Increase of Total Nonfarm Payroll Jobs by 4.800 Million and of Private Payroll Jobs by 4.767 Million in Jun 2020 In The Global Recession of Lockdown of Economic Activity in the COVID-19 Event, Beginning Recovery of United States Vehicle Sales, Forty-One Million Unemployed or Underemployed in the Lost Economic Cycle of the Global Recession with Economic Growth Underperforming Below Trend Worldwide, Sample Hurdles in Measuring Real Wages, Cyclically Stagnating Real Disposable Income Per Capita, Beginning Recovery of Personal Consumption, Financial Repression, World Cyclical Slow Growth, and Government Intervention in Globalization
Carlos M. Pelaez
© Carlos M. Pelaez, 2009, 2010, 2011, 2012, 2013, 2014, 2015, 2016, 2017, 2018, 2019, 2020.
I Forty-One Million Unemployed or Underemployed in the Lost Economic Cycle of the Global Recession with Economic Growth Underperforming Below Trend Worldwide
IA2 Number of People in Job Stress
IA3 Long-term and Cyclical Comparison of Employment
IA4 Job Creation
II Stagnating Real Disposable Income and Consumption Expenditures
IIB1 Stagnating Real Disposable Income and Consumption Expenditures
IB2 Financial Repression
III World Financial Turbulence
IV Global Inflation
V World Economic Slowdown
VA United States
VB Japan
VC China
VD Euro Area
VE Germany
VF France
VG Italy
VH United Kingdom
VI Valuation of Risk Financial Assets
VII Economic Indicators
VIII Interest Rates
IX Conclusion
References
Appendixes
Appendix I The Great Inflation
IIIB Appendix on Safe Haven Currencies
IIIC Appendix on Fiscal Compact
IIID Appendix on European Central Bank Large Scale Lender of Last Resort
IIIG Appendix on Deficit Financing of Growth and the Debt Crisis
Foreword A. Total nonfarm payroll employment seasonally adjusted (SA) increased 4.800 million in Jun 2020 and private payroll employment increased 4.767 million. The Bureau of Labor Statistics states (https://www.bls.gov/news.release/empsit.nr0.htm): “Our analysis suggests that the net effect of these hurricanes [Harvey and Irma] was to reduce the estimate of total nonfarm payroll employment for September. There was no discernible effect on the national unemployment rate. No changes were made to either the establishment or household survey estimation procedures for the September figures.” A hurdle in analyzing the labor market is the global recession, with output in the US reaching a high in Feb 2020 (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html), in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event (https://www.bls.gov/cps/employment-situation-covid19-faq-june-2020.pdf).
Table I-8, US, Monthly Change in Jobs, Number SA
Month | 1981 | 1982 | 1983 | 2008 | 2009 | 2010 | Private |
1993 | 2020 | ||||||
Jan | 299 | 214 | 179 | ||||
Feb | 250 | 251 | 220 | ||||
Mar | -50 | -1373 | -1356 | ||||
Apr | 302 | -20787 | -19835 | ||||
May | 272 | 2699 | 3232 | ||||
Jun | 181 | 4800 | 4767 |
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
Foreword B. Table VA-1B provides the seasonally adjusted annual rate of total vehicle sales in the United States. The rate decreased from 17.705 in Jun 2019 and 17.203 in Feb 2020 to 9.051 in Apr 2020 in the lockdown of economic activity in the global recession, with output in the US reaching a high in Feb 2020 (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html), in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event. The rate recovered to 12.624 in May 2020 and 13.351 in Jun 2020 in gradual return to economic activity.
Table VA-1B, United States, Annual Rate, Total Vehicle Sales, Seasonally Adjusted Annual Rate
2019-01-01 | 17.238 |
2019-02-01 | 17.026 |
2019-03-01 | 17.773 |
2019-04-01 | 17.049 |
2019-05-01 | 17.933 |
2019-06-01 | 17.705 |
2019-07-01 | 17.442 |
2019-08-01 | 17.512 |
2019-09-01 | 17.723 |
2019-10-01 | 17.046 |
2019-11-01 | 17.447 |
2019-12-01 | 17.120 |
2020-01-01 | 17.364 |
2020-02-01 | 17.203 |
2020-03-01 | 11.779 |
2020-04-01 | 9.051 |
2020-05-01 | 12.624 |
2020-06-01 | 13.351 |
Source: Economic Research Division, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/TOTALSA
Chart I-4 of the Economic Research Division, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, provides the complete data set of SAAR of total car sales in the US. The SAAR of 9.051 in Apr 2020 is lower than the lowest rate in the global recession at 9.223 in Feb 2009.
