employment data. In the first month of the year, the BLS revises data for several years by adjusting benchmarks and seasonal factors (page 4 at http://www.bls.gov/news.release/pdf/empsit.pdf ), which is the case of the data for Jan 2014 released on Feb 7, 2014:

“In accordance with annual practice, the establishment survey data released today [Feb 7, 2014] have been benchmarked to reflect comprehensive counts of payroll jobs for March 2013. These counts are derived principally from the Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages (QCEW), which enumerates jobs covered by the UI tax system. The benchmark process results in revisions to not seasonally adjusted data from April 2012 forward. Seasonally adjusted data from January 2009 forward are subject to revision. In addition, data for some series prior to 2009, both seasonally adjusted and unadjusted, incorporate revisions.”

The range of differences in total nonfarm employment in revisions in Table A of the employment situation report for Jan 2014 (page 5 at http://www.bls.gov/news.release/pdf/empsit.pdf) is from minus 1,000 for Mar 2013 to 274,000 for Nov 2013. There are also adjustments of population that affect comparability of labor statistics over time (page 6 at http://www.bls.gov/news.release/pdf/empsit.pdf):

“Effective with data for January 2014, updated population estimates have been used in the household survey. Population estimates for the household survey are developed by the U.S. Census Bureau. Each year, the Census Bureau updates the estimates to reflect new information and assumptions about the growth of the population since the previous decennial census. The change in population reflected in the new estimates results from adjustments for net international migration, updated vital statistics and other information, and some methodological changes in the estimation process.

In accordance with usual practice, BLS will not revise the official household survey estimates for

December 2013 and earlier months. To show the impact of the population adjustments, however, differences in selected December 2013 labor force series based on the old and new population estimates are shown in table B.

The adjustments increased the estimated size of the civilian noninstitutional population in December by 2,000, the civilian labor force by 24,000, employment by 22,000, and unemployment by 2,000. The number of persons not in the labor force was reduced by 22,000. The total unemployment rate, employment-population ratio, and labor force participation rate were unaffected.

Data users are cautioned that these annual population adjustments can affect the comparability of household data series over time. Table C shows the effect of the introduction of new population estimates on the comparison of selected labor force measures between December 2013 and January 2014. Additional information on the population adjustments and their effect on national labor force estimates is available at www.bls.gov/cps/cps14adj.pdf (emphasis added).”

There are also adjustments of benchmarks and seasonality factors for establishment data that affect comparability over time (page 1 at http://www.bls.gov/news.release/pdf/empsit.pdf):

“Establishment survey data have been revised as a result of the annual benchmarking process and the updating of seasonal adjustment factors. Also, household survey data for January 2014 reflect updated population estimates. See the notes beginning on page 4 for more information about these changes.”

All comparisons over time are affected by yearly adjustments of benchmarks and seasonality factors. All data in this blog comment use revised data released by the BLS on Feb 7, 2014 (http://www.bls.gov/).

IA2 Number of People in Job Stress. There are two approaches to calculating the number of people in job stress. The first approach consists of calculating the number of people in job stress unemployed or underemployed with the raw data of the employment situation report as in Table I-2. The data are seasonally adjusted (SA). The first three rows provide the labor force and unemployed in millions and the unemployment rate of unemployed as percent of the labor force. There is decrease in the number unemployed from 9.591 million in Aug 2014 to 9.262 million in Sep 2014 and decrease to 8.995 million in Oct 2014. The rate of unemployment decreased from 6.1 percent in Aug 2014 to 5.9 percent in Sep 2014 and decreased to 5.8 percent in Oct 2014. An important aspect of unemployment is its persistence for more than 27 weeks with 2.916 million in Oct 2014, corresponding to 32.4 percent of the unemployed. The longer the period of unemployment the lower are the chances of finding another job with many long-term unemployed ceasing to search for a job. Another key characteristic of the current labor market is the high number of people trying to subsist with part-time jobs because they cannot find full-time employment or part-time for economic reasons. The BLS explains as follows: “these individuals were working part time because their hours had been cut back or because they were unable to find full-time work” (http://www.bls.gov/news.release/pdf/empsit.pdf 2). The number of part-time for economic reasons decreased from 7.277 million in Aug 2014 to 7.103 million in Sep 2014 and decreased to 7.027 million in Oct 2014. Another important fact is the marginally attached to the labor force. The BLS explains as follows: “these individuals were not in the labor force, wanted and were available for work, and had looked for a job sometime in the prior 12 months. They were not counted as unemployed because they had not searched for work in the 4 weeks preceding the survey” (http://www.bls.gov/news.release/pdf/empsit.pdf 2). The number in job stress unemployed or underemployed of 18.214 million in Oct 2014 is composed of:

· 8.995 million unemployed (of whom 2.916 million, or 32.4 percent, unemployed for 27 weeks or more) compared with 9.262 million unemployed in Sep 2014 (of whom 2.954 million, or 31.9 percent, unemployed for 27 weeks or more),

· 7.027 million employed part-time for economic reasons in Oct 2014 (who suffered reductions in their work hours or could not find full-time employment) compared with 7.103 million in Sep 2014

· 2.192 million who were marginally attached to the labor force in Oct 2014 (who were not in the labor force but wanted and were available for work) compared with 2.226 million in Sep 2014

The final row in Table I-2 provides the number in job stress as percent of the labor force: 11.7 percent in Oct 2014, which is close to 11.9 percent in Sep 2014 and 12.2 percent in Aug 2014.

Table I-2, US, People in Job Stress, Millions and % SA

2014

Oct 2014

Sep 2014

Aug 2014

Labor Force Millions

156.278

155.862

155.959

Unemployed
Millions

8.995

9.262

9.591

Unemployment Rate (unemployed as % labor force)

5.8

5.9

6.1

Unemployed ≥27 weeks
Millions

2.916

2.954

2.963

Unemployed ≥27 weeks %

32.4

31.9

30.9

Part Time for Economic Reasons
Millions

7.027

7.103

7.277

Marginally
Attached to Labor Force
Millions

2.192

2.226

2.141

Job Stress
Millions

18.214

18.591

19.009

In Job Stress as % Labor Force

11.7

11.9

12.2

Job Stress = Unemployed + Part Time Economic Reasons + Marginally Attached Labor Force

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/cps/

Table I-3 repeats the data in Table I-2 but including Jul and additional data. What really matters is the number of people with jobs or the total employed, representing the opportunity for exit from unemployment. The final row of Table I-3 provides people employed as percent of the population or employment to population ratio. The number has remained relatively constant around 59 percent, reaching 59.0 in Jul 2014, 59.0 in Aug 2014, 59.0 in Sep 2014 and 59.2 in Oct 2014. The employment to population ratio fell from an annual level of 63.1 percent in 2006 to 58.6 percent in 2012 and 58.6 percent in 2013 with the lowest level at 58.4 percent in 2011.

Table I-3, US, Unemployment and Underemployment, SA, Millions and Percent

 

Oct 2014

Sep 2014

Aug 2014

Jul 2014

Labor Force

156.278

155.862

155.959

156.023

Participation Rate

62.8

62.7

62.8

62.9

Unemployed

8.995

9.262

9.591

9.671

UNE Rate %

5.8

5.9

6.1

6.2

Part Time Economic Reasons

7.027

7.103

7.277

7.511

Marginally Attached to Labor Force

2.192

2.226

2.141

2.178

In Job Stress

18.214

18.591

19.009

19.360

In Job Stress % Labor Force

11.7

11.9

12.2

12.4

Employed

147.283

146.600

146.368

146.352

Employment % Population

59.2

59.0

59.0

59.0

Job Stress = Unemployed + Part Time Economic Reasons + Marginally Attached Labor Force

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/cps/

The balance of this section considers the second approach. Charts I-1 to I-12 explain the reasons for considering another approach to calculating job stress in the US. Chart I-1 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics provides the level of employment in the US from 2001 to 2014. There was a big drop of the number of people employed from 147.315 million at the peak in Jul 2007 (NSA) to 136.809 million at the trough in Jan 2010 (NSA) with 10.506 million fewer people employed. Recovery has been anemic compared with the shallow recession of 2001 that was followed by nearly vertical growth in jobs. The number employed in Oct 2014 was 147.936 million (NSA) or 0.621 million more people with jobs relative to the peak of 147.315 million in Jul 2007 while the civilian noninstitutional population of ages 16 years and over increased from 231.958 million in Jul 2007 to 248.657 million in Oct 2014 or by 16.699 million. The number employed increased 0.4 percent from Jul 2007 to Oct 2014 while the noninstitutional civilian population of ages of 16 years and over, or those available for work, increased 7.2 percent. The ratio of employment to population in Jul 2007 was 63.5 percent (147.315 million employment as percent of population of 231.958 million). The same ratio in Oct 2014 would result in 157.897 million jobs (0.635 multiplied by noninstitutional civilian population of 248.657 million). There are effectively 9.961 million fewer jobs in Oct 2014 than in Jul 2007, or 157.897 million minus 147.936 million. There is actually not sufficient job creation in merely absorbing new entrants in the labor force because of those dropping from job searches, worsening the stock of unemployed or underemployed in involuntary part-time jobs.

clip_image001

Chart I-1, US, Employed, Thousands, SA, 2001-2014

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-2 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics provides 12-month percentage changes of the number of people employed in the US from 2001 to 2014. There was recovery since 2010 but not sufficient to recover lost jobs. Many people in the US who had jobs before the global recession are not working now.

clip_image002

Chart I-2, US, Employed, 12-Month Percentage Change NSA, 2001-2014

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The foundation of the second approach derives from Chart II-3 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics providing the level of the civilian labor force in the US. The civilian labor force consists of people who are available and willing to work and who have searched for employment recently. The labor force of the US grew 9.4 percent from 142.828 million in Jan 2001 to 156.255 million in Jul 2009 but is only 0.2 percent higher at 156.616 million in Oct 2014, all numbers not seasonally adjusted. Chart I-3 shows the flattening of the curve of expansion of the labor force and its decline in 2010 and 2011. The ratio of the labor force of 154.871 million in Jul 2007 to the noninstitutional population of 231.958 million in Jul 2007 was 66.8 percent while the ratio of the labor force of 156.616 million in Oct 2014 to the noninstitutional population of 248.657 million in Oct 2014 was 63.0 percent. The labor force of the US in Oct 2014 corresponding to 66.8 percent of participation in the population would be 166.103 million (0.668 x 248.657). The difference between the measured labor force in Oct 2014 of 156.616 million and the labor force in Oct 2014 with participation rate of 66.8 percent (as in Jul 2007) of 166.103 million is 9.487 million. The level of the labor force in the US has stagnated and is 9.487 million lower than what it would have been had the same participation rate been maintained. Millions of people have abandoned their search for employment because they believe there are no jobs available for them. The key issue is whether the decline in participation of the population in the labor force is the result of people giving up on finding another job.

clip_image003

Chart I-3, US, Civilian Labor Force, Thousands, SA, 2001-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-4 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics provides 12-month percentage changes of the level of the labor force in the US. The rate of growth fell almost instantaneously with the global recession and became negative from 2009 to 2011. The labor force of the US collapsed and did not recover. Growth in the beginning of the summer originates in younger people looking for jobs in the summer after graduation or during school recess.

clip_image004

Chart I-4, US, Civilian Labor Force, Thousands, NSA, 12-month Percentage Change, 2001-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-5 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics provides the labor force participation rate in the US or labor force as percent of the population. The labor force participation rate of the US fell from 66.8 percent in Jan 2001 to 62.8 percent NSA in Sep 2014, all numbers not seasonally adjusted. The annual labor force participation rate for 1979 was 63.7 percent and also 63.7 percent in Nov 1980 during sharp economic contraction. This comparison is further elaborated below. Chart I-5 shows an evident downward trend beginning with the global recession that has continued throughout the recovery beginning in IIIQ2009. The critical issue is whether people left the workforce of the US because they believe there is no longer a job for them.

clip_image005

Chart I-5, Civilian Labor Force Participation Rate, Percent of Population in Labor Force SA, 2001-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-6 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics provides the level of unemployed in the US. The number unemployed rose from the trough of 6.272 million NSA in Oct 2006 to the peak of 16.147 million in Jan 2010, declining to 13.400 million in Jul 2012, 12.696 million in Aug 2012 and 11.741 million in Sep 2012. The level unemployed fell to 11.741 million in Oct 2012, 11.404 million in Nov 2012, 11.844 million in Dec 2012, 13.181 million in Jan 2013, 12.500 million in Feb 2013 and 9.984 million in Dec 2013. The level of unemployment reached 8.995 million in Oct 2014, all numbers not seasonally adjusted.

clip_image006

Chart I-6, US, Unemployed, Thousands, SA, 2001-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-7 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics provides the rate of unemployment in the US or unemployed as percent of the labor force. The rate of unemployment of the US rose from 4.7 percent in Jan 2001 to 6.5 percent in Jun 2003, declining to 4.1 percent in Oct 2006. The rate of unemployment jumped to 10.6 percent in Jan 2010 and declined to 7.6 percent in Dec 2012 but increased to 8.5 percent in Jan 2013 and 8.1 percent in Feb 2013, falling back to 7.3 percent in May 2013 and 7.8 percent in Jun 2013, all numbers not seasonally adjusted. The rate of unemployment not seasonally adjusted stabilized at 7.7 percent in Jul 2013 and fell to 6.5 percent in Dec 2013 and 5.5 percent in Oct 2014.

clip_image007

Chart I-7, US, Unemployment Rate, SA, 2001-2014

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-8 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics provides 12-month percentage changes of the level of unemployed. There was a jump of 81.8 percent in Apr 2009 with subsequent decline and negative rates since 2010. On an annual basis, the level of unemployed rose 59.8 percent in 2009 and 26.1 percent in 2008 with increase of 3.9 percent in 2010, decline of 7.3 percent in 2011 and decrease of 9.0 percent in 2012. The annual level of unemployment decreased 8.4 percent in 2013 and fell 19.4 percent in Oct 2014 relative to Oct 2013.

clip_image008

Chart I-8, US, Unemployed, 12-month Percentage Change, NSA, 2001-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-9 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics provides the number of people in part-time occupations because of economic reasons, that is, because they cannot find full-time employment. The number underemployed in part-time occupations not seasonally adjusted rose from 3.732 million in Jan 2001 to 5.270 million in Jan 2004, falling to 3.787 million in Apr 2006. The number underemployed seasonally adjusted jumped to 9.114 million in Nov 2009, falling to 8.177 million in Dec 2011 but increasing to 8.228 million in Jan 2012 and 8.133 million in Feb 2012 but then falling to 7.929 million in Dec 2012 and increasing to 8.180 million in Jul 2013. The number employed part-time for economic reasons seasonally adjusted reached 7.771 million in Dec 2013 and 7.103 million in Sep 2014. Without seasonal adjustment, the number employed part-time for economic reasons reached 9.354 million in Dec 2009, declining to 8.918 million in Jan 2012 and 8.166 million in Dec 2012 but increasing to 8.324 million in Jul 2013. The number employed part-time for economic reasons NSA stood at 7.990 million in Dec 2013 and 6.787 million in Oct 2014. The longer the period in part-time jobs the lower are the chances of finding another full-time job.

clip_image009

Chart I-9, US, Part-Time for Economic Reasons, Thousands, SA, 2001-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-10 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics repeats the behavior of unemployment. The 12-month percentage change of the level of people at work part-time for economic reasons jumped 84.7 percent in Mar 2009 and declined subsequently. The declines have been insufficient to reduce significantly the number of people who cannot shift from part-time to full-time employment. On an annual basis, the number of part-time for economic reasons increased 33.5 percent in 2008 and 51.7 percent in 2009, declining 0.4 percent in 2010, 3.5 percent in 2011 and 5.1 percent in 2012. The annual number of part-time for economic reasons decreased 2.3 percent in 2013. The number of part-time for economic reasons fell 11.9 percent in Oct 2014 relative to a year earlier.