Chart I-4, SA Annual Rate of Total Car Sales in the United States, Jan 1976 to Apr 2020
Source: Economic Research Division, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/TOTALSA
Chart I-5 of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve provides output of motor vehicles and parts in the United States from 1972 to 2020. Output virtually stagnated since the late 1990s with recent increase followed by the highest decrease in the data history in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event.
Chart 1-5, US, Motor Vehicles and Parts Output, 1972-2020
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
https://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/g17/Current/default.htm
Table VI-7, updated with every blog comment, provides in the second column the yield at the close of market of the 10-year Treasury note on the date in the first column. The price in the third column is calculated with the coupon of 2.625 percent of the 10-year note current at the time of the second round of quantitative easing after Nov 3, 2010 and the final column “∆% 11/04/10” calculates the percentage change of the price on the date relative to that of 101.2573 at the close of market on Nov 4, 2010, one day after the decision on quantitative easing by the Fed on Nov 3, 2010. Prices with new coupons such as 2.0 percent in recent auctions (http://www.treasurydirect.gov/RI/OFAuctions?form=extended&cusip=912828RR3) are not comparable to prices in Table VI-7. The highest yield in the decade was 5.510 percent on May 1, 2001 that would result in a loss of principal of 22.9 percent relative to the price on Nov 4. Monetary policy has created a “duration trap” of bond prices. Duration is the percentage change in bond price resulting from a percentage change in yield or what economists call the yield elasticity of bond price. Duration is higher the lower the bond coupon and yield, all other things constant. This means that the price loss in a yield rise from low coupons and yields is much higher than with high coupons and yields. Intuitively, the higher coupon payments offset part of the price loss. Prices/yields of Treasury securities were affected by the combination of Fed purchases for its program of quantitative easing and by the flight to dollar-denominated assets because of geopolitical risks in the Middle East, subsequently by the tragic Great East Japan Earthquake and Tsunami and now again by the sovereign risk doubts in Europe and the growth recession in the US and the world. The yield of 0.673 percent at the close of market on Fri Jul 3, 2020 would be equivalent to price of 118.8470 in a hypothetical bond maturing in 10 years with coupon of 2.625 percent for price increase of 17.4 percent relative to the price on Nov 4, 2010, one day after the decision on the second program of quantitative easing, as shown in the last row of Table VI-7. The price loss between Sep 7, 2012 and Sep 14, 2012 would have been 1.7 percent in just five trading days. The price loss between Jun 1, 2012 and Jun 8, 2012 would have been 1.6 percent, in just a week, and much higher with leverage of 10:1 as typical in Treasury positions. The price loss between Mar 9, 2012 and Mar 16, 2012 is 2.3 percent but much higher when using common leverage of 10:1. The price loss between Dec 28, 2012 and Jan 4, 2013 would have been 1.7 percent. These losses defy annualizing. If inflation accelerates, yields of Treasury securities may rise sharply. Yields are not observed without special yield-lowering effects such as the flight into dollars caused by the events in the Middle East, continuing purchases of Treasury securities by the Fed, the tragic Tōhoku or Great East Earthquake and Tsunami of Mar 11, 2011 affecting Japan, recurring fears on European sovereign credit issues and worldwide risk aversion in the week of Sep 30 caused by “let’s twist again” monetary policy. There is a difficult climb from the record federal deficit of 9.8 percent of GDP in 2009 and cumulative deficit of $5090 billion in four consecutive years of deficits exceeding one trillion dollars from 2009 to 2012, which is the worst fiscal performance since World War II (https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2018/10/global-contraction-of-valuations-of.html and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2017/04/mediocre-cyclical-economic-growth-with.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2017/01/twenty-four-million-unemployed-or.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2016/07/unresolved-us-balance-of-payments.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2016/04/proceeding-cautiously-in-reducing.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/09/monetary-policy-designed-on-measurable.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/06/fluctuating-financial-asset-valuations.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/03/irrational-exuberance-mediocre-cyclical.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/12/patience-on-interest-rate-increases.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/09/world-inflation-waves-squeeze-of.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/02/theory-and-reality-of-cyclical-slow.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/09/duration-dumping-and-peaking-valuations.html and earlier at http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/02/united-states-unsustainable-fiscal.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/11/united-states-unsustainable-fiscal.html and earlier Section IB at http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/08/expanding-bank-cash-and-deposits-with.html). There is no subsequent jump of debt in US peacetime history as the one from 39.4 percent of GDP in 2008 to 65.8 percent of GDP in 2011, 70.3 percent in 2012, 72.2 percent in 2013, 73.7 percent in 2014, 72.5 percent in 2015, 76.4 percent in 2016, 76.1 percent in 2017 and 77.8 percent in 2018 (https://www.cbo.gov/about/products/budget-economic-data#6) (https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2018/10/global-contraction-of-valuations-of.html and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2017/04/mediocre-cyclical-economic-growth-with.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2017/01/twenty-four-million-unemployed-or.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2016/07/unresolved-us-balance-of-payments.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2016/04/proceeding-cautiously-in-reducing.html and earlier (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2016/01/weakening-equities-and-dollar.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/06/fluctuating-financial-asset-valuations.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/03/irrational-exuberance-mediocre-cyclical.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/12/patience-on-interest-rate-increases.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/09/world-inflation-waves-squeeze-of.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/08/monetary-policy-world-inflation-waves.html
and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/02/theory-and-reality-of-cyclical-slow.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/09/duration-dumping-and-peaking-valuations.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/02/united-states-unsustainable-fiscal.html). The US is facing an unsustainable debt/GDP path (https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2018/10/global-contraction-of-valuations-of.html and earlier and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2017/01/twenty-four-million-unemployed-or.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2016/12/rising-yields-and-dollar-revaluation.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2016/07/unresolved-us-balance-of-payments.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2016/01/weakening-equities-and-dollar.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/09/monetary-policy-designed-on-measurable.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/03/irrational-exuberance-mediocre-cyclical.html and earlier (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/12/patience-on-interest-rate-increases.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/09/world-inflation-waves-squeeze-of.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/08/monetary-policy-world-inflation-waves.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/02/theory-and-reality-of-cyclical-slow.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/09/duration-dumping-and-peaking-valuations.html and earlier at http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/02/united-states-unsustainable-fiscal.html).
The Chair of the Federal Reserve Board, Jerome H. Powell, at the 61st Annual Meeting on the National Association for Business Economics, on Oct 28, 2019, in Denver, Colorado, stated (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/powell20191008a.htm): “Reserve balances are one among several items on the liability side of the Federal Reserve's balance sheet, and demand for these liabilities—notably, currency in circulation—grows over time. Hence, increasing the supply of reserves or even maintaining a given level over time requires us to increase the size of our balance sheet. As we indicated in our March statement on balance sheet normalization, at some point, we will begin increasing our securities holdings to maintain an appropriate level of reserves.18 That time is now upon us.
I want to emphasize that growth of our balance sheet for reserve management purposes should in no way be confused with the large-scale asset purchase programs that we deployed after the financial crisis. Neither the recent technical issues nor the purchases of Treasury bills we are contemplating to resolve them should materially affect the stance of monetary policy, to which I now turn.” On October 25, 2017, at the beginning of the FOMC programmed reduction of the balance sheet, Total Assets of Federal Reserve Banks stood at $4,461,117 million. Total Assets increased $2,547,923 million from $4,461,117 on Oct 25, 2017 to $7,009,040 on Jul 1, 2020. Total Assets of Federal Reserve Banks increased from $3,981,420 million on Feb 20, 2019 to $7,009,040 million on Jul 1, 2020, by $3,027,620 million or 76.0 percent. The policy of reducing the fed funds policy rate requires increasing the balance sheet. The line “Securities Held Outright” increased from $4,019,823 million on Oct 25, 2017 to $6,126,948 on Jul 1, 2020 or $2,107,125 million. Securities Held Outright increased from $3,617,939 million on Jul 1, 2019 to $6,126,948 on Jul 1, 2020 by $2,509,009 million or 69.3 percent. The portfolio of long-term securities (“securities held outright”) for monetary policy consists primarily of $5764 billion, or $5.8 trillion, of which $3,581 billion Treasury nominal notes and bonds, $270 billion of notes and bonds inflation-indexed, $2 billion Federal agency debt securities and $1911 billion mortgage-backed securities ($1,911,381 million). Reserve balances deposited with Federal Reserve Banks reached $2863 billion ($2,863,196 million) or $2.9 trillion (https://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h41/current/h41.htm#h41tab1). The rounded values of $1649 billion of reserves deposited at Federal Reserve Banks and mortgage-backed securities are identical on Dec 19, 2018, by pure coincidence. There is no simple exit of this trap created by the highest monetary policy accommodation in US history together with the highest deficits and debt in percent of GDP since World War II. Risk aversion from various sources, discussed in section III World Financial Turbulence, has been affecting financial markets for several months. The risk is that in a reversal of exposures because of increasing risk aversion that has been typical in this cyclical expansion of the economy yields of Treasury securities may back up sharply.