clip_image010

Chart I-10, US, Part-Time for Economic Reasons NSA 12-Month Percentage Change, 2001-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-11 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics provides the same pattern of the number marginally attached to the labor force jumping to significantly higher levels during the global recession and remaining at historically high levels. The number marginally attached to the labor force not seasonally adjusted increased from 1.295 million in Jan 2001 to 1.691 million in Feb 2004. The number of marginally attached to the labor force fell to 1.299 million in Sep 2006 and increased to 2.609 million in Dec 2010 and 2.800 million in Jan 2011. The number marginally attached to the labor force was 2.540 million in Dec 2011, increasing to 2.809 million in Jan 2012, falling to 2.608 million in Feb 2012. The number marginally attached to the labor force fell to 2.352 million in Mar 2012, 2.363 million in Apr 2012, 2.423 million in May 2012, 2.483 million in Jun 2012, 2.529 million in Jul 2012 and 2.561 million in Aug 2012. The number marginally attached to the labor force fell to 2.517 million in Sep 2012, 2.433 million in Oct 2012, 2.505 million in Nov 2012 and 2.427 million in in Dec 2013. The number marginally attached to the labor force reached 2.192 million in Oct 2014.

clip_image011

Chart I-11, US, Marginally Attached to the Labor Force, Thousands, NSA, 2001-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-12 provides 12-month percentage changes of the marginally attached to the labor force from 2001 to 2014. There was a jump of 56.1 percent in May 2009 during the global recession followed by declines in percentage changes but insufficient negative changes. On an annual basis, the number of marginally attached to the labor force increased in four consecutive years: 15.7 percent in 2008, 37.9 percent in 2009, 11.7 percent in 2010 and 3.5 percent in 2011. The number marginally attached to the labor force fell 2.2 percent on annual basis in 2012 but increased 2.9 percent in the 12 months ending in Dec 2012, fell 13.0 percent in the 12 months ending in Jan 2013, falling 10.7 percent in the 12 months ending in May 2013. The number marginally attached to the labor force increased 4.0 percent in the 12 months ending in Jun 2013 and fell 4.5 percent in the 12 months ending in Jul 2013 and 8.6 percent in the 12 months ending in Aug 2013. The annual number of marginally attached to the labor force fell 6.2 percent in 2013. The number marginally attached to the labor force fell 7.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Dec 2013 and 4.0 percent in the 12 months ending in Oct 2014.

clip_image012

Chart I-12, US, Marginally Attached to the Labor Force 12-Month Percentage Change, NSA, 2001-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/data/

Table I-4 consists of data and additional calculations using the BLS household survey, illustrating the possibility that the actual rate of unemployment could be 10.1 percent and the number of people in job stress could be around 26.6 million, which is 16.1 percent of the effective labor force. The first column provides for 2006 the yearly average population (POP), labor force (LF), participation rate or labor force as percent of population (PART %), employment (EMP), employment population ratio (EMP/POP %), unemployment (UEM), the unemployment rate as percent of labor force (UEM/LF Rate %) and the number of people not in the labor force (NLF). All data are unadjusted or not-seasonally-adjusted (NSA). The numbers in column 2006 are averages in millions while the monthly numbers for Oct 2013, Sep 2014 and Oct 2014 are in thousands, not seasonally adjusted. The average yearly participation rate of the population in the labor force was in the range of 66.0 percent minimum to 67.1 percent maximum between 2000 and 2006 with the average of 66.4 percent (ftp://ftp.bls.gov/pub/special.requests/lf/aa2006/pdf/cpsaat1.pdf). Table I-4b provides the yearly labor force participation rate from 1979 to 2014. The objective of Table I-4 is to assess how many people could have left the labor force because they do not think they can find another job. Row “LF PART 66.2 %” applies the participation rate of 2006, almost equal to the rates for 2000 to 2006, to the noninstitutional civilian population in Oct 2013, Sep 2014 and Oct 2014 to obtain what would be the labor force of the US if the participation rate had not changed. In fact, the participation rate fell to 62.9 percent by Oct 2013 and was 62.8 percent in Sep 2014 and 63.0 percent in Oct 2014, suggesting that many people simply gave up on finding another job. Row “∆ NLF UEM” calculates the number of people not counted in the labor force because they could have given up on finding another job by subtracting from the labor force with participation rate of 66.2 percent (row “LF PART 66.2%”) the labor force estimated in the household survey (row “LF”). Total unemployed (row “Total UEM”) is obtained by adding unemployed in row “∆NLF UEM” to the unemployed of the household survey in row “UEM.” The row “Total UEM%” is the effective total unemployed “Total UEM” as percent of the effective labor force in row “LF PART 66.2%.” The results are that:

  • there are an estimated 7.995 million unemployed in Oct 2014 who are not counted because they left the labor force on their belief they could not find another job (∆NLF UEM), that is, they dropped out of their job searches
  • the total number of unemployed is effectively 16.675 million (Total UEM) and not 8.680 million (UEM) of whom many have been unemployed long term
  • the rate of unemployment is 10.1 percent (Total UEM%) and not 5.5 percent, not seasonally adjusted, or 5.8 percent seasonally adjusted
  • the number of people in job stress is close to 26.6 million by adding the 7.995 million leaving the labor force because they believe they could not find another job.

The row “In Job Stress” in Table I-4 provides the number of people in job stress not seasonally adjusted at 26.554 million in Oct 2014, adding the total number of unemployed (“Total UEM”), plus those involuntarily in part-time jobs because they cannot find anything else (“Part Time Economic Reasons”) and the marginally attached to the labor force (“Marginally attached to LF”). The final row of Table I-4 shows that the number of people in job stress is equivalent to 16.1 percent of the labor force in Oct 2014. The employment population ratio “EMP/POP %” dropped from 62.9 percent on average in 2006 to 58.5 percent in Oct 2013, 59.1 percent in Sep 2014 and 59.5 percent in Oct 2014. The number employed in Oct 2014 was 147.936 million (NSA) or 0.621 million more people with jobs relative to the peak of 147.315 million in Jul 2007 while the civilian noninstitutional population of ages 16 years and over increased from 231.958 million in Jul 2007 to 248.657 million in Oct 2014 or by 16.699 million. The number employed increased 0.4 percent from Jul 2007 to Oct 2014 while the noninstitutional civilian population of ages of 16 years and over, or those available for work, increased 7.2 percent. The ratio of employment to population in Jul 2007 was 63.5 percent (147.315 million employment as percent of population of 231.958 million). The same ratio in Oct 2014 would result in 157.897 million jobs (0.635 multiplied by noninstitutional civilian population of 248.657 million). There are effectively 9.961 million fewer jobs in Oct 2014 than in Jul 2007, or 157.897 million minus 147.936 million. There is actually not sufficient job creation in merely absorbing new entrants in the labor force because of those dropping from job searches, worsening the stock of unemployed or underemployed in involuntary part-time jobs.

The argument that anemic population growth causes “secular stagnation” in the US (Hansen 1938, 1939, 1941) is as misplaced currently as in the late 1930s (for early dissent see Simons 1942). There is currently population growth in the ages of 16 to 24 years but not enough job creation and discouragement of job searches for all ages (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/10/global-financial-volatility-recovery.html). This is merely another case of theory without reality with dubious policy proposals. The number of hiring relative to the number unemployed measures the chances of becoming employed. The number of hiring in the US economy has declined by 10 million and does not show signs of increasing in an unusual recovery without hiring (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/10/global-financial-volatility-recovery.html). The US maintained growth at 3.0 percent on average over entire cycles with expansions at higher rates compensating for contractions. Growth at trend in the entire cycle from IVQ2007 to IIIQ2014 would have accumulated to 23.0 percent. GDP in IIIQ2014 would be $18,438.0 billion (in constant dollars of 2009) if the US had grown at trend, which is higher by $2,287.4 billion than actual $16,150.6 billion. There are about two trillion dollars of GDP less than at trend, explaining the 26.6 million unemployed or underemployed equivalent to actual unemployment of 16.1 percent of the effective labor force (Section I and earlier (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/10/world-financial-turbulence-twenty-seven.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/09/competitive-monetary-policy-and.html). US GDP in IIIQ2014 is 12.4 percent lower than at trend. US GDP grew from $14,991.8 billion in IVQ2007 in constant dollars to $16,150.6 billion in IIIQ2014 or 7.7 percent at the average annual equivalent rate of 1.1 percent. Cochrane (2014Jul2) estimates US GDP at more than 10 percent below trend. The US missed the opportunity to grow at higher rates during the expansion and it is difficult to catch up because growth rates in the final periods of expansions tend to decline. The US missed the opportunity for recovery of output and employment always afforded in the first four quarters of expansion from recessions. Zero interest rates and quantitative easing were not required or present in successful cyclical expansions and in secular economic growth at 3.0 percent per year and 2.0 percent per capita as measured by Lucas (2011May). There is cyclical uncommonly slow growth in the US instead of allegations of secular stagnation. There is similar behavior in manufacturing. The long-term trend is growth at average 3.3 percent per year from Jan 1919 to Sep 2014. Growth at 3.3 percent per year would raise the NSA index of manufacturing output from 99.2392 in Dec 2007 to 123.5550 in Sep 2014. The actual index NSA in Sep 2014 is 102.0228, which is 17.4 percent below trend. Manufacturing output grew at average 2.3 percent between Dec 1986 and Dec 2013, raising the index at trend to 115.7028 in Sep 2014. The output of manufacturing at 102.0228 in Sep 2014 is 11.8 percent below trend under this alternative calculation. The output of manufacturing at 101.5145 in Aug 2014 is 13.8 percent below trend under this alternative calculation.

Table I-4, US, Population, Labor Force and Unemployment, NSA

 

2006

Oct 2013

Sep 2014

Oct 2014

POP

229

246,381

248,446

248,657

LF

151

154,918

155,903

156,616

PART%

66.2

62.9

62.8

63.0

EMP

144

144,144

146,941

147,936

EMP/POP%

62.9

58.5

59.1

59.5

UEM

7

10,773

8,962

8,680

UEM/LF Rate%

4.6

7.0

5.7

5.5

NLF

77

91,463

92,543

92,041

LF PART 66.2%

 

163,104

164,471

164,611

NLF UEM

 

8,186

8,568

7,995

Total UEM

 

18,959

17,530

16,675

Total UEM%

 

11.6

10.7

10.1

Part Time Economic Reasons

 

7,700

6,711

7,687

Marginally Attached to LF

 

2,283

2,226

2,192

In Job Stress

 

28,942

26,467

26,554

People in Job Stress as % Labor Force

 

17.7

16.1

16.1

Pop: population; LF: labor force; PART: participation; EMP: employed; UEM: unemployed; NLF: not in labor force; NLF UEM: additional unemployed; Total UEM is UEM + NLF UEM; Total UEM% is Total UEM as percent of LF PART 66.2%; In Job Stress = Total UEM + Part Time Economic Reasons + Marginally Attached to LF

Note: the first column for 2006 is in average millions; the remaining columns are in thousands; NSA: not seasonally adjusted

The labor force participation rate of 66.2% in 2006 is applied to current population to obtain LF PART 66.2%; NLF UEM is obtained by subtracting the labor force with participation of 66.2 percent from the household survey labor force LF; Total UEM is household data unemployment plus NLF UEM; and total UEM% is total UEM divided by LF PART 66.2%

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/cps/

In the analysis of Hansen (1939, 3) of secular stagnation, economic progress consists of growth of real income per person driven by growth of productivity. The “constituent elements” of economic progress are “(a) inventions, (b) the discovery and development of new territory and new resources, and (c) the growth of population” (Hansen 1939, 3). Secular stagnation originates in decline of population growth and discouragement of inventions. According to Hansen (1939, 2), US population grew by 16 million in the 1920s but grew by one half or about 8 million in the 1930s with forecasts at the time of Hansen’s writing in 1938 of growth of around 5.3 million in the 1940s. Hansen (1939, 2) characterized demography in the US as “a drastic decline in the rate of population growth. Hansen’s plea was to adapt economic policy to stagnation of population in ensuring full employment. In the analysis of Hansen (1939, 8), population caused half of the growth of US GDP per year. Growth of output per person in the US and Europe was caused by “changes in techniques and to the exploitation of new natural resources.” In this analysis, population caused 60 percent of the growth of capital formation in the US. Declining population growth would reduce growth of capital formation. Residential construction provided an important share of growth of capital formation. Hansen (1939, 12) argues that market power of imperfect competition discourages innovation with prolonged use of obsolete capital equipment. Trade unions would oppose labor-savings innovations. The combination of stagnating and aging population with reduced innovation caused secular stagnation. Hansen (1939, 12) concludes that there is role for public investments to compensate for lack of dynamism of private investment but with tough tax/debt issues.

The current application of Hansen’s (1938, 1939, 1941) proposition argues that secular stagnation occurs because full employment equilibrium can be attained only with negative real interest rates between minus 2 and minus 3 percent. Professor Lawrence H. Summers (2013Nov8) finds that “a set of older ideas that went under the phrase secular stagnation are not profoundly important in understanding Japan’s experience in the 1990s and may not be without relevance to America’s experience today” (emphasis added). Summers (2013Nov8) argues there could be an explanation in “that the short-term real interest rate that was consistent with full employment had fallen to -2% or -3% sometime in the middle of the last decade. Then, even with artificial stimulus to demand coming from all this financial imprudence, you wouldn’t see any excess demand. And even with a relative resumption of normal credit conditions, you’d have a lot of difficulty getting back to full employment.” The US economy could be in a situation where negative real rates of interest with fed funds rates close to zero as determined by the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) do not move the economy to full employment or full utilization of productive resources. Summers (2013Oct8) finds need of new thinking on “how we manage an economy in which the zero nominal interest rates is a chronic and systemic inhibitor of economy activity holding our economies back to their potential.”

Former US Treasury Secretary Robert Rubin (2014Jan8) finds three major risks in prolonged unconventional monetary policy of zero interest rates and quantitative easing: (1) incentive of delaying action by political leaders; (2) “financial moral hazard” in inducing excessive exposures pursuing higher yields of risker credit classes; and (3) major risks in exiting unconventional policy. Rubin (2014Jan8) proposes reduction of deficits by structural reforms that could promote recovery by improving confidence of business attained with sound fiscal discipline.

Professor John B. Taylor (2014Jan01, 2014Jan3) provides clear thought on the lack of relevance of Hansen’s contention of secular stagnation to current economic conditions. The application of secular stagnation argues that the economy of the US has attained full-employment equilibrium since around 2000 only with negative real rates of interest of minus 2 to minus 3 percent. At low levels of inflation, the so-called full-employment equilibrium of negative interest rates of minus 2 to minus 3 percent cannot be attained and the economy stagnates. Taylor (2014Jan01) analyzes multiple contradictions with current reality in this application of the theory of secular stagnation:

  • Secular stagnation would predict idle capacity, in particular in residential investment when fed fund rates were fixed at 1 percent from Jun 2003 to Jun 2004. Taylor (2014Jan01) finds unemployment at 4.4 percent with house prices jumping 7 percent from 2002 to 2003 and 14 percent from 2004 to 2005 before dropping from 2006 to 2007. GDP prices doubled from 1.7 percent to 3.4 percent when interest rates were low from 2003 to 2005.
  • Taylor (2014Jan01, 2014Jan3) finds another contradiction in the application of secular stagnation based on low interest rates because of savings glut and lack of investment opportunities. Taylor (2009) shows that there was no savings glut. The savings rate of the US in the past decade is significantly lower than in the 1980s.
  • Taylor (2014Jan01, 2014Jan3) finds another contradiction in the low ratio of investment to GDP currently and reduced investment and hiring by US business firms.
  • Taylor (2014Jan01, 2014Jan3) argues that the financial crisis and global recession were caused by weak implementation of existing regulation and departure from rules-based policies.
  • Taylor (2014Jan01, 2014Jan3) argues that the recovery from the global recession was constrained by a change in the regime of regulation and fiscal/monetary policies.

In revealing research, Edward P. Lazear and James R. Spletzer (2012JHJul22) use the wealth of data in the valuable database and resources of the Bureau of Labor Statistics (http://www.bls.gov/data/) in providing clear thought on the nature of the current labor market of the United States. The critical issue of analysis and policy currently is whether unemployment is structural or cyclical. Structural unemployment could occur because of (1) industrial and demographic shifts and (2) mismatches of skills and job vacancies in industries and locations. Consider the aggregate unemployment rate, Y, expressed in terms of share si of a demographic group in an industry i and unemployment rate yi of that demographic group (Lazear and Spletzer 2012JHJul22, 5-6):

Y = ∑isiyi (1)

This equation can be decomposed for analysis as (Lazear and Spletzer 2012JHJul22, 6):

Y = ∑isiy*i + ∑iyis*i (2)

The first term in (2) captures changes in the demographic and industrial composition of the economy ∆si multiplied by the average rate of unemployment y*i , or structural factors. The second term in (2) captures changes in the unemployment rate specific to a group, or ∆yi, multiplied by the average share of the group s*i, or cyclical factors. There are also mismatches in skills and locations relative to available job vacancies. A simple observation by Lazear and Spletzer (2012JHJul22) casts intuitive doubt on structural factors: the rate of unemployment jumped from 4.4 percent in the spring of 2007 to 10 percent in October 2009. By nature, structural factors should be permanent or occur over relative long periods. The revealing result of the exhaustive research of Lazear and Spletzer (2012JHJul22) is:

“The analysis in this paper and in others that we review do not provide any compelling evidence that there have been changes in the structure of the labor market that are capable of explaining the pattern of persistently high unemployment rates. The evidence points to primarily cyclic factors.”