Table VI-7, Yield, Price and Percentage Change to November 4, 2010 of Ten-Year Treasury Note
Date | Yield | Price | ∆% 11/04/10 |
05/01/01 | 5.510 | 78.0582 | -22.9 |
06/10/03 | 3.112 | 95.8452 | -5.3 |
06/12/07 | 5.297 | 79.4747 | -21.5 |
12/19/08 | 2.213 | 104.4981 | 3.2 |
12/31/08 | 2.240 | 103.4295 | 2.1 |
03/19/09 | 2.605 | 100.1748 | -1.1 |
06/09/09 | 3.862 | 89.8257 | -11.3 |
10/07/09 | 3.182 | 95.2643 | -5.9 |
11/27/09 | 3.197 | 95.1403 | -6.0 |
12/31/09 | 3.835 | 90.0347 | -11.1 |
02/09/10 | 3.646 | 91.5239 | -9.6 |
03/04/10 | 3.605 | 91.8384 | -9.3 |
04/05/10 | 3.986 | 88.8726 | -12.2 |
08/31/10 | 2.473 | 101.3338 | 0.08 |
10/07/10 | 2.385 | 102.1224 | 0.8 |
10/28/10 | 2.658 | 99.7119 | -1.5 |
11/04/10 | 2.481 | 101.2573 | - |
11/15/10 | 2.964 | 97.0867 | -4.1 |
11/26/10 | 2.869 | 97.8932 | -3.3 |
12/03/10 | 3.007 | 96.7241 | -4.5 |
12/10/10 | 3.324 | 94.0982 | -7.1 |
12/15/10 | 3.517 | 92.5427 | -8.6 |
12/17/10 | 3.338 | 93.9842 | -7.2 |
12/23/10 | 3.397 | 93.5051 | -7.7 |
12/31/10 | 3.228 | 94.3923 | -6.7 |
01/07/11 | 3.322 | 94.1146 | -7.1 |
01/14/11 | 3.323 | 94.1064 | -7.1 |
01/21/11 | 3.414 | 93.4687 | -7.7 |
01/28/11 | 3.323 | 94.1064 | -7.1 |
02/04/11 | 3.640 | 91.750 | -9.4 |
02/11/11 | 3.643 | 91.5319 | -9.6 |
02/18/11 | 3.582 | 92.0157 | -9.1 |
02/25/11 | 3.414 | 93.3676 | -7.8 |
03/04/11 | 3.494 | 92.7235 | -8.4 |
03/11/11 | 3.401 | 93.4727 | -7.7 |
03/18/11 | 3.273 | 94.5115 | -6.7 |
03/25/11 | 3.435 | 93.1935 | -7.9 |
04/01/11 | 3.445 | 93.1129 | -8.0 |
04/08/11 | 3.576 | 92.0635 | -9.1 |
04/15/11 | 3.411 | 93.3874 | -7.8 |
04/22/11 | 3.402 | 93.4646 | -7.7 |
04/29/11 | 3.290 | 94.3759 | -6.8 |
05/06/11 | 3.147 | 95.5542 | -5.6 |
05/13/11 | 3.173 | 95.3387 | -5.8 |
05/20/11 | 3.146 | 95.5625 | -5.6 |
05/27/11 | 3.068 | 96.2089 | -4.9 |
06/03/11 | 2.990 | 96.8672 | -4.3 |
06/10/11 | 2.973 | 97.0106 | -4.2 |
06/17/11 | 2.937 | 97.3134 | -3.9 |
06/24/11 | 2.872 | 97.8662 | -3.3 |
07/01/11 | 3.186 | 95.2281 | -5.9 |
07/08/11 | 3.022 | 96.5957 | -4.6 |
07/15/11 | 2.905 | 97.5851 | -3.6 |
07/22/11 | 2.964 | 97.0847 | -4.1 |
07/29/11 | 2.795 | 98.5258 | -2.7 |
08/05/11 | 2.566 | 100.5175 | -0.7 |
08/12/11 | 2.249 | 103.3504 | 2.1 |
08/19/11 | 2.066 | 105.270 | 3.7 |
08/26/11 | 2.202 | 103.7781 | 2.5 |
09/02/11 | 1.992 | 105.7137 | 4.4 |
09/09/11 | 1.918 | 106.4055 | 5.1 |
09/16/11 | 2.053 | 101.5434 | 0.3 |
09/23/11 | 1.826 | 107.2727 | 5.9 |
09/30/11 | 1.912 | 106.4602 | 5.1 |
10/07/11 | 2.078 | 104.9161 | 3.6 |
10/14/11 | 2.251 | 103.3323 | 2.0 |
10/21/11 | 2.220 | 103.6141 | 2.3 |
10/28/11 | 2.326 | 102.6540 | 1.4 |
11/04/11 | 2.066 | 105.0270 | 3.7 |
11/11/11 | 2.057 | 105.1103 | 3.8 |
11/18/11 | 2.003 | 105.6113 | 4.3 |
11/25/11 | 1.964 | 105.9749 | 4.7 |
12/02/11 | 2.042 | 105.2492 | 3.9 |
12/09/11 | 2.065 | 105.0363 | 3.7 |
12/16/11 | 1.847 | 107.0741 | 5.7 |
12/23/11 | 2.027 | 105.3883 | 4.1 |
12/30/11 | 1.871 | 106.8476 | 5.5 |
01/06/12 | 1.957 | 106.0403 | 4.7 |
01/13/12 | 1.869 | 106.8664 | 5.5 |
01/20/12 | 2.026 | 105.3976 | 4.1 |
01/27/12 | 1.893 | 106.6404 | 5.3 |
02/03/12 | 1.923 | 106.3586 | 5.0 |
02/10/12 | 1.974 | 105.8815 | 4.6 |
02/17/12 | 2.000 | 105.6392 | 4.3 |
02/24/12 | 1.977 | 105.8535 | 4.5 |
03/02/12 | 1.977 | 105.8535 | 4.5 |
03/09/12 | 2.031 | 105.3512 | 4.0 |
03/16/12 | 2.294 | 102.9428 | 1.7 |
03/23/12 | 2.234 | 103.4867 | 2.2 |
03/30/12 | 2.214 | 103.6687 | 2.4 |
04/06/12 | 2.058 | 105.1010 | 3.8 |
04/13/12 | 1.987 | 105.7603 | 4.4 |
04/20/12 | 1.959 | 106.0216 | 4.7 |
04/27/12 | 1.931 | 106.2836 | 5.0 |
05/04/12 | 1.876 | 106.8004 | 5.5 |
05/11/12 | 1.845 | 107.0930 | 5.8 |
05/18/12 | 1.714 | 108.3393 | 7.0 |
05/25/12 | 1.738 | 108.1098 | 6.8 |
06/01/12 | 1.454 | 110.8618 | 9.5 |
06/08/12 | 1.635 | 109.0989 | 7.7 |
06/15/12 | 1.584 | 109.5924 | 8.2 |
06/22/12 | 1.676 | 108.7039 | 7.4 |
06/29/12 | 1.648 | 108.9734 | 7.6 |
07/06/12 | 1.548 | 109.9423 | 8.6 |
07/13/12 | 1.49 | 110.5086 | 9.1 |
07/20/12 | 1.459 | 110.8127 | 9.4 |
07/27/12 | 1.544 | 109.9812 | 8.6 |
08/03/12 | 1.569 | 109.7380 | 8.4 |
08/10/12 | 1.658 | 108.8771 | 7.5 |
08/17/12 | 1.814 | 107.3864 | 6.1 |
08/24/12 | 1.684 | 108.6270 | 7.3 |
08/31/12 | 1.543 | 109.9910 | 8.6 |
9/7/12 | 1.668 | 108.7808 | 7.4 |