Table I-4b and Chart I-12-b provide the US labor force participation rate or percentage of the labor force in population. It is not likely that simple demographic trends caused the sharp decline during the global recession and failure to recover earlier levels. The civilian labor force participation rate dropped from the peak of 66.9 percent in Jul 2006 to 62.6 percent in Dec 2013 and 63.0 percent in Oct 2014. The civilian labor force participation rate was 63.7 percent on an annual basis in 1979 and 63.4 percent in Dec 1980 and Dec 1981, reaching even 62.9 percent in both Apr and May 1979. The civilian labor force participation rate jumped with the recovery to 64.8 percent on an annual basis in 1985 and 65.9 percent in Jul 1985. Structural factors cannot explain these sudden changes vividly shown visually in the final segment of Chart I-12b. Seniors would like to delay their retiring especially because of the adversities of financial repression on their savings. Labor force statistics are capturing the disillusion of potential workers with their chances in finding a job in what Lazear and Spletzer (2012JHJul22) characterize as accentuated cyclical factors. The argument that anemic population growth causes “secular stagnation” in the US (Hansen 1938, 1939, 1941) is as misplaced currently as in the late 1930s (for early dissent see Simons 1942). There is currently population growth in the ages of 16 to 24 years but not enough job creation and discouragement of job searches for all ages (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/10/global-financial-volatility-recovery.html). “Secular stagnation” would be a process over many years and not from one year to another. This is merely another case of theory without reality with dubious policy proposals.

Table I-4b, US, Labor Force Participation Rate, Percent of Labor Force in Population, NSA, 1979-2014

Year

Jan

Feb

Jun

Jul

Aug

Sep

Oct

Nov

Dec

Annual

1979

62.9

63.0

64.5

64.9

64.5

63.8

64.0

63.8

63.8

63.7

1980

63.3

63.2

64.6

65.1

64.5

63.6

63.9

63.7

63.4

63.8

1981

63.2

63.2

64.6

65.0

64.6

63.5

64.0

63.8

63.4

63.9

1982

63.0

63.2

64.8

65.3

64.9

64.0

64.1

64.1

63.8

64.0

1983

63.3

63.2

65.1

65.4

65.1

64.3

64.1

64.1

63.8

64.0

1984

63.3

63.4

65.5

65.9

65.2

64.4

64.6

64.4

64.3

64.4

1985

64.0

64.0

65.5

65.9

65.4

64.9

65.1

64.9

64.6

64.8

1986

64.2

64.4

66.3

66.6

66.1

65.3

65.5

65.4

65.0

65.3

1987

64.7

64.8

66.3

66.8

66.5

65.5

65.9

65.7

65.5

65.6

1988

65.1

65.2

66.7

67.1

66.8

65.9

66.1

66.2

65.9

65.9

1989

65.8

65.6

67.4

67.7

67.2

66.3

66.6

66.7

66.3

66.5

1990

66.0

66.0

67.4

67.7

67.1

66.4

66.5

66.3

66.1

66.5

1991

65.5

65.7

67.2

67.3

66.6

66.1

66.1

66.0

65.8

66.2

1992

65.7

65.8

67.6

67.9

67.2

66.3

66.2

66.2

66.1

66.4

1993

65.6

65.8

67.3

67.5

67.0

66.1

66.4

66.3

66.2

66.3

1994

66.0

66.2

67.2

67.5

67.2

66.5

66.8

66.7

66.5

66.6

1995

66.1

66.2

67.2

67.7

67.1

66.5

66.7

66.5

66.2

66.6

1996

65.8

66.1

67.4

67.9

67.2

66.8

67.1

67.0

66.7

66.8

1997

66.4

66.5

67.8

68.1

67.6

67.0

67.1

67.1

67.0

67.1

1998

66.6

66.7

67.7

67.9

67.3

67.0

67.1

67.1

67.0

67.1

1999

66.7

66.8

67.7

67.9

67.3

66.8

67.0

67.0

67.0

67.1

2000

66.8

67.0

67.7

67.6

67.2

66.7

66.9

66.9

67.0

67.1

2001

66.8

66.8

67.2

67.4

66.8

66.6

66.7

66.6

66.6

66.8

2002

66.2

66.6

67.1

67.2

66.8

66.6

66.6

66.3

66.2

66.6

2003

66.1

66.2

67.0

66.8

66.3

65.9

66.1

66.1

65.8

66.2

2004

65.7

65.7

66.5

66.8

66.2

65.7

66.0

66.1

65.8

66.0

2005

65.4

65.6

66.5

66.8

66.5

66.1

66.2

66.1

65.9

66.0

2006

65.5

65.7

66.7

66.9

66.5

66.1

66.4

66.4

66.3

66.2

2007

65.9

65.8

66.6

66.8

66.1

66.0

66.0

66.1

65.9

66.0

2008

65.7

65.5

66.6

66.8

66.4

65.9

66.1

65.8

65.7

66.0

2009

65.4

65.5

66.2

66.2

65.6

65.0

64.9

64.9

64.4

65.4

2010

64.6

64.6

65.1

65.3

65.0

64.6

64.4

64.4

64.1

64.7

2011

63.9

63.9

64.5

64.6

64.3

64.2

64.1

63.9

63.8

64.1

2012

63.4

63.6

64.3

64.3

63.7

63.6

63.8

63.5

63.4

63.7

2013

63.3

63.2

64.0

64.0

63.4

63.2

62.9

62.9

62.6

63.2

2014

62.5

62.7

63.4

63.5

63.0

62.8

63.0

     

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/cps/

clip_image013

Chart I-12b, US, Labor Force Participation Rate, Percent of Labor Force in Population, NSA, 1979-2014

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/cps/

Broader perspective is provided by Chart I-12c of the US Bureau of Labor Statistics. The United States civilian noninstitutional population has increased along a consistent trend since 1948 that continued through earlier recessions and the global recession from IVQ2007 to IIQ2009 and the cyclical expansion after IIIQ2009.

clip_image014

Chart I-12c, US, Civilian Noninstitutional Population, Thousands, NSA, 1948-2014

Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The labor force of the United States in Chart I-12d has increased along a trend similar to that of the civilian noninstitutional population in Chart I-12c. There is an evident stagnation of the civilian labor force in the final segment of Chart I-12d during the current economic cycle. This stagnation is explained by cyclical factors similar to those analyzed by Lazear and Spletzer (2012JHJul22) that motivated an increasing population to drop out of the labor force instead of structural factors. Large segments of the potential labor force are not observed, constituting unobserved unemployment and of more permanent nature because those afflicted have been seriously discouraged from working by the lack of opportunities.

clip_image015

Chart I-12d, US, Labor Force, Thousands, NSA, 1948-2014

Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The rate of labor force participation of the US is in Chart I-12E from 1948 to 2014. There is sudden decline during the global recession after 2007 without recovery explained by cyclic factors (Lazear and Spletzer 2012JHJul22) as many potential workers stopped their job searches disillusioned that there could be an opportunity for them in sharply contracted labor markets.

clip_image016

Chart I-12E, US, Labor Force Participation Rate, Percent of Labor Force in Population, NSA, 1948-2014

Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

IA3 Long-term and Cyclical Comparison of Employment. There is initial discussion here of long-term employment trends followed by cyclical comparison. Growth and employment creation have been mediocre in the expansion beginning in Jul IIIQ2009 from the contraction between Dec IVQ2007 and Jun IIQ2009 (http://www.nber.org/cycles.html). A series of charts from the database of the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) provides significant insight. Chart I-13 provides the monthly employment level of the US from 1948 to 2014. The number of people employed has trebled. There are multiple contractions throughout the more than six decades but followed by resumption of the strong upward trend. The contraction after 2007 is deeper and followed by a flatter curve of job creation. The United States missed this opportunity of high growth in the initial phase of recovery that historically eliminated unemployment and underemployment created during the contraction. Inferior performance of the US economy and labor markets is the critical current issue of analysis and policy design. Long-term economic performance in the United States consisted of trend growth of GDP at 3 percent per year and of per capita GDP at 2 percent per year as measured for 1870 to 2010 by Robert E Lucas (2011May). The economy returned to trend growth after adverse events such as wars and recessions. The key characteristic of adversities such as recessions was much higher rates of growth in expansion periods that permitted the economy to recover output, income and employment losses that occurred during the contractions. Over the business cycle, the economy compensated the losses of contractions with higher growth in expansions to maintain trend growth of GDP of 3 percent and of GDP per capita of 2 percent. The US maintained growth at 3.0 percent on average over entire cycles with expansions at higher rates compensating for contractions. US economic growth has been at only 2.3 percent on average in the cyclical expansion in the 21 quarters from IIIQ2009 to IIIQ2014. Boskin (2010Sep) measures that the US economy grew at 6.2 percent in the first four quarters and 4.5 percent in the first 12 quarters after the trough in the second quarter of 1975; and at 7.7 percent in the first four quarters and 5.8 percent in the first 12 quarters after the trough in the first quarter of 1983 (Professor Michael J. Boskin, Summer of Discontent, Wall Street Journal, Sep 2, 2010 http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052748703882304575465462926649950.html). There are new calculations using the revision of US GDP and personal income data since 1929 by the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) (http://bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm) and the first estimate of GDP for IIIQ2014 (http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/gdp/2014/pdf/gdp3q14_adv.pdf). The average of 7.7 percent in the first four quarters of major cyclical expansions is in contrast with the rate of growth in the first four quarters of the expansion from IIIQ2009 to IIQ2010 of only 2.7 percent obtained by diving GDP of $14,745.9 billion in IIQ2010 by GDP of $14,355.6 billion in IIQ2009 {[$14,745.9/$14,355.6 -1]100 = 2.7%], or accumulating the quarter on quarter growth rates (Section I and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/09/financial-volatility-mediocre-cyclical.html). The expansion from IQ1983 to IVQ1985 was at the average annual growth rate of 5.9 percent, 5.4 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1986, 5.2 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1986, 5.0 percent from IQ1983 to IQ1987, 5.0 percent from IQ1983 to IIQ1987, 4.9 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1987, 5.0 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1987, 4.9 percent from IQ1983 to IQ1988 and at 7.8 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1983 (Section I and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/09/financial-volatility-mediocre-cyclical.html). The US maintained growth at 3.0 percent on average over entire cycles with expansions at higher rates compensating for contractions. Growth at trend in the entire cycle from IVQ2007 to IIIQ2014 would have accumulated to 23.0 percent. GDP in IIIQ2014 would be $18,438.0 billion (in constant dollars of 2009) if the US had grown at trend, which is higher by $2,287.4 billion than actual $16,150.6 billion. There are about two trillion dollars of GDP less than at trend, explaining the 26.6 million unemployed or underemployed equivalent to actual unemployment of 16.1 percent of the effective labor force (Section I and earlier (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/10/world-financial-turbulence-twenty-seven.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/09/competitive-monetary-policy-and.html). US GDP in IIIQ2014 is 12.4 percent lower than at trend. US GDP grew from $14,991.8 billion in IVQ2007 in constant dollars to $16,150.6 billion in IIIQ2014 or 7.7 percent at the average annual equivalent rate of 1.1 percent. Cochrane (2014Jul2) estimates US GDP at more than 10 percent below trend. The US missed the opportunity to grow at higher rates during the expansion and it is difficult to catch up because growth rates in the final periods of expansions tend to decline. The US missed the opportunity for recovery of output and employment always afforded in the first four quarters of expansion from recessions. Zero interest rates and quantitative easing were not required or present in successful cyclical expansions and in secular economic growth at 3.0 percent per year and 2.0 percent per capita as measured by Lucas (2011May). There is cyclical uncommonly slow growth in the US instead of allegations of secular stagnation. There is similar behavior in manufacturing. The long-term trend is growth at average 3.3 percent per year from Jan 1919 to Sep 2014. Growth at 3.3 percent per year would raise the NSA index of manufacturing output from 99.2392 in Dec 2007 to 123.5550 in Sep 2014. The actual index NSA in Sep 2014 is 102.0228, which is 17.4 percent below trend. Manufacturing output grew at average 2.3 percent between Dec 1986 and Dec 2013, raising the index at trend to 115.7028 in Sep 2014. The output of manufacturing at 102.0228 in Sep 2014 is 11.8 percent below trend under this alternative calculation. The output of manufacturing at 101.5145 in Aug 2014 is 13.8 percent below trend under this alternative calculation.

clip_image017

Chart I-13, US, Employment Level, Thousands, SA, 1948-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The steep and consistent curve of growth of the US labor force is shown in Chart I-14. The contraction beginning in Dec 2007 flattened the path of the US civilian labor force and is now followed by a flatter curve during the current expansion.

clip_image018

Chart I-14, US, Civilian Labor Force, SA, 1948-2014, Thousands

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-15 for the period from 1948 to 2014. The labor force participation rate is influenced by numerous factors such as the age of the population. There is no comparable episode in the postwar economy to the sharp collapse of the labor force participation rate in Chart I-15 during the contraction and subsequent expansion after 2007. Aging can reduce the labor force participation rate as many people retire but many may have decided to work longer as their wealth and savings have been significantly reduced. There is an important effect of many people just exiting the labor force because they believe there is no job available for them.

clip_image019

Chart I-15, US, Civilian Labor Force Participation Rate, SA, 1948-2014, %

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The number of unemployed in the US jumped seasonally adjusted from 5.8 million in May 1979 to 12.1 million in Dec 1982, by 6.3 million, or 108.6 percent. The jump not seasonally adjusted was from 5.4 million in May 1979 to 12.5 million in Jan 1983, by 7.1 million or 131.5 percent. The number of unemployed seasonally adjusted jumped from 6.7 million in Mar 2007 to 15.4 million in Oct 2009, by 8.7 million, or 129.9 percent. The number of unemployed not seasonally adjusted jumped from 6.5 million in Apr 2007 to 16.1 million in Jan 2010, by 9.6 million or 147.7 percent. These are the two episodes with steepest increase in the level of unemployment in Chart I-16.

clip_image020

Chart I-16, US, Unemployed, SA, 1948-2014, Thousands

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-17 provides the rate of unemployment of the US from 1948 to 2014. The peak of the series is 10.8 percent in both Nov and Dec 1982. The second highest rates are 10.0 percent in Oct 2009 and 9.9 percent in both Nov and Dec 2009. The unadjusted rate of unemployment reached 10.6 percent in Jan 2010.

clip_image021

Chart I-17, US, Unemployment Rate, SA, 1948-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-18 provides the number unemployed for 27 weeks and over from 1948 to 2014. The number unemployed for 27 weeks and over jumped from 510,000 in Dec 1978 to 2.885 million in Jun 1983, by 2.4 million, or 465.7 percent. The number of unemployed 27 weeks or over SA jumped from 1.132 million in May 2007 to 6.604 million in Jun 2010, by 5.472 million, or 483.4 percent.

clip_image022

Chart I-18, US, Unemployed for 27 Weeks or More, SA, 1948-2014, Thousands

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The employment-population ratio in Chart I-19 is an important indicator of wellbeing in labor markets, measuring the number of people with jobs. The US employment-population ratio fell from 63.5 in Dec 2006 to 58.6 in Jul 2011 and stands at 59.5 NSA in Oct 2014. There is no comparable decline followed by stabilization during an expansion in Chart I-19.

clip_image023

Chart I-19, US, Employment-Population Ratio, 1948-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The number employed part-time for economic reasons in Chart I-20 increased in the recessions and declined during the expansions. In the current cycle, the number employed part-time for economic reasons increased sharply and has not returned to normal levels. Lower growth of economic activity in the expansion after IIIQ2009 failed to reduce the number desiring to work full time but finding only part-time occupations.

clip_image024

Chart I-20, US, Part-Time for Economic Reasons, NSA, 1955-2014, Thousands

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Table I-5 provides percentage change of real GDP in the United States in the 1930s, 1980s and 2000s. The recession in 1981-1982 is quite similar on its own to the 2007-2009 recession. In contrast, during the Great Depression in the four years of 1930 to 1933, GDP in constant dollars fell 26.4 percent cumulatively and fell 45.3 percent in current dollars (Pelaez and Pelaez, Financial Regulation after the Global Recession (2009a), 150-2, Pelaez and Pelaez, Globalization and the State, Vol. II (2009b), 205-7 and revisions in http://bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm). Data are available for the 1930s only on a yearly basis. US GDP fell 4.7 percent in the two recessions (1) from IQ1980 to IIIQ1980 and (2) from III1981 to IVQ1981 to IVQ1982 and 4.2 percent cumulatively in the recession from IVQ2007 to IIQ2009. It is instructive to compare the first three years of the expansions in the 1980s and the current expansion. GDP grew at 4.6 percent in 1983, 7.3 percent in 1984, 4.2 percent in 1985, 3.5 percent in 1986 and 3.5 percent in 1987. In contrast, GDP grew 2.5 percent in 2010, 1.6 percent in 2011, 2.3 percent in 2012 and 2.2 percent in 2013. Actual annual equivalent GDP growth in the four quarters of 2012, and seven quarters from IQ2013 to IIIQ2014 is 2.3 percent and 2.3 percent in the four quarters ending in IIIQ2014. GDP grew at 4.2 percent in 1985, 3.5 percent in 1986 and 3.5 percent in 1987 while the forecasts of the central tendency of participants of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) are in the range of 2.0 to 2.2 percent in 2014 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/fomcprojtabl20140917.pdf) with less reliable forecast of 2.6 to 3.0 percent in 2015 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/fomcprojtabl20140917.pdf ). Growth of GDP in the expansion from IIIQ2009 to IIQ2014 has been at average 2.2 percent in annual equivalent.