9/14/12 | 1.863 | 106.9230 | 5.6 |
9/21/12 | 1.753 | 107.9666 | 6.6 |
9/28/12 | 1.631 | 109.1375 | 7.8 |
10/05/12 | 1.737 | 108.1193 | 6.8 |
10/12/12 | 1.663 | 108.8290 | 7.5 |
10/19/12 | 1.766 | 107.8426 | 6.5 |
10/26/12 | 1.748 | 108.0143 | 6.7 |
11/02/12 | 1.715 | 108.3297 | 7.0 |
11/09/12 | 1.614 | 109.3018 | 7.9 |
11/16/12 | 1.584 | 109.5924 | 8.2 |
11/23/12 | 1.691 | 108.5598 | 7.2 |
11/30/12 | 1.612 | 109.3211 | 7.9 |
12/7/12 | 1.625 | 109.1954 | 7.8 |
12/14/12 | 1.704 | 108.4351 | 7.1 |
12/21/12 | 1.770 | 107.8045 | 6.5 |
12/28/12 | 1.699 | 108.4831 | 7.1 |
1/4/13 | 1.898 | 106.5934 | 5.3 |
1/11/13 | 1.862 | 106.9324 | 5.6 |
1/18/13 | 1.840 | 107.1403 | 5.8 |
1/25/13 | 1.947 | 106.1338 | 4.8 |
2/1/13 | 2.024 | 105.4161 | 4.1 |
2/8/13 | 1.949 | 106.1151 | 4.8 |
2/15/13 | 2.007 | 105.5741 | 4.3 |
2/22/13 | 1.967 | 105.9469 | 4.6 |
3/1/13 | 1.842 | 107.1213 | 5.8 |
3/8/13 | 2.056 | 105.1195 | 3.8 |
3/15/13 | 1.992 | 105.7137 | 4.4 |
03/22/13 | 1.931 | 106.2836 | 5.0 |
03/29/13 | 1.847 | 107.0741 | 5.7 |
04/05/13 | 1.706 | 108.4160 | 7.1 |
04/12/13 | 1.719 | 108.2914 | 6.9 |
04/19/13 | 1.702 | 108.4543 | 7.1 |
04/26/13 | 1.663 | 108.8290 | 7.5 |
05/3/13 | 1.742 | 108.2436 | 6.9 |
05/10/13 | 1.896 | 106.6122 | 5.3 |
05/17/13 | 1.952 | 106.0870 | 4.8 |
05/24/13 | 2.009 | 105.5555 | 4.2 |
05/31/13 | 2.132 | 104.5015 | 3.2 |
06/07/13 | 2.174 | 104.0338 | 2.7 |
06/14/13 | 2.125 | 104.4831 | 3.2 |
06/21/13 | 2.542 | 100.7288 | -0.5 |
06/28/13 | 2.486 | 101.2240 | 0.0 |
07/5/13 | 2.734 | 99.0519 | -2.2 |
07/12/13 | 2.585 | 100.3505 | -0.9 |
07/19/13 | 2.480 | 101.2772 | 0.0 |
07/26/13 | 2.565 | 100.5263 | -0.7 |
08/2/13 | 2.597 | 100.2452 | -1.0 |
8/9/13 | 2.579 | 100.4032 | -0.8 |
8/16/13 | 2.829 | 98.2339 | -3.0 |
8/23/13 | 2.818 | 98.3283 | -2.9 |
8/30/13 | 2.784 | 98.6205 | -2.6 |
9/6/13 | 2.941 | 97.2795 | -3.9 |
9/13/13 | 2.890 | 97.7128 | -3.5 |
9/20/13 | 2.734 | 99.0519 | -2.2 |
9/27/13 | 2.626 | 99.9913 | -1.3 |
10/4/13 | 2.645 | 99.8253 | -1.4 |
10/11/13 | 2.688 | 99.4508 | -1.8 |
10/18/13 | 2.588 | 100.3242 | -0.9 |
10/25/13 | 2.507 | 101.0380 | -0.2 |