Table I-5, US, Percentage Change of GDP in the 1930s, 1980s and 2000s, ∆%

Year

GDP ∆%

Year

GDP ∆%

Year

GDP ∆%

1930

-8.5

1980

-0.2

2000

4.1

1931

-6.4

1981

2.6

2001

1.0

1932

-12.9

1982

-1.9

2002

1.8

1933

-1.3

1983

4.6

2003

2.8

1934

10.8

1984

7.3

2004

3.8

1935

8.9

1985

4.2

2005

3.3

1936

12.9

1986

3.5

2006

2.7

1937

5.1

1987

3.5

2007

1.8

1938

-3.3

1988

4.2

2008

-0.3

1930

8.0

1989

3.7

2009

-2.8

1940

8.8

1990

1.9

2010

2.5

1941

17.7

1991

-0.1

2011

1.6

1942

18.9

1992

3.6

2012

2.3

1943

17.0

1993

2.7

2013

2.2

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

Characteristics of the four cyclical contractions are provided in Table I-6 with the first column showing the number of quarters of contraction; the second column the cumulative percentage contraction; and the final column the average quarterly rate of contraction. There were two contractions from IQ1980 to IIIQ1980 and from IIIQ1981 to IVQ1982 separated by three quarters of expansion. The drop of output combining the declines in these two contractions is 4.7 percent, which is almost equal to the decline of 4.2 percent in the contraction from IVQ2007 to IIQ2009. In contrast, during the Great Depression in the four years of 1930 to 1933, GDP in constant dollars fell 26.4 percent cumulatively and fell 45.3 percent in current dollars (Pelaez and Pelaez, Financial Regulation after the Global Recession (2009a), 150-2, Pelaez and Pelaez, Globalization and the State, Vol. II (2009b), 205-7 and revisions in http://bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm). The comparison of the global recession after 2007 with the Great Depression is entirely misleading.

Table I-6, US, Number of Quarters, GDP Cumulative Percentage Contraction and Average Percentage Annual Equivalent Rate in Cyclical Contractions   

 

Number of Quarters

Cumulative Percentage Contraction

Average Percentage Rate

IIQ1953 to IIQ1954

3

-2.4

-0.8

IIIQ1957 to IIQ1958

3

-3.0

-1.0

IVQ1973 to IQ1975

5

-3.1

-0.6

IQ1980 to IIIQ1980

2

-2.2

-1.1

IIIQ1981 to IVQ1982

4

-2.5

-0.64

IVQ2007 to IIQ2009

6

-4.2

-0.72

Sources: Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

Table I-7 shows the mediocre average annual equivalent growth rate of 2.3 percent of the US economy in the twenty-one quarters of the current cyclical expansion from IIIQ2009 to IIIQ2014. In sharp contrast, the average growth rate of GDP was:

  • 5.7 percent in the first thirteen quarters of expansion from IQ1983 to IQ1986
  • 5.4 percent in the first fifteen quarters of expansion from IQ1983 to IIIQ1986
  • 5.2 percent in the first sixteen quarters of expansion from IQ1983 to IVQ1986
  • 5.0 percent in the first seventeen quarters of expansion from IQ1983 to IQ1987
  • 5.0 percent in the first eighteen quarters of expansion from IQ1983 to IIQ1987
  • 4.9 percent in the first nineteen quarters of expansion from IQ1983 to IIIQ1987
  • 5.0 percent in the first twenty quarters of expansion from IQ1983 to IVQ1987
  • 4.9 percent in the first twenty-first quarters of expansion from IQ1983 to IQ1988

The line “average first four quarters in four expansions” provides the average growth rate of 7.7 percent with 7.8 percent from IIIQ1954 to IIQ1955, 9.2 percent from IIIQ1958 to IIQ1959, 6.1 percent from IIIQ1975 to IIQ1976 and 7.8 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1983. The United States missed this opportunity of high growth in the initial phase of recovery. BEA data show the US economy in standstill with annual growth of 2.5 percent in 2010 decelerating to 1.6 percent annual growth in 2011, 2.3 percent in 2012 and 2.2 percent in 2013 (http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm) The expansion from IQ1983 to IQ1986 was at the average annual growth rate of 5.7 percent, 5.2 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1986, 4.9 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1987, 5.0 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1987, 4.9 percent from IQ1983 to IQ1988 and at 7.8 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1983. GDP growth in the four quarters of 2012, the four quarters of 2013 and the first three quarters of 2014 accumulated to 6.3 percent. This growth is equivalent to 2.3 percent per year, obtained by dividing GDP in IIIQ2014 of $16,150.6 billion by GDP in IVQ2011 of $15,190.3 billion and compounding by 4/11: {[($16,150.6/$15,190.3)4/11 -1]100 = 2.3 percent.

The rate of growth of GDP in the revision of the third estimate of IIIQ2013 is 4.5 percent in seasonally adjusted annual rate (SAAR). Inventory accumulation contributed 1.49 percentage points to this rate of growth. The actual rate without this impulse of unsold inventories would have been 3.0 percent, or 0.74 percent in IIIQ2013, such that annual equivalent growth in 2013 is closer to 2.8 percent {[(1.007)(1.004)(1.0074)(1.009)4/4-1]100 = 2.8%}, compounding the quarterly rates and converting into annual equivalent. Inventory divestment deducted 1.16 percentage points from GDP growth in IQ2014. Without this deduction of inventory divestment, GDP growth would have been minus 0.9 percent in IQ2014, such that the actual growth rates in the four quarters ending in IQ2014 is closer to 2.2 percent {[(1.004)(1.011)(1.009)(0.9977)]4/4 -1]100 = 2.2%}.

Table I-7, US, Number of Quarters, Cumulative Growth and Average Annual Equivalent Growth Rate in Cyclical Expansions

 

Number
of
Quarters

Cumulative Growth

∆%

Average Annual Equivalent Growth Rate

IIIQ 1954 to IQ1957

11

12.8

4.5

First Four Quarters IIIQ1954 to IIQ1955

4

7.8

 

IIQ1958 to IIQ1959

5

10.0

7.9

First Four Quarters

IIIQ1958 to IIQ1959

4

9.2

 

IIQ1975 to IVQ1976

8

8.3

4.1

First Four Quarters IIIQ1975 to IIQ1976

4

6.1

 

IQ1983-IQ1986

IQ1983-IIIQ1986

IQ1983-IVQ1986

IQ1983-IQ1987

IQ1983-IIQ1987

IQ1983 to IIIQ1987

IQ1983 to IVQ1987

IQ1983 to IQ1988

13

15

16

17

18

19

20

21

19.9

21.6

22.3

23.1

24.5

25.6

27.7

28.4

5.7

5.4

5.2

5.0

5.0

4.9

5.0

4.9

First Four Quarters IQ1983 to IVQ1983

4

7.8

 

Average First Four Quarters in Four Expansions*

 

7.7

 

IIIQ2009 to IIIQ2014

21

12.5

2.3

First Four Quarters IIIQ2009 to IIQ2010

 

2.7

 

*First Four Quarters: 7.8% IIIQ1954-IIQ1955; 9.2% IIIQ1958-IIQ1959; 6.1% IIIQ1975-IQ1976; 7.8% IQ1983-IVQ1983

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

A group of charts from the database of the Bureau of Labor Statistics facilitates the comparison of employment in the 1980s and 2000s. The long-term charts and tables from I-5 to I-7 in the discussion above confirm the view that the comparison of the current expansion should be with that in the 1980s because of similar dimensions. Chart I-21 provides the level of employment in the US between 1979 and 1989. Employment surged after the contraction and grew rapidly during the decade.

clip_image025

Chart I-21, US, Employed, Thousands, 1979-1989

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-22 provides the level of employment in the US from 2001 to 2014. There is actually not sufficient job creation in merely absorbing new entrants in the labor force because of those dropping from job searches, worsening the stock of unemployed or underemployed in involuntary part-time jobs. Recovery has been anemic compared with the shallow recession of 2001 that was followed by nearly vertical growth in jobs. The number employed in Oct 2014 was 147.936 million (NSA) or 0.621 million more people with jobs relative to the peak of 147.315 million in Jul 2007 while the civilian noninstitutional population of ages 16 years and over increased from 231.958 million in Jul 2007 to 248.657 million in Oct 2014 or by 16.699 million. The number employed increased 0.4 percent from Jul 2007 to Oct 2014 while the noninstitutional civilian population of ages of 16 years and over, or those available for work, increased 7.2 percent. The ratio of employment to population in Jul 2007 was 63.5 percent (147.315 million employment as percent of population of 231.958 million). The same ratio in Oct 2014 would result in 157.897 million jobs (0.635 multiplied by noninstitutional civilian population of 248.657 million). There are effectively 9.961 million fewer jobs in Oct 2014 than in Jul 2007, or 157.897 million minus 147.936 million. There is actually not sufficient job creation in merely absorbing new entrants in the labor force because of those dropping from job searches, worsening the stock of unemployed or underemployed in involuntary part-time jobs.

clip_image001[1]

Chart I-22, US, Employed, Thousands, 2001-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

There was a steady upward trend in growth of the civilian labor force between 1979 and 1989 as shown in Chart I-23. There were fluctuations but strong long-term dynamism over an entire decade.

clip_image026

Chart I-23, US, Civilian Labor Force, Thousands, 1979-1989

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The civilian labor force in Chart I-24 grew steadily on an upward trend in the 2000s until it contracted together with the economy after 2007. There has not been recovery during the expansion but rather decline and marginal turn of the year 2011 into expansion in 2012 followed by stability and oscillation into 2013-2014. The civilian labor force consists of people who are available and willing to work and who have searched for employment recently. The labor force of the US grew 9.4 percent from 142.828 million in Jan 2001 to 156.255 million in Jul 2009 but is only 0.1 percent higher at 156.434 million in Aug 2014, all numbers not seasonally adjusted. Chart I-24 shows the flattening of the curve of expansion of the labor force and its decline in 2010 and 2011. The ratio of the labor force of 154.871 million in Jul 2007 to the noninstitutional population of 231.958 million in Jul 2007 was 66.8 percent while the ratio of the labor force of 156.616 million in Oct 2014 to the noninstitutional population of 248.657 million in Oct 2014 was 63.0 percent. The labor force of the US in Oct 2014 corresponding to 66.8 percent of participation in the population would be 166.103 million (0.668 x 248.657). The difference between the measured labor force in Oct 2014 of 156.616 million and the labor force in Oct 2014 with participation rate of 66.8 percent (as in Jul 2007) of 166.103 million is 9.487 million. The level of the labor force in the US has stagnated and is 9.487 million lower than what it would have been had the same participation rate been maintained. Millions of people have abandoned their search for employment because they believe there are no jobs available for them. The key issue is whether the decline in participation of the population in the labor force is the result of people giving up on finding another job.

clip_image003[1]

Chart I-24, US, Civilian Labor Force, Thousands, 2001-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The rate of participation of the labor force in population stagnated during the stagflation and conquest of inflation in the late 1970s and early 1980s, as shown in Chart I-25. Recovery was vigorous during the expansion and lasted through the remainder of the decade.

clip_image027

Chart I-25, US, Civilian Labor Force Participation Rate, 1979-1989, %

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The rate of participation in the labor force declined after the recession of 2001 and stagnated until 2007, as shown in Chart I-26. The rate of participation in the labor force continued to decline both during the contraction after 2007 and the expansion after 2009 with marginal expansion at the turn of the year into 2012 followed by trend of decline and stability.

clip_image005[1]

Chart I-26, US, Civilian Labor Force Participation Rate, 2001-2014, %

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-27 provides the number unemployed during the 1980s. The number unemployed peaked at 12.051 million in Dec 1982 seasonally adjusted and 12.517 in Jan 1983 million not seasonally adjusted, declining to 8.358 million in Dec 1984 seasonally adjusted and 7.978 in Dec 1984 million not seasonally adjusted during the first two years of expansion from the contraction. The number unemployed then fell to 6.667 million in Dec 1989 seasonally adjusted and 6.300 million not seasonally adjusted.

clip_image028

Chart I-27, US, Unemployed Thousands 1979-1989

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-28 provides the number unemployed from 2001 to 2014. Using seasonally adjusted data, the number unemployed rose from 6.727 million in Oct 2006 to 15.352 million in Oct 2009, declining to 13.090 million in Dec 2011 and to 8.995 million in Oct 2014. Using data not seasonally adjusted, the number unemployed rose from 6.272 million in Oct 2006 to 16.147 million in Jan 2010, declining to 11.844 million in Dec 2012, increasing to 13.181 million in Jan 20013 and declining to 9.984 million in Dec 2013. The level of unemployment was 8.680 million in Oct 2014.

clip_image006[1]

Chart I-28, US, Unemployed Thousands 2001-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The rate of unemployment peaked at 10.8 percent in both Nov and Dec 1982 seasonally adjusted, as shown in Chart I-29. The rate of unemployment dropped sharply during the expansion after 1984 and continued to decline during the rest of the decade to 5.4 percent in Dec 1989. Using not seasonally adjusted data, the rate of unemployment peaked at 11.4 percent in Jan 1983, declining to 7.0 percent in Dec 1984 and 5.1 percent in Dec 1989.

clip_image029

Chart I-29, US, Unemployment Rate, 1979-1989, %

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The rate of unemployment in the US seasonally adjusted jumped from 4.4 percent in May 2007 to 10.0 percent in Oct 2009 and 9.9 percent in both Nov and Dec 2009, as shown in Chart I-30. The rate of unemployment fluctuated at around 9.0 percent in 2011, declining to 7.9 percent in Dec 2012 and 6.7 percent in Dec 2013. The rate of unemployed eased to 5.8 percent in Oct 2014.

clip_image007[1]

Chart I-30, US, Unemployment Rate, 2001-2014, %

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The employment population ratio seasonally adjusted fell from around 60.1 in Dec 1979 to 57.1 in both Feb and Mar 1983, as shown in Chart I-31. The employment population ratio seasonally adjusted rose back to 59.9 in Dec 1984 and reached 63.0 later in the decade in Dec 1989. Using not seasonally adjusted data, the employment population ratio dropped from 60.4 percent in Oct 1979 to 56.1 percent in Jan 1983, increasing to 59.8 in Dec 1984 and to 62.9 percent in Dec 1989.

clip_image030

Chart I-31, US, Employment Population Ratio, 1979-1989, %

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The US employment-population ratio seasonally adjusted has fallen from 63.4 in Dec 2006 to 58.5 in Dec 2011, 58.6 in Dec 2012 and 58.6 in Dec 2013, as shown in Chart I-32. The employment-population ratio reached 59.2 in Oct 2014. The employment population-ratio has stagnated during the expansion. Using not seasonally adjusted data, the employment population ratio fell from 63.6 percent in Jul 2006 to 57.6 percent in Jan 2011, 58.5 percent in Dec 2012 and 58.5 percent in Dec 2013. The employment population ratio eased to 59.5 in Oct 2014.

clip_image031

Chart I-32, US, Employment Population Ratio, 2001-2014, %

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The number unemployed 27 weeks or more rose in Chart I-33 rose from 492,000 NSA in Oct 1979 to 2.978 million in Mar 1983. The level unemployed 27 weeks or more NSA fell to 566,000 in Aug 1989.

clip_image032

Chart I-33, US, Number Unemployed for 27 Weeks or More 1979-1989, SA, Thousands

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The number unemployed for 27 weeks or over, seasonally adjusted, increased sharply during the contraction as shown in Chart I-34 from 1.131 million in Nov 2006 to 6.770 million in Apr 2010 seasonally adjusted. The number of unemployed for 27 weeks remained at around 6 million during the expansion compared with somewhat above 1 million before the contraction, falling to 2.916 million in Oct 2014 seasonally adjusted and 2.838 million not seasonally adjusted.

clip_image033

Chart I-34, US, Number Unemployed for 27 Weeks or More, 2001-2014, SA, Thousands

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The number of persons working part-time for economic reasons because they cannot find full-time work peaked during the contraction at 6.857 million SA in Oct 1982, as shown in Chart I-35. The number of persons at work part-time for economic reasons fell sharply during the expansion to 5.797 million in Dec 1984 and continued to fall throughout the decade to 4.817 million in Dec 1989 SA and 4.709 million NSA.

clip_image034

Chart I-35, US, Part-Time for Economic Reasons, 1979-1989, Thousands

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The number of people working part-time because they cannot find full-time employment, not seasonally adjusted, increased sharply during the contraction from 3.787 million in Apr 2006, not seasonally adjusted, to 9.354 million in Dec 2009, as shown in Chart I-36. The number of people working part-time because of failure to find an alternative occupation stagnated at a very high level during the expansion, declining to 7.687 million not seasonally adjusted in Oct 2014.

clip_image009[1]

Chart I-36, US, Part-Time for Economic Reasons, 2001-2014, Thousands

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

The number marginally attached to the labor force in Chart I-37 jumped from 1.252 million in Dec 2006 to 2.800 million in Jan 2011, remaining at a high level of 2.540 million in Dec 2011, 2.809 million in Jan 2012 and 2.614 million in Dec 2012. The number marginally attached to the labor force eased to 2.427 million in Dec 2013 and 2.192 million in Oct 2014.

clip_image011[1]

Chart I-37, US, Marginally Attached to the Labor Force, 2001-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

IA4 Job Creation. What is striking about the data in Table I-8 is that the numbers of monthly increases in jobs in 1983 and 1984 are several times higher than in 2010 to 2013. The civilian noninstitutional population grew by 41.0 percent from 174.215 million in 1983 to 245.679 million in 2013 and labor force higher by 39.3 percent, growing from 111.550 million in 1983 to 155.389 million in 2013. Total nonfarm payroll employment seasonally adjusted (SA) increased 214,000 in Oct 2014 and private payroll employment increased 209,000. The average monthly number of nonfarm jobs created from Oct 2012 to Oct 2013 was 199,167 using seasonally adjusted data, while the average number of nonfarm jobs created from Oct 2013 to Oct 2014 was 220,250, or increase by 10.6 percent. The average number of private jobs created in the US from Oct 2012 to Oct 2013 was 202,750, using seasonally adjusted data, while the average from Oct 2013 to Oct 2014 was 215,250, or increase by 6.2 percent. This blog calculates the effective labor force of the US at 163.104 million in Oct 2013 and 164.611 million in Oct 2014 (Table I-4), for growth of 1.507 million at average 125,583 per month. The difference between the average increase of 215,250 new private nonfarm jobs per month in the US from Oct 2013 to Oct 2014 and the 125,583 average monthly increase in the labor force from Oct 2013 to Oct 2014 is 89,667 monthly new jobs net of absorption of new entrants in the labor force. There are 26.554 million in job stress in the US currently. Creation of 89,667 new jobs per month net of absorption of new entrants in the labor force would require 296 months to provide jobs for the unemployed and underemployed (26.554 million divided by 89,667) or 25 years (294 divided by 12). The civilian labor force of the US in Oct 2014 not seasonally adjusted stood at 156.616 million with 8.680 million unemployed or effectively 16.675 million unemployed in this blog’s calculation by inferring those who are not searching because they believe there is no job for them for effective labor force of 164.611 million. Reduction of one million unemployed at the current rate of job creation without adding more unemployment requires 0.9 years (1 million divided by product of 89,667 by 12, which is 1,076,000). Reduction of the rate of unemployment to 5 percent of the labor force would be equivalent to unemployment of only 7.831 million (0.05 times labor force of 156.616 million). New net job creation would be 0.849 million (8.680 million unemployed minus 7.831 million unemployed at rate of 5 percent) that at the current rate would take 0.8 years (0.849 million divided by 1.076). Under the calculation in this blog, there are 16.675 million unemployed by including those who ceased searching because they believe there is no job for them and effective labor force of 164.611 million. Reduction of the rate of unemployment to 5 percent of the labor force would require creating 9.464 million jobs net of labor force growth that at the current rate would take 7.8 years (16.675 million minus 0.05(164.611 million) = 8.444 million divided by 1.076, using LF PART 66.2% and Total UEM in Table I-4). These calculations assume that there are no more recessions, defying United States economic history with periodic contractions of economic activity when unemployment increases sharply. The number employed in Oct 2014 was 147.936 million (NSA) or 0.621 million more people with jobs relative to the peak of 147.315 million in Jul 2007 while the civilian noninstitutional population of ages 16 years and over increased from 231.958 million in Jul 2007 to 248.657 million in Oct 2014 or by 16.699 million. The number employed increased 0.4 percent from Jul 2007 to Oct 2014 while the noninstitutional civilian population of ages of 16 years and over, or those available for work, increased 7.2 percent. The ratio of employment to population in Jul 2007 was 63.5 percent (147.315 million employment as percent of population of 231.958 million). The same ratio in Oct 2014 would result in 157.897 million jobs (0.635 multiplied by noninstitutional civilian population of 248.657 million). There are effectively 9.961 million fewer jobs in Oct 2014 than in Jul 2007, or 157.897 million minus 147.936 million. There is actually not sufficient job creation in merely absorbing new entrants in the labor force because of those dropping from job searches, worsening the stock of unemployed or underemployed in involuntary part-time jobs.

There is current interest in past theories of “secular stagnation.” Alvin H. Hansen (1939, 4, 7; see Hansen 1938, 1941; for an early critique see Simons 1942) argues:

“Not until the problem of full employment of our productive resources from the long-run, secular standpoint was upon us, were we compelled to give serious consideration to those factors and forces in our economy which tend to make business recoveries weak and anaemic (sic) and which tend to prolong and deepen the course of depressions. This is the essence of secular stagnation-sick recoveries which die in their infancy and depressions which feed on them-selves and leave a hard and seemingly immovable core of unemployment. Now the rate of population growth must necessarily play an important role in determining the character of the output; in other words, the com-position of the flow of final goods. Thus a rapidly growing population will demand a much larger per capita volume of new residential building construction than will a stationary population. A stationary population with its larger proportion of old people may perhaps demand more personal services; and the composition of consumer demand will have an important influence on the quantity of capital required. The demand for housing calls for large capital outlays, while the demand for personal services can be met without making large investment expenditures. It is therefore not unlikely that a shift from a rapidly growing population to a stationary or declining one may so alter the composition of the final flow of consumption goods that the ratio of capital to output as a whole will tend to decline.”

The argument that anemic population growth causes “secular stagnation” in the US (Hansen 1938, 1939, 1941) is as misplaced currently as in the late 1930s (for early dissent see Simons 1942). There is currently population growth in the ages of 16 to 24 years but not enough job creation and discouragement of job searches for all ages (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/10/global-financial-volatility-recovery.html). The proper explanation is not in secular stagnation but in cyclically slow growth. The US maintained growth at 3.0 percent on average over entire cycles with expansions at higher rates compensating for contractions. Growth at trend in the entire cycle from IVQ2007 to IIIQ2014 would have accumulated to 23.0 percent. GDP in IIIQ2014 would be $18,438.0 billion (in constant dollars of 2009) if the US had grown at trend, which is higher by $2,287.4 billion than actual $16,150.6 billion. There are about two trillion dollars of GDP less than at trend, explaining the 26.6 million unemployed or underemployed equivalent to actual unemployment of 16.1 percent of the effective labor force (Section I and earlier (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/10/world-financial-turbulence-twenty-seven.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/09/competitive-monetary-policy-and.html). US GDP in IIIQ2014 is 12.4 percent lower than at trend. US GDP grew from $14,991.8 billion in IVQ2007 in constant dollars to $16,150.6 billion in IIIQ2014 or 7.7 percent at the average annual equivalent rate of 1.1 percent. Cochrane (2014Jul2) estimates US GDP at more than 10 percent below trend. The US missed the opportunity to grow at higher rates during the expansion and it is difficult to catch up because growth rates in the final periods of expansions tend to decline. The US missed the opportunity for recovery of output and employment always afforded in the first four quarters of expansion from recessions. Zero interest rates and quantitative easing were not required or present in successful cyclical expansions and in secular economic growth at 3.0 percent per year and 2.0 percent per capita as measured by Lucas (2011May). There is cyclical uncommonly slow growth in the US instead of allegations of secular stagnation. There is similar behavior in manufacturing. The long-term trend is growth at average 3.3 percent per year from Jan 1919 to Sep 2014. Growth at 3.3 percent per year would raise the NSA index of manufacturing output from 99.2392 in Dec 2007 to 123.5550 in Sep 2014. The actual index NSA in Sep 2014 is 102.0228, which is 17.4 percent below trend. Manufacturing output grew at average 2.3 percent between Dec 1986 and Dec 2013, raising the index at trend to 115.7028 in Sep 2014. The output of manufacturing at 102.0228 in Sep 2014 is 11.8 percent below trend under this alternative calculation. The output of manufacturing at 101.5145 in Aug 2014 is 13.8 percent below trend under this alternative calculation.

Table I-8, US, Monthly Change in Jobs, Number SA

Month

1981

1982

1983

2008

2009

2010

Private

Jan

94

-326

224

15

-798

18

20

Feb

68

-5

-75

-86

-701

-50

-38

Mar

105

-130

172

-80

-826

156

113

Apr

73

-280

276

-214

-684

251

192

May

10

-45

277

-182

-354

516

94

Jun

197

-243

379

-172

-467

-122

110

Jul

112

-342

418

-210

-327

-61

120

Aug

-36

-158

-308

-259

-216

-42

117

Sep

-87

-181

1115

-452

-227

-57

107

Oct

-99

-277

271

-474

-198

241

199

Nov

-209

-123

353

-765

-6

137

149

Dec

-278

-14

356

-697

-283

71

94

     

1984

   

2011

Private

Jan

   

446

   

70

72

Feb

   

481

   

168

223

Mar

   

275

   

212

231

Apr

   

363

   

322

320

May

   

308

   

102

166

Jun

   

379

   

217

186

Jul

   

313

   

106

219

Aug

   

242

   

122

125

Sep

   

310

   

221

268

Oct

   

286

   

183

177

Nov

   

349

   

164

191

Dec

   

128

   

196

222

     

1985

   

2012

Private

Jan

   

266

   

360

364

Feb

   

124

   

226

228

Mar

   

346

   

243

246

Apr

   

196

   

96

102

May

   

274

   

110

131

Jun

   

146

   

88

75

Jul

   

190

   

160

172

Aug

   

193

   

150

136

Sep

   

203

   

161

159

Oct

   

188

   

225

255

Nov

   

209

   

203

211

Dec

   

167

   

214

215

     

1986

   

2013

Private

Jan

   

125

   

197

219

Feb

   

107

   

280

263

Mar

   

94

   

141

164

Apr

   

187

   

203

188

May

   

127

   

199

222

Jun

   

-94

   

201

201

Jul

   

318

   

149

170

Aug

   

114

   

202

180

Sep

   

347

   

164

153

Oct

   

186

   

237

247

Nov

   

186

   

274

272

Dec

   

205

   

84

86

     

1987

   

2014

Private

Jan

   

172

   

144

166

Feb

   

232

   

222

201

Mar

   

249

   

203

200

Apr

   

338

   

304

278

May

   

226

   

229

228

Jun

   

172

   

267

260

Jul

   

347

   

243

239

Aug

   

171

   

203

200

Sep

   

228

   

256

244

Oct

   

492

   

214

209

Nov

   

232

       

Dec

   

294

       

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/

Charts numbered from I-38 to I-41 from the database of the Bureau of Labor Statistics provide a comparison of payroll survey data for the contractions and expansions in the 1980s and after 2007. Chart I-38 provides total nonfarm payroll jobs from 2001 to 2013. The sharp decline in total nonfarm jobs during the contraction after 2007 has been followed by initial stagnation and then inadequate growth in 2012 and 2013-2014 while population growth continued.

clip_image035

Chart I-38, US, Total Nonfarm Payroll Jobs SA 2001-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Chart I-39 provides total nonfarm jobs SA from 1979 to 1989. Recovery is strong throughout the decade with the economy growing at trend over the entire economic cycle.

clip_image036

Chart I-39, US, Total Nonfarm Payroll Jobs SA 1979-1989

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Most job creation in the US is by the private sector. Chart I-40 shows the sharp destruction of private payroll jobs during the contraction after 2007. There has been growth after 2010 but insufficient to recover higher levels of employment prevailing before the contraction. At current rates, recovery of employment may spread over several years in contrast with past expansions of the business cycle in the US.

clip_image037

Chart I-40, US, Total Private Payroll Jobs SA 2001-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

In contrast, growth of private payroll jobs in the US recovered vigorously during the expansion in 1983 through 1985, as shown in Chart I-41. Rapid growth of creation of private jobs continued throughout the 1980s.

clip_image038

Chart I-41, US, Total Private Payroll Jobs SA 1979-1989

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Types of jobs created, and not only the pace of job creation, may be important. Aspects of growth of payroll jobs from Oct 2013 to Oct 2014, not seasonally adjusted (NSA), are in Table I-9. Total nonfarm employment increased by 2,804,000 (row A, column Change), consisting of growth of total private employment by 2,720,000 (row B, column Change) and increase by 84,000 of government employment (row C, column Change). Monthly average growth of private payroll employment has been 226,667, which is mediocre relative to 24 to 30 million in job stress, while total nonfarm employment has grown on average by only 233,667 per month, which barely keeps with 125,583 new entrants per month in the labor force. These monthly rates of job creation are insufficient to meet the demands of new entrants in the labor force and thus perpetuate unemployment and underemployment. Manufacturing employment increased by 172,000, at the monthly rate of 14,333 while private service providing employment grew by 2,258,000, at the monthly rate of 188,167. An important feature in Table I-9 is that jobs in professional and business services increased by 673,000 with temporary help services increasing by 235,000. This episode of jobless recovery is characterized by part-time jobs and creation of jobs that are inferior to those that have been lost. Monetary and fiscal stimuli fail to increase consumption in a fractured job market. The segment leisure and hospitality added 394,000 jobs in 12 months. An important characteristic is that the loss of government jobs has stabilized in federal government with loss of 14,000 jobs while states added 15,000 jobs and local government added 83,000 jobs. Local government provides the bulk of government jobs, 14.355 million, while federal government provides 2.715 million and states government 5.229 million.

Table I-9, US, Employees in Nonfarm Payrolls Not Seasonally Adjusted, in Thousands

 

Oct 2013

Oct 2014

Change

A Total Nonfarm

138,013

140,817

2,804

B Total Private

115,798

118,518

2,720

B1 Goods Producing

19,029

19,491

462

B1a

Manufacturing

12,055

12,227

172

B2 Private service providing

96,769

99,027

2,258

B2a Wholesale Trade

5,782

5,907

125

B2b Retail Trade

15,203

15,482

279

B2c Transportation & Warehousing

4,548

4,706

158

B2d Financial Activities

7,905

7,999

94

B2e Professional and Business Services

18,918

19,591

673

B2e1 Temporary help services

2,818

3,053

235

B2f Health Care & Social Assistance

17,881

18,250

369

B2g Leisure & Hospitality

14,324

14,718

394

C Government

22,215

22,299

84

C1 Federal

2,729

2,715

-14

C2 State

5,214

5,229

15

C3 Local

14,272

14,355

83

Note: A = B+C, B = B1 + B2, C=C1 + C2 + C3

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/

Greater detail on the types of jobs created is provided in Table I-10 with data for Sep 2014 and Oct 2014. Strong seasonal effects are shown by the significant difference between seasonally adjusted (SA) and not-seasonally-adjusted (NSA) data. The purpose of adjusting for seasonality is to isolate nonseasonal effects. The 214,000 SA total nonfarm jobs created in Oct 2014 relative to Sep 2014 actually correspond to increase of 1,064,000 jobs NSA, as shown in row A. Most of this difference in Jan 2014 is due to the necessary benchmark and seasonal adjustments in the beginning of every year. The 209,000 total private payroll jobs SA created in Oct 2014 relative to Sep 2014 actually correspond to increase of 567,000 jobs NSA. The analysis of NSA job creation in the prior Table I-9 does show improvement over the 12 months ending in Oct 2014 that is not clouded by seasonal variations but is inadequate number of jobs created. In fact, the 12-month rate of job creation without seasonal adjustment is stronger indication of marginal improvement in the US job market but that is insufficient in even making a dent in about 30 million people unemployed or underemployed. Benchmark and seasonal adjustments affect comparability of data over time.

Table I-10, US, Employees on Nonfarm Payrolls and Selected Industry Detail, Thousands, SA and NSA

 

Sep  2014 SA

Oct      2014 SA

Sep   2014 NSA

Oct    2014 NSA

A Total Nonfarm

139,466

139,680

214

139,753

140,817

1064

B Total Private

117,557

117,766

209

117,951

118,518

567

B1 Goods Producing

19,176

19,204

28

19,491

19,491

0

B1a Constr.

6,083

6,095

12

6,320

6,328

8

B Mfg

12,166

12,181

15

12,232

12,227

-5

B2 Private Service Providing

98,381

98,562

181

98,460

99,027

567

B2a Wholesale Trade

5,886

5,895

9

5,890

5,907

17

B2b Retail Trade

15,409

15,436

27

15,301

15,482

181

B2c Couriers     & Mess.

577

581

4

561

572

11

B2d Health-care & Social Assistance

18,170

18,197

27

18,146

18,250

104

B2De Profess. & Business Services

19,373

19,410

37

19,453

19,591

138

B2De1 Temp Help Services

2,928

2,943

15

3,005

3,053

48

B2f Leisure & Hospit.

14,708

14,760

52

14,880

14,718

-162

Notes: ∆: Absolute Change; Constr.: Construction; Mess.: Messengers; Temp: Temporary; Hospit.: Hospitality. SA aggregates do not add because of seasonal adjustment.

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/

Chart I-42 of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System shows that output of durable manufacturing accelerated in the 1980s and 1990s with slower growth in the 2000s perhaps because processes matured. Growth was robust after the major drop during the global recession but appears to vacillate in the final segment.

clip_image039

Chart I-42, US, Output of Durable Manufacturing, 1972-2014

Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve

http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/g17/Current/default.htm

Manufacturing jobs not seasonally adjusted increased 172,000 from Oct 2013 to
Oct 2014 or at the average monthly rate of 14,333. There are effects of the weaker economy and international trade together with the yearly adjustment of labor statistics. Industrial production increased 1.0 percent in Sep 2014 and decreased 0.2 percent in Aug 2014 after increasing 0.2 percent in Jul 2014, as shown in Table I-1, with all data seasonally adjusted. The Federal Reserve completed its annual revision of industrial production and capacity utilization on Mar 28, 2014 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/g17/revisions/Current/DefaultRev.htm). The report of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System states (http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/g17/Current/default.htm):

“Industrial production increased 1.0 percent in September and advanced at an annual rate of 3.2 percent in the third quarter of 2014, roughly its average quarterly increase since the end of 2010. In September, manufacturing output moved up 0.5 percent, while the indexes for mining and for utilities climbed 1.8 percent and 3.9 percent, respectively. For the third quarter as a whole, manufacturing production rose at an annual rate of 3.5 percent and mining output increased at an annual rate of 8.7 percent. The output of utilities fell at an annual rate of 8.5 percent for a second consecutive quarterly decline. At 105.1 percent of its 2007 average, total industrial production in September was 4.3 percent above its level of a year earlier. The capacity utilization rate for total industry moved up 0.6 percentage point in September to 79.3 percent, a rate that is 1.0 percentage point above its level of 12 months earlier but 0.8 percentage point below its long-run (1972–2013) average.”

In the six months ending in Sep 2014, United States national industrial production accumulated increase of 1.9 percent at the annual equivalent rate of 3.9 percent, which is lower than growth of 4.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Sep 2014. Excluding growth of 1.0 percent in Sep 2014, growth in the remaining five months from Apr to Aug 2014 accumulated to 0.9 percent or 2.2 percent annual equivalent. Industrial production declined in one of the past six months. Industrial production expanded at annual equivalent 4.1 percent in the most recent quarter from Jul to Sep 2014 and at 3.7 percent in the prior quarter Apr-Jun 2014. Business equipment accumulated growth of 2.2 percent in the six months from Apr to Sep 2014 at the annual equivalent rate of 4.5 percent, which is close growth of 4.6 percent in the 12 months ending in Sep 2014. The Fed analyzes capacity utilization of total industry in its report (http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/g17/Current/default.htm): “The capacity utilization rate for total industry moved up 0.6 percentage point in September to 79.3 percent, a rate that is 1.0 percentage point above its level of 12 months earlier but 0.8 percentage point below its long-run (1972–2013) average.” United States industry apparently decelerated to a lower growth rate with possible acceleration in past months.

Manufacturing decreased by 21.9 from the peak in Jun 2007 to the trough in Apr 2009 and increased by 19.9 percent from the trough in Apr 2009 to Dec 2013. Manufacturing grew 26.8 percent from the trough in Apr 2009 to Sep 2014. Manufacturing output in Sep 2014 is 1.0 percent below the peak in Jun 2007. Growth at trend in the entire cycle from IVQ2007 to IIIQ2014 would have accumulated to 23.0 percent. GDP in IIIQ2014 would be $18,438.0 billion (in constant dollars of 2009) if the US had grown at trend, which is higher by $2,287.4 billion than actual $16,150.6 billion. There are about two trillion dollars of GDP less than at trend, explaining the 26.6 million unemployed or underemployed equivalent to actual unemployment of 16.1 percent of the effective labor force (Section I and earlier (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/10/world-financial-turbulence-twenty-seven.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/09/competitive-monetary-policy-and.html). US GDP in IIIQ2014 is 12.4 percent lower than at trend. US GDP grew from $14,991.8 billion in IVQ2007 in constant dollars to $16,150.6 billion in IIIQ2014 or 7.7 percent at the average annual equivalent rate of 1.1 percent. Cochrane (2014Jul2) estimates US GDP at more than 10 percent below trend. The US missed the opportunity to grow at higher rates during the expansion and it is difficult to catch up because growth rates in the final periods of expansions tend to decline. The US missed the opportunity for recovery of output and employment always afforded in the first four quarters of expansion from recessions. Zero interest rates and quantitative easing were not required or present in successful cyclical expansions and in secular economic growth at 3.0 percent per year and 2.0 percent per capita as measured by Lucas (2011May). There is cyclical uncommonly slow growth in the US instead of allegations of secular stagnation. There is similar behavior in manufacturing. The long-term trend is growth at average 3.3 percent per year from Jan 1919 to Sep 2014. Growth at 3.3 percent per year would raise the NSA index of manufacturing output from 99.2392 in Dec 2007 to 123.5550 in Sep 2014. The actual index NSA in Sep 2014 is 102.0228, which is 17.4 percent below trend. Manufacturing output grew at average 2.3 percent between Dec 1986 and Dec 2013, raising the index at trend to 115.7028 in Sep 2014. The output of manufacturing at 102.0228 in Sep 2014 is 11.8 percent below trend under this alternative calculation.

Table I-13 provides national income by industry without capital consumption adjustment (WCCA). “Private industries” or economic activities have share of 87.3 percent in IIQ2014. Most of US national income is in the form of services. In Oct 2014, there were 140.817 million nonfarm jobs NSA in the US, according to estimates of the establishment survey of the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) (http://www.bls.gov/news.release/empsit.nr0.htm Table B-1). Total private jobs of 118.518 million NSA in Oct 2014 accounted for 84.2 percent of total nonfarm jobs of 140.817 million, of which 12.227 million, or 10.3 percent of total private jobs and 8.7 percent of total nonfarm jobs, were in manufacturing. Private service-producing jobs were 99.027 million NSA in Oct 2014, or 70.3 percent of total nonfarm jobs and 83.6 percent of total private-sector jobs. Manufacturing has share of 11.3 percent in US national income in IIQ2014 and durable goods 6.4 percent, as shown in Table I-13. Most income in the US originates in services. Subsidies and similar measures designed to increase manufacturing jobs will not increase economic growth and employment and may actually reduce growth by diverting resources away from currently employment-creating activities because of the drain of taxation.

Table I-13, US, National Income without Capital Consumption Adjustment by Industry, Seasonally Adjusted Annual Rates, Billions of Dollars, % of Total

 

SAAR IQ2014

% Total

SAAR
IIQ2014

% Total

National Income WCCA

14,982.0

100.0

15,276.2

100.0

Domestic Industries

14,771.0

98.6

15,062.8

98.6

Private Industries

13,055.8

87.1

13,342.0

87.3

    Agriculture

161.0

1.1

178.6

1.2

    Mining

273.1

1.8

260.5

1.7

    Utilities

209.1

1.4

215.7

1.4

    Construction

660.3

4.4

666.8

4.4

    Manufacturing

1642.5

11.0

1721.4

11.3

       Durable Goods

950.2

6.3

982.0

6.4

       Nondurable Goods

692.3

4.6

739.3

4.8

    Wholesale Trade

908.7

6.1

925.1

6.1

     Retail Trade

1029.8

6.9

1051.9

6.9

     Transportation & WH

465.6

3.1

478.0

3.1

     Information

560.5

3.7

578.0

3.8

     Finance, Insurance, RE

2638.0

17.6

2661.9

17.4

     Professional & Business Services

2026.8

13.5

2086.1

13.7

     Education, Health Care

1461.8

9.8

1487.5

9.7

     Arts, Entertainment

593.9

4.0

605.2

4.0

     Other Services

424.7

2.8

425.4

2.8

Government

1715.1

11.4

1720.8

11.3

Rest of the World

211.0

1.4

213.5

1.4

Notes: SSAR: Seasonally-Adjusted Annual Rate; WCCA: Without Capital Consumption Adjustment by Industry; WH: Warehousing; RE, includes rental and leasing: Real Estate; Art, Entertainment includes recreation, accommodation and food services; BS: business services

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

The NBER dates recessions in the US from peaks to troughs as: IQ80 to IIIQ80, IIIQ81 to IV82 and IVQ07 to IIQ09 (http://www.nber.org/cycles/cyclesmain.html). Table I-12 provides total annual level nonfarm employment in the US for the 1980s and the 2000s, which is different from 12-month comparisons. Nonfarm jobs rose by 4.859 million from 1982 to 1984, or 5.4 percent, and continued rapid growth in the rest of the decade. In contrast, nonfarm jobs are down by 7.661 million in 2010 relative to 2007 and fell by 958,000 in 2010 relative to 2009 even after six quarters of GDP growth. Monetary and fiscal stimuli have failed in increasing growth to rates required for mitigating job stress. The initial growth impulse reflects a flatter growth curve in the current expansion. Nonfarm jobs declined from 137.936 million in 2007 to 136.368 million in 2013, by 1.568 million or 1.1 percent. The US noninstitutional population or in condition to work increased from 231.867 million in 2007 to 245.679 million in 2013, by 13.812 million or 6.0 percent. The ratio of nonfarm jobs in 2007 or 137.936 million in 2007 to the noninstitutional population of 231.867 was 59.5. Nonfarm jobs in 2013 corresponding to the ratio of 59.5 of nonfarm jobs/noninstitutional population would be 146.179 million (0.595x245.679). The difference between actual nonfarm jobs of 136.368 million in 2013 and nonfarm jobs of 146.179 million that are equivalent to 59.5 percent of the noninstitutional population as in 2007 is 9.811 million. The proper explanation for this loss of work opportunities is not in secular stagnation but in cyclically slow growth. The US maintained growth at 3.0 percent on average over entire cycles with expansions at higher rates compensating for contractions. Growth at trend in the entire cycle from IVQ2007 to IIIQ2014 would have accumulated to 23.0 percent. GDP in IIIQ2014 would be $18,438.0 billion (in constant dollars of 2009) if the US had grown at trend, which is higher by $2,287.4 billion than actual $16,150.6 billion. There are about two trillion dollars of GDP less than at trend, explaining the 26.6 million unemployed or underemployed equivalent to actual unemployment of 16.1 percent of the effective labor force (Section I and earlier (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/10/world-financial-turbulence-twenty-seven.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/09/competitive-monetary-policy-and.html). US GDP in IIIQ2014 is 12.4 percent lower than at trend. US GDP grew from $14,991.8 billion in IVQ2007 in constant dollars to $16,150.6 billion in IIIQ2014 or 7.7 percent at the average annual equivalent rate of 1.1 percent. Cochrane (2014Jul2) estimates US GDP at more than 10 percent below trend. The US missed the opportunity to grow at higher rates during the expansion and it is difficult to catch up because growth rates in the final periods of expansions tend to decline. The US missed the opportunity for recovery of output and employment always afforded in the first four quarters of expansion from recessions. Zero interest rates and quantitative easing were not required or present in successful cyclical expansions and in secular economic growth at 3.0 percent per year and 2.0 percent per capita as measured by Lucas (2011May). There is cyclical uncommonly slow growth in the US instead of allegations of secular stagnation. There is similar behavior in manufacturing. The long-term trend is growth at average 3.3 percent per year from Jan 1919 to Sep 2014. Growth at 3.3 percent per year would raise the NSA index of manufacturing output from 99.2392 in Dec 2007 to 123.5550 in Sep 2014. The actual index NSA in Sep 2014 is 102.0228, which is 17.4 percent below trend. Manufacturing output grew at average 2.3 percent between Dec 1986 and Dec 2013, raising the index at trend to 115.7028 in Sep 2014. The output of manufacturing at 102.0228 in Sep 2014 is 11.8 percent below trend under this alternative calculation.

Table I-12, US, Total Nonfarm Employment in Thousands

Year

Total Nonfarm

Year

Total Nonfarm

1980

90,533

2000

132,019

1981

91,297

2001

132,074

1982

89,689

2002

130,628

1983

90,295

2003

130,318

1984

94,548

2004

131,749

1985

97,532

2005

134,005

1986

99,500

2006

136,398

1987

102,116

2007

137,936

1988

105,378

2008

137,170

1989

108,051

2009

131,233

1990

109,527

2010

130,275

1991

108,427

2011

131,842

1992

108,802

2012

134,104

1993

110,935

2013

136,368

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/

Chart I-43 provides annual nonfarm jobs in the US not seasonally adjusted from 2000 to 2013. Cyclically slow growth in the expansion since IIIQ2009 has not been sufficient to recover nonfarm jobs. Because of population growth, there are 9.811 million fewer nonfarm jobs in the US in 2013 than in 2007.

clip_image040

Chart I-43, US, Annual Nonfarm Jobs, NSA, Thousands, 2000-2013

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/

Chart I-44 provides annual nonfarm jobs in the US not seasonally adjusted from 1980 to 1993. Much more rapid cyclical growth as in other expansions historically allowed steady and rapid growth of nonfarm job opportunities even with similarly dynamic population growth.

clip_image041

Chart I-44, US, Annual Nonfarm Jobs, NSA, Thousands, 1980-1993

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov

The highest average yearly percentage of unemployed to the labor force since 1940 was 14.6 percent in 1940 followed by 9.9 percent in 1941, 8.5 percent in 1975, 9.7 percent in 1982 and 9.6 percent in 1983 (ftp://ftp.bls.gov/pub/special.requests/lf/aa2006/pdf/cpsaat1.pdf). The rate of unemployment remained at high levels in the 1930s, rising from 3.2 percent in 1929 to 22.9 percent in 1932 in one estimate and 23.6 percent in another with real wages increasing by 16.4 percent (Margo 1993, 43; see Pelaez and Pelaez, Regulation of Banks and Finance (2009b), 214-5). There are alternative estimates of 17.2 percent or 9.5 percent for 1940 with real wages increasing by 44 percent. Employment declined sharply during the 1930s. The number of hours worked remained in 1939 at 29 percent below the level of 1929 (Cole and Ohanian 1999). Private hours worked fell in 1939 to 25 percent of the level in 1929. The policy of encouraging collusion through the National Industrial Recovery Act (NIRA), to maintain high prices, together with the National Labor Relations Act (NLRA), to maintain high wages, prevented the US economy from recovering employment levels until Roosevelt abandoned these policies toward the end of the 1930s (for review of the literature analyzing the Great Depression see Pelaez and Pelaez, Regulation of Banks and Finance (2009b), 198-217).

The Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) makes yearly revisions of its establishment survey (Harris 2011BA):

“With the release of data for January 2011, the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) introduced its annual revision of national estimates of employment, hours, and earnings from the Current Employment Statistics (CES) monthly survey of nonfarm establishments.  Each year, the CES survey realigns its sample-based estimates to incorporate universe counts of employment—a process known as benchmarking.  Comprehensive counts of employment, or benchmarks, are derived primarily from unemployment insurance (UI) tax reports that nearly all employers are required to file with State Workforce Agencies.”

The number of not seasonally adjusted total private jobs in the US in Dec 2010 is 108.464 million, declining to 106.079 million in Jan 2011, or by 2.385 million, because of the adjustment of a different benchmark and not actual job losses. The not seasonally adjusted number of total private jobs in Dec 1984 is 80.250 million, declining to 78.704 million in Jan 1985, or by 1.546 million for the similar adjustment. Table I-13 attempts to measure job losses and gains in the recessions and expansions of 1981-1985 and 2007-2011. The final ten rows provide job creation from May 1983 to May 1984 and from May 2010 to May 2011, that is, at equivalent stages of the recovery from two comparable strong recessions. The row “Change ∆%” for May 1983 to May 1984 shows an increase of total nonfarm jobs by 4.9 percent and of 5.9 percent for total private jobs. The row “Change ∆%” for May 2010 to May 2011 shows an increase of total nonfarm jobs by 0.7 percent and of 1.7 percent for total private jobs. The last two rows of Table 7 provide a calculation of the number of jobs that would have been created from May 2010 to May 2011 if the rate of job creation had been the same as from May 1983 to May 1984. If total nonfarm jobs had grown between May 2010 and May 2011 by 4.9 percent, as between May 1983 and May 1984, 6.409 million jobs would have been created in the past 12 months for a difference of 5.457 million more total nonfarm jobs relative to 0.952 million jobs actually created. If total private jobs had grown between May 2010 and May 2011 by 5.9 percent as between May 1983 and May 1984, 6.337 million private jobs would have been created for a difference of 4.539 million more total private jobs relative to 1.798 million jobs actually created.

Table I-13, US, Total Nonfarm and Total Private Jobs Destroyed and Subsequently Created in Two Recessions IIIQ1981-IVQ1982 and IVQ2007-IIQ2009, Thousands and Percent

 

Total Nonfarm Jobs

Total Private Jobs

06/1981 #

92,288

75,969

11/1982 #

89,482

73,260

Change #

-2,806

-2,709

Change ∆%

-3.0

-3.6

12/1982 #

89,383

73,185

05/1984 #

94,471

78,049

Change #

5,088

4,864

Change ∆%

5.7

6.6

11/2007 #

139,090

116,291

05/2009 #

131,626

108,601

Change %

-7,464

-7,690

Change ∆%

-5.4

-6.6

12/2009 #

130,178

107,338

05/2011 #

131,753

108,494

Change #

1,575

1,156

Change ∆%

1.2

1.1

05/1983 #

90,005

73,667

05/1984 #

94,471

78,049

Change #

4,466

4,382

Change ∆%

4.9

5.9

05/2010 #

130,801

107,405

05/2011 #

131,753

109,203

Change #

952

1,798

Change ∆%

0.7

1.7

Change # by ∆% as in 05/1984 to 05/1985

6,409*

6,337**

Difference in Jobs that Would Have Been Created

5,457 =
6,409-952

4,539 =
6,337-1,798

*[(130,801x1.049)-130,801] = 6,409 thousand

**[(107,405)x1.059 – 107,405] = 6,337 thousand

Source: http://www.bls.gov/data/

IB Stagnating Real Wages. The wage bill is the product of average weekly hours times the earnings per hour. Table IB-1 provides the estimates by the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) of earnings per hour seasonally adjusted, increasing from $24.09/hour in Oct 2013 to $24.57/hour in Oct 2014, or by 2.0 percent. There has been disappointment about the pace of wage increases because of rising food and energy costs that inhibit consumption and thus sales and similar concern about growth of consumption that accounts for about 68.2 percent of GDP (Table I-10 at http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/11/growth-uncertainties-mediocre-cyclical.html). Growth of consumption by decreasing savings by means of controlling interest rates in what is called financial repression may not be lasting and sound for personal finances (See Pelaez and Pelaez, Globalization and the State, Vol. II (2008c), 81-6, Pelaez (1975), Section http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/11/growth-uncertainties-mediocre-cyclical.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/09/geopolitical-and-financial-risks.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/08/fluctuating-financial-valuations.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/06/financial-indecision-mediocre-cyclical.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/06/financial-instability-mediocre-cyclical.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/03/financial-uncertainty-mediocre-cyclical.html

http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/02/mediocre-cyclical-united-states.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/12/collapse-of-united-states-dynamism-of.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/11/global-financial-risk-mediocre-united.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/09/mediocre-and-decelerating-united-states.html

http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/09/increasing-interest-rate-risk.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/08/risks-of-steepening-yield-curve-and.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/06/tapering-quantitative-easing-policy-and.html

http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/06/mediocre-united-states-economic-growth.html

http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/04/mediocre-and-decelerating-united-states.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/03/mediocre-gdp-growth-at-16-to-20-percent.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/12/mediocre-and-decelerating-united-states_24.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/12/mediocre-and-decelerating-united-states.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/09/historically-sharper-recoveries-from.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/09/collapse-of-united-states-dynamism-of.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/07/recovery-without-jobs-stagnating-real.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/mediocre-recovery-without-jobs.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/04/mediocre-growth-with-high-unemployment.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/04/mediocre-economic-growth-falling-real.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/03/mediocre-economic-growth-flattening.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/01/mediocre-economic-growth-financial.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/12/slow-growth-falling-real-disposable.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/11/us-growth-standstill-falling-real.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/10/slow-growth-driven-by-reducing-savings.html). Average hourly earnings seasonally adjusted increased 0.1 percent from $24.54 in Sep 2014 to $24.57 in Oct 2014. Average private weekly earnings increased $21.42 from $828.70 in Oct 2013 to $850.70 in Oct 2014 or 2.6 percent and increased from $846.63 in Sep 2014 to $850.12 in Oct 2014 or 0.4 percent. The inflation-adjusted wage bill can only be calculated for Sep, which is the most recent month for which there are estimates of the consumer price index. Earnings per hour (not-seasonally-adjusted (NSA)) rose from $24.16 in Sep 2013 to $24.50 in Sep 2014 or by 1.4 percent (http://www.bls.gov/data/; see Table IB-3 below). Data NSA are more suitable for comparison over a year. Average weekly hours NSA were 34.9 in Sep 2013 and 34.5 in Sep 2014 (http://www.bls.gov/data/; see Table IB-2 below). The wage bill increased 0.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Sep 2014:

{[(wage bill in Sep 2014)/(wage bill in Sep 2013)]-1}100 =

{[($24.50x34.5)/($24.16x34.9)]-1]}100

= {[($845.25)/($843.18)]-1}100 = 0.2%

CPI inflation was 1.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Sep 2014 (http://www.bls.gov/cpi/) for an inflation-adjusted wage-bill change of minus 1.5 percent :{[(1.002/1.017)-1]100 = -1.5%} (see Table IB-5 below for Sep 2014 with minor rounding difference). The wage bill for Oct 2014 before inflation adjustment increased 2.3 percent relative to the wage bill for Oct 2013:

{[(wage bill in Sep 2014)/(wage bill in Sep 2013)]-1}100 =

{[($24.51x34.5)/($24.04x34.4)]-1]}100

= {[845.59)/($826.98]-1}100 = 2.3%

Average hourly earnings increased 2.0 percent from Oct 2013 to Oct 2014 {[($24.51/$24.04) – 1]100 = 2.0%} while hours worked increased 0.3 percent {[(34.5/34.4) – 1]100 = 0.3%}. The increase of the wage bill is the product of the increase of hourly earnings of 2.0 percent and decrease of hours worked of 0.3 percent {[(1.020x1.003) -1]100 = 2.3%}.

Energy and food price increases are similar to a “silent tax” that is highly regressive, harming the most those with lowest incomes. There are concerns that the wage bill would deteriorate in purchasing power because of renewed raw materials shocks in the form of increases in prices of commodities such as the 31.1 percent steady increase in the DJ-UBS Commodity Index from Jul 2, 2010 to Sep 2, 2011. The charts of four commodity price indexes by Bloomberg show steady increase since Jul 2, 2010 that was interrupted briefly only in Nov 2010 with the sovereign issues in Europe triggered by Ireland; in Mar 2011 by the earthquake and tsunami in Japan; and in the beginning of May 2011 by the decline in oil prices and sovereign risk difficulties in Europe (http://www.bloomberg.com/markets/commodities/futures/). Renewed risk aversion because of the sovereign risks in Europe had reduced the rate of increase of the DJ UBS commodity index to 10.2 percent on May 2, 2014, relative to Jul 2, 2010 (see Table VI-4) but there has been a shift in investor preferences into equities. Inflation has been rising in waves with carry trades driven by zero interest rates to commodity futures during periods of risk appetite with interruptions during risk aversion (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/10/financial-oscillations-world-inflation.html). Inflation-adjusted wages fall sharply during carry trades from zero interest rates to long positions in commodity futures during periods of risk appetite.

Table IB-1, US, Earnings per Hour and Average Weekly Hours SA

Earnings per Hour

Oct 2013

Aug 2014

Sep 2014

Oct 2014

Total Private

$24.09

$24.54

$24.54

$24.57

Goods Producing

$25.30

$25.79

$25.79

$25.88

Service Providing

$23.80

$24.24

$24.25

$24.26

Average Weekly Earnings

       

Total Private

$828.70

$846.63

$846.63

$850.12

Goods Producing

$1,022.12

$1,047.07

$1,041.92

$1,048.14

Service Providing

$790.16

$807.19

$809.95

$810.28

Average Weekly Hours

       

Total Private

34.4

34.5

34.5

34.6

Goods Producing

40.4

40.6

40.4

40.5

Service Providing

33.2

33.3

33.4

33.4

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/

Average weekly hours in Table IB-2 fell from 34.9 in Dec 2007 at the beginning of the contraction to 33.8 in Jun 2009, which was the last month of the contraction. Average weekly hours rose to 34.4 in Dec 2011 and oscillated to 34.9 in Dec 2012 and 34.7 in Dec 2013. Average weekly hours of all employees eased to 34.5 in Oct 2014.

Table IB-2, US, Average Weekly Hours of All Employees, NSA 2006-2014

Year

Jan

Feb

Mar

Apr

May

Jun

Jul

Aug

Sep

Oct

Nov

Dec

2006

   

34.2

34.6

34.3

34.6

34.9

34.6

34.5

34.9

34.4

34.6

2007

34.1

34.1

34.3

34.7

34.4

34.7

34.9

34.7

35.0

34.5

34.5

34.9

2008

34.1

34.2

34.7

34.4

34.4

34.9

34.5

34.6

34.4

34.4

34.6

34.1

2009

33.8

34.2

33.9

33.6

33.7

33.8

33.8

34.3

33.7

33.8

34.2

33.9

2010

33.7

33.6

33.8

34.0

34.4

34.1

34.2

34.7

34.1

34.3

34.2

34.2

2011

34.2

34.0

34.1

34.2

34.6

34.4

34.4

34.4

34.4

34.8

34.3

34.4

2012

34.5

34.2

34.2

34.6

34.2

34.4

34.8

34.5

34.9

34.3

34.3

34.9

2013

34.0

34.2

34.3

34.3

34.3

34.9

34.3

34.5

34.9

34.4

34.4

34.7

2014

34.0

34.4

34.7

34.4

34.4

34.9

34.5

34.6

34.5

34.5

   

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/

Chart IB-1 provides average weekly hours monthly from Mar 2006 to May 2014. Average weekly hours remained relatively stable in the period before the contraction and fell sharply during the contraction as business could not support lower production with the same labor input. Average weekly hours rose rapidly during the expansion but have stabilized at a level below that prevailing before the contraction.

clip_image042

Chart IB-1, US, Average Weekly Hours of All Employees, SA 2006-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/data/

Calculations of inflation-adjusted average hourly earnings using BLS data are in Table IB-3. The final column of Table IB-3 (“12-Month Real ∆%”) provides inflation-adjusted average hourly earnings of all employees in the US. Average hourly earnings rose above inflation throughout the first nine months of 2007 just before the global recession that began in the final quarter of 2007 when average hourly earnings began to lose to inflation. In contrast, average hourly earnings of all US workers have risen less than inflation in four months in 2010 and in all but the first month in 2011 and the loss accelerated at 1.8 percent in Sep 2011, declining to a real loss of 1.1 percent in Feb 2012 and 0.6 percent in Mar 2012. There was a gain of 0.5 percent in Apr 2012 in inflation-adjusted average hourly earnings but another fall of 0.6 percent in May 2012 followed by increases of 0.3 percent in Jun and 1.0 percent in Jul 2012. Real hourly earnings stagnated in the 12 months ending in Aug 2012 with increase of only 0.1 percent, and increased 0.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Sep 2012. Real hourly earnings fell 1.3 percent in Oct 2012 and gained 1.0 percent in Dec 2012 but declined 0.3 percent in Jan 2013 and stagnated at change of 0.1 percent in Feb 2013. Real hourly earnings increased 0.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Mar 2013 and 0.2 percent in Apr 2013, increasing 0.6 percent in May 2013. In Jun 2013, real hourly earnings increased 1.0 percent relative to Jun 2012. Real hourly earnings fell 0.6 percent in the 12 months ending in Jul 2013 and increased 0.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Aug 2013. Real hourly earnings increased 1.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Oct 2013 and 1.0 percent in Nov 2013. Real hourly earnings increased 0.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Dec 2013. Real hourly earnings increased 0.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Jan 2014 and 1.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Feb 2014. Real hourly earnings increased 1.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Mar 2014. Real hourly earnings fell 0.1 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr 2014. Real hourly earnings stagnated at 0.0 percent in the 12 months ending in May 2014. Real hourly earnings fell 0.1 percent in the 12 months ending in Jun 2014. Real hourly earnings changed 0.0 percent in the 12 months ending in Jul 2014 and increased 0.5 percent in the 12 months ending in Aug 2014. Real hourly earnings fell 0.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Sep 2014. Real hourly earnings are oscillating in part because of world inflation waves caused by carry trades from zero interest rates to commodity futures (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/10/financial-oscillations-world-inflation.html) and in part because of the collapse of hiring (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/10/global-financial-volatility-recovery.html) originating in weak economic growth (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/11/growth-uncertainties-mediocre-cyclical.html).

Table IB-3, US, Average Hourly Earnings Nominal and Inflation Adjusted, Dollars and % NSA

 

AHE ALL

12 Month-
Nominal
∆%

∆% 12 Month CPI

12-Month
Real ∆%

2007

       

Jan*

$20.69*

4.2*

2.1

2.1*

Feb*

$20.77*

4.1*

2.4

1.7*

Mar

$20.80

3.6

2.8

0.8

Apr

$21.03

3.3

2.6

0.7

May

$20.82

3.8

2.7

1.1

Jun

$20.81

3.8

2.7

1.1

Jul

$20.97

3.4

2.4

1.0

Aug

$20.83

3.5

2.0

1.5

Sep

$21.17

4.0

2.8

1.2

Oct

$21.05

2.6

3.5

-0.9

Nov

$21.12

3.3

4.3

-1.0

Dec

$21.35

3.6

4.1

-0.5

2010

       

Jan

$22.53

2.0

2.6

-0.6

Feb

$22.59

1.4

2.1

-0.7

Mar

$22.49

1.1

2.3

-1.2

Apr

$22.54

1.8

2.2

-0.4

May

$22.61

2.5

2.0

0.5

Jun

$22.35

1.7

1.1

0.6

Jul

$22.42

1.8

1.2

0.6

Aug

$22.55

1.7

1.1

0.6

Sep

$22.61

1.8

1.1

0.7

Oct

$22.70

1.9

1.2

0.7

Nov

$22.70

1.1

1.1

0.0

Dec

$22.77

1.7

1.5

0.2

2011

       

Jan

$23.17

2.8

1.6

1.2

Feb

$23.00

1.8

2.1

-0.3

Mar

$22.91

1.9

2.7

-0.8

Apr

$22.97

1.9

3.2

-1.3

May

$23.07

2.0

3.6

-1.5

Jun

$22.82

2.1

3.6

-1.4

Jul

$22.95

2.4

3.6

-1.2

Aug

$22.86

1.4

3.8

-2.3

Sep

$23.06

2.0

3.9

-1.8

Oct

$23.31

2.7

3.5

-0.8

Nov

$23.16

2.0

3.4

-1.4

Dec

$23.22

2.0

3.0

-1.0

2012

       

Jan

$23.57

1.7

2.9

-1.2

Feb

$23.41

1.8

2.9

-1.1

Mar

$23.40

2.1

2.7

-0.6

Apr

$23.62

2.8

2.3

0.5

May

$23.33

1.1

1.7

-0.6

Jun

$23.28

2.0

1.7

0.3

Jul

$23.49

2.4

1.4

1.0

Aug

$23.27

1.8

1.7

0.1

Sep

$23.68

2.7

2.0

0.7

Oct

$23.52

0.9

2.2

-1.3

Nov

$23.59

1.9

1.8

0.1

Dec

$23.85

2.7

1.7

1.0

2013

       

Jan

$23.88

1.3

1.6

-0.3

Feb

$23.91

2.1

2.0

0.1

Mar

$23.84

1.9

1.5

0.4

Apr

$23.92

1.3

1.1

0.2

May

$23.80

2.0

1.4

0.6

Jun

$23.93

2.8

1.8

1.0

Jul

$23.81

1.4

2.0

-0.6

Aug

$23.79

2.2

1.5

0.7

Sep

$24.16

2.0

1.2

0.8

Oct

$24.04

2.2

1.0

1.2

Nov

$24.11

2.2

1.2

1.0

Dec

$24.30

1.9

1.5

0.4

2014

       

Jan

$24.35

2.0

1.6

0.4

Feb

$24.58

2.8

1.1

1.7

Mar

$24.48

2.7

1.5

1.2

Apr

$24.38

1.9

2.0

-0.1

May

$24.29

2.1

2.1

0.0

Jun

$24.40

2.0

2.1

-0.1

Jul

$24.29

2.0

2.0

0.0

Aug

$24.31

2.2

1.7

0.5

Sep

$24.50

1.4

1.7

-0.3

Oct

$24.51

2.0

   

Note: AHE ALL: average hourly earnings of all employees; CPI: consumer price index; Real: adjusted by CPI inflation; NA: not available

*AHE of production and nonsupervisory employees because of unavailability of data for all employees for Jan-Feb 2006

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/

Calculations of inflation-adjusted average hourly earnings using BLS data are in Table IB-3. The final column of Table IB-3 (“12-Month Real ∆%”) provides inflation-adjusted average hourly earnings of all employees in the US. Average hourly earnings rose above inflation throughout the first nine months of 2007 just before the global recession that began in the final quarter of 2007 when average hourly earnings began to lose to inflation. In contrast, average hourly earnings of all US workers have risen less than inflation in four months in 2010 and in all but the first month in 2011 and the loss accelerated at 1.8 percent in Sep 2011, declining to a real loss of 1.1 percent in Feb 2012 and 0.6 percent in Mar 2012. There was a gain of 0.6 percent in Apr 2012 in inflation-adjusted average hourly earnings but another fall of 0.6 percent in May 2012 followed by increases of 0.3 percent in Jun and 0.9 percent in Jul 2012. Real hourly earnings stagnated in the 12 months ending in Aug 2012 with increase of only 0.1 percent, and increased 0.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Sep 2012. Real hourly earnings fell 1.2 percent in Oct 2012 and gained 1.0 percent in Dec 2012 but declined 0.3 percent in Jan 2013 and stagnated at change of 0.1 percent in Feb 2013. Real hourly earnings increased 0.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Mar 2013 and 0.2 percent in Apr 2013, increasing 0.7 percent in May 2013. In Jun 2013, real hourly earnings increased 1.1 percent relative to Jun 2012. Real hourly earnings fell 0.6 percent in the 12 months ending in Jul 2013 and increased 0.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Aug 2013. Real hourly earnings increased 1.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Oct 2013 and 0.9 percent in Nov 2013. Real hourly earnings increased 0.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Dec 2013. Real hourly earnings increased 0.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Jan 2014 and 1.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Feb 2014. Real hourly earnings increased 1.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Mar 2014. Real hourly earnings fell 0.1 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr 2014. Real hourly earnings fell 0.1 percent in the 12 months ending in May 2014. Real hourly earnings fell 0.1 percent in the 12 months ending in Jun 2014. Real hourly earnings increased 0.1 percent in the 12 months ending in Jul 2014 and increased 0.5 percent in the 12 months ending in Aug 2014. Real hourly earnings fell 0.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Sep 2014. Real hourly earnings are oscillating in part because of world inflation waves caused by carry trades from zero interest rates to commodity futures (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/10/financial-oscillations-world-inflation.html) and in part because of the collapse of hiring (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/10/global-financial-volatility-recovery.html) originating in weak economic growth (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/11/growth-uncertainties-mediocre-cyclical.html).

Table IB-4, US, Average Hourly Earnings of All Employees NSA in Constant Dollars of 1982-1984

Year

Jan

Feb

Mar

Apr

May

Jun

Jul

Aug

Sep

Dec

2006

   

10.05

10.10

9.91

9.88

9.97

9.87

10.03

10.21

2007

10.22

10.21

10.13

10.17

10.01

9.99

10.07

10.02

10.15

10.16

2008

10.11

10.11

10.10

9.99

9.90

9.83

9.76

9.82

9.93

10.46

2009

10.46

10.50

10.46

10.38

10.31

10.19

10.23

10.28

10.29

10.37

2010

10.40

10.42

10.33

10.34

10.36

10.25

10.28

10.33

10.35

10.39

2011

10.52

10.39

10.25

10.21

10.21

10.11

10.16

10.09

10.16

10.29

2012

10.40

10.28

10.20

10.27

10.15

10.14

10.25

10.10

10.23

10.39

∆%12M

-1.1

-1.1

-0.5

0.6

-0.6

0.3

0.9

0.1

0.7

1.0

2013

10.37

10.30

10.24

10.29

10.22

10.25

10.19

10.17

10.32

10.43

∆%12M

-0.3

0.2

0.4

0.2

0.7

1.1

-0.6

0.7

0.9

0.4

2014

10.41

10.47

10.36

10.28

10.21

10.24

10.20

10.22

10.29

 

∆%12M

0.4

1.7

1.2

-0.1

-0.1

-0.1

0.1

0.5

-0.3

 

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/

Chart IB-2 of the US Bureau of Labor Statistics plots average hourly earnings of all US employees in constant 1982-1984 dollars with evident decline from annual earnings of $10.34 in 2009 and $10.35 in 2010 to $10.24 in 2011 and $10.24 again in 2012 or loss of 1.1 percent (data in http://www.bls.gov/data/). Annual real hourly earnings increased 0.5 percent in 2013 relative to 2012. The economic welfare or wellbeing of United States workers deteriorated in a recovery without hiring (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/10/global-financial-volatility-recovery.html), stagnating/declining real wages and 26.6 million unemployed or underemployed (Section I and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/10/world-financial-turbulence-twenty-seven.html) because of mediocre economic growth (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/11/growth-uncertainties-mediocre-cyclical.html).

clip_image043

Chart IB-2, US, Average Hourly Earnings of All Employees in Constant Dollars of 1982-1984, SA 2006-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/

Chart IB-3 provides 12-month percentage changes of average hourly earnings of all employees in constant dollars of 1982-1984, that is, adjusted for inflation. There was sharp contraction of inflation-adjusted average hourly earnings of US employees during parts of 2007 and 2008. Rates of change in 12 months became positive in parts of 2009 and 2010 but then became negative again in 2011 and into 2012 with temporary increase in Apr 2012 that was reversed in May with another gain in Jun and Jul 2012 followed by stagnation in Aug 2012. There was marginal gain in Sep 2012 with sharp decline in Oct 2012, stagnation in Nov 2012, increase in Dec 2012 and renewed decrease in Jan 2013 with near stagnation in Feb 2013 followed by mild increase in Mar-Apr 2013. Hourly earnings adjusted for inflation increased in Jun 2013 and fell in Jul 2013, increasing in Aug-Dec 2013 and Jan-Mar 2014. Average hourly earnings decreased in Apr-May 2014 and rebounded mildly in Jun-Jul 2014, increasing in Aug 2014 and decreasing in Sep 2014.

clip_image044

Chart IB-3, Average Hourly Earnings of All Employees NSA 12-Month Percent Change, 1982-1984 Dollars, NSA 2007-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/

Average weekly earnings of all US employees in the US in constant dollars of 1982-1984 from the dataset of the US Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) are provided in Table IB-5. Average weekly earnings fell 3.2 percent after adjusting for inflation in the 12 months ending in Aug 2011, decreased 0.9 percent in the 12 months ending in Sep 2011 and increased 0.6 percent in the 12 months ending in Oct 2011. Average weekly earnings fell 1.0 percent in the 12 months ending in Nov 2011 and 0.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Dec 2011. Average weekly earnings declined 0.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Jan 2012 and 0.5 percent in the 12 months ending in Feb 2012. Average weekly earnings in constant dollars were virtually flat in Mar 2012 relative to Mar 2011, decreasing 0.2 percent. Average weekly earnings in constant dollars increased 1.7 percent in Apr 2012 relative to Apr 2011 but fell 1.7 percent in May 2012 relative to May 2011, increasing 0.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Jun 2012 and 2.1 percent in the 12 months ending in Jul 2012. Real weekly earnings increased 0.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Aug 2012 and 2.1 percent in the 12 months ending in Sep 2012. Real weekly earnings fell 2.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Oct 2012 and increased 0.1 percent in the 12 months ending in Nov 2012 and 2.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Dec 2012. Real weekly earnings fell 1.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Jan 2013 and virtually stagnated with gain of 0.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Feb 2013, increasing 0.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Mar 2013. Real weekly earnings fell 0.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr 2013 and increased 0.9 percent in the 12 months ending in May 2013. Average weekly earnings increased 2.5 percent in the 12 months ending in Jun 2013 and fell 2.0 percent in the 12 months ending in Jul 2013. Real weekly earnings increased 0.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Aug 2013, 0.8 percent in the 12 months ending in Sep 2013 and 1.5 percent in the 12 months ending in Oct 2013. Average weekly earnings increased 1.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Nov 2013 and fell 0.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Dec 2013. Average weekly earnings increased 0.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Jan 2014 and 2.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Feb 2014. Average weekly earnings increased 2.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Mar 2014 and 0.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr 2014. Average weekly earnings in constant dollars increased 0.2 percent in the 12 months ending in May 2014 and fell 0.1 percent in the 12 months ending in Jun 2014. Real average weekly earnings increased 0.6 percent in the 12 months ending in Jul 2014 and 0.8 percent in the 12 months ending in Aug 2014.

Real weekly earnings decreased 1.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Sep 2014. Table I-5 confirms the trend of deterioration of purchasing power of average weekly earnings in 2011 and into 2013 with oscillations according to carry trades causing world inflation waves (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/10/imf-view-squeeze-of-economic-activity.html). On an annual basis, average weekly earnings in constant 1982-1984 dollars increased from $349.34 in 2007 to $354.16 in 2013, by 1.4 percent or at the average rate of 0.2 percent per year (data in http://www.bls.gov/data/). Annual average weekly earnings in constant dollars of $353.11 in 2010 were virtually unchanged at $353.00 in 2012. Those who still work bring back home a paycheck that buys fewer high-quality goods than a year earlier. The fractured US job market does not provide an opportunity for advancement as in past booms following recessions because of poor job creation with 26.6 million unemployed or underemployed (Section I and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/10/world-financial-turbulence-twenty-seven.html) in a recovery without hiring (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/10/global-financial-volatility-recovery.html) because of mediocre economic growth (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/11/growth-uncertainties-mediocre-cyclical.html).

Table IB-5, US, Average Weekly Earnings of All Employees in Constant Dollars of 1982-1984, NSA 2007-2014

Year

Apr

May

Jun

Jul

Aug

Sep

2006

349.61

339.78

341.73

347.80

341.42

346.02

2007

353.07

344.42

346.58

351.35

347.64

355.39

2008

343.80

340.46

343.08

336.75

339.86

341.51

2009

348.86

347.47

344.28

345.61

352.48

346.72

2010

351.53

356.49

349.66

351.71

358.43

352.96

2011

349.29

353.25

347.78

349.45

347.12

349.62

2012

355.19

347.19

348.98

356.80

348.48

357.13

∆%12M

1.7

-1.7

0.3

2.1

0.4

2.1

2013

352.84

350.44

357.66

349.61

350.94

360.10

∆%12M

-0.7

0.9

2.5

-2.0

0.7

0.8

2014

353.76

351.23

357.28

351.74

353.64

355.10

∆%12M

0.3

0.2

-0.1

0.6

0.8

-1.4

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/

Chart IB-4 provides average weekly earnings of all employees in constant dollars of 1982-1984. The same pattern emerges of sharp decline during the contraction, followed by recovery in the expansion and continuing fall with oscillations caused by carry trades from zero interest rates into commodity futures from 2010 to 2011 and into 2012-2014.

clip_image045

Chart IB-4, US, Average Weekly Earnings of All Employees in Constant Dollars of 1982-1984, SA 2006-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/

Chart IB-5 provides 12-month percentage changes of average weekly earnings of all employees in the US in constant dollars of 1982-1984. There is the same pattern of contraction during the global recession in 2008 and then again trend of deterioration in the recovery without hiring and inflation waves. (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/10/financial-oscillations-world-inflation.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/09/world-inflation-waves-squeeze-of.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/08/monetary-policy-world-inflation-waves.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/07/world-inflation-waves-united-states.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/06/valuation-risks-world-inflation-waves.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/05/world-inflation-waves-squeeze-of.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/04/imf-view-world-inflation-waves-squeeze.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/03/interest-rate-risks-world-inflation.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/01/world-inflation-waves-interest-rate.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/12/tapering-quantitative-easing-mediocre.html

http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/11/risks-of-zero-interest-rates-world.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/10/world-inflation-waves-regional-economic.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/08/duration-dumping-and-peaking-valuations.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/07/tapering-quantitative-easing-policy-and.html

http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/06/paring-quantitative-easing-policy-and.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/05/word-inflation-waves-squeeze-of.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/04/world-inflation-waves-squeeze-of.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/04/recovery-without-hiring-ten-million.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/04/mediocre-and-decelerating-united-states.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/02/world-inflation-waves-united-states.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/12/recovery-without-hiring-forecast-growth.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/11/united-states-unsustainable-fiscal.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/09/recovery-without-hiring-world-inflation.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012_09_01_archive.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/07/world-inflation-waves-financial.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/destruction-of-three-trillion-dollars.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/05/world-inflation-waves-monetary-policy.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/recovery-without-hiring-continuance-of.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/04/fractured-labor-market-with-hiring.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/03/global-financial-and-economic-risk.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/02/world-inflation-waves-united-states.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/01/world-inflation-waves-united-states.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/01/recovery-without-hiring-united-states.html

http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/09/recovery-without-hiring-world-inflation.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012_09_01_archive.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/07/world-inflation-waves-financial.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/05/world-inflation-waves-monetary-policy.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/recovery-without-hiring-continuance-of.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/04/fractured-labor-market-with-hiring.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/03/global-financial-and-economic-risk.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/02/world-inflation-waves-united-states.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/01/world-inflation-waves-united-states.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/01/recovery-without-hiring-united-states.html).

clip_image046

Chart IB-5, US, Average Weekly Earnings of All Employees NSA in Constant Dollars of 1982-1984 12-Month Percent Change, NSA 2007-2014

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/

© Carlos M. Pelaez, 2009, 2010, 2011, 2012, 2013, 2014.

No comments:

Post a Comment