11/1/13 | 2.622 | 100.0262 | -1.2 |
11/8/13 | 2.750 | 98.9136 | -2.3 |
11/15/13 | 2.704 | 99.3118 | -1.9 |
11/22/13 | 2.746 | 98.9482 | -2.3 |
11/29/13 | 2.743 | 98.9741 | -2.3 |
12/6/13 | 2.858 | 97.9858 | -3.2 |
12/13/13 | 2.865 | 97.9260 | -3.3 |
12/20/13 | 2.891 | 97.7043 | -3.5 |
12/27/13 | 3.004 | 96.7472 | -4.5 |
1/3/2014 | 2.999 | 96.7893 | -4.4 |
1/10/14 | 2.858 | 97.9858 | -3.2 |
1/17/14 | 2.818 | 98.3283 | -2.9 |
1/24/14 | 2.720 | 99.1731 | -2.1 |
1/31/14 | 2.645 | 99.8253 | -1.4 |
2/7/14 | 2.681 | 99.5116 | -1.7 |
2/14/14 | 2.743 | 98.9741 | -2.3 |
2/21/14 | 2.730 | 99.0865 | -2.1 |
2/28/14 | 2.655 | 99.7380 | -1.5 |
3/7/14 | 2.792 | 98.5516 | -2.7 |
3/14/14 | 2.654 | 99.7468 | -1.5 |
3/21/14 | 2.743 | 98.9741 | -2.3 |
3/28/14 | 2.721 | 99.1645 | -2.1 |
4/4/14 | 2.724 | 99.1385 | -2.1 |
4/11/14 | 2.628 | 99.9738 | -1.3 |
4/18/14 | 2.724 | 99.1385 | -2.1 |
4/25/14 | 2.668 | 99.6248 | -1.6 |
5/2/14 | 2.583 | 100.3681 | -0.9 |
5/9/14 | 2.624 | 100.0088 | -1.2 |
5/16/14 | 2.520 | 100.9320 | -0.3 |
5/23/14 | 2.532 | 100.8171 | -0.4 |
5/30/14 | 2.473 | 101.3394 | 0.1 |
6/6/2014 | 2.598 | 100.2364 | -1.0 |
6/13/14 | 2.605 | 100.1751 | -1.1 |
6/20/14 | 2.609 | 00.1400 | -1.1 |
6/27/14 | 2.536 | 100.7818 | -0.05 |
7/4/14 | 2.641 | 99.8602 | -1.4 |
7/11/14 | 2.516 | 100.9584 | -0.3 |
7/18/14 | 2.484 | 101.2417 | 0.0 |
7/25/14 | 2.464 | 101.4193 | 0.2 |
8/1/14 | 2.497 | 101.1265 | -0.1 |
8/8/14 | 2.420 | 101.8111 | 0.5 |
8/15/14 | 2.341 | 102.5190 | 1.2 |
8/22/14 | 2.399 | 101.9988 | 0.7 |
8/29/14 | 2.342 | 102.5100 | 1.2 |
9/5/14 | 2.457 | 101.4815 | 0.2 |
9/12/14 | 2.606 | 10.1663 | -1.1 |
9/19/14 | 2.576 | 100.4296 | -0.8 |
9/26/14 | 2.527 | 100.8612 | -0.4 |
10/03/14 | 2.437 | 101.6595 | 0.4 |
10/10/14 | 2.292 | 102.9609 | 1.7 |
10/17/14 | 2.197 | 103.8237 | 2.5 |
10/24/14 | 2.263 | 103.2234 | 1.9 |
10/31/14 | 2.332 | 102.6000 | 1.3 |
11/07/14 | 2.302 | 102.8705 | 1.6 |
11/14/14 | 2.319 | 102.7171 | 1.4 |
11/21/14 | 2.307 | 102.8254 | 1.5 |
11/28/14 | 2.165 | 104.1162 | 2.8 |
12/5/14 | 2.306 | 102.8344 | 1.6 |
12/12/14 | 2.086 | 104.8423 | 3.5 |
12/19/14 | 2.185 | 103.9333 | 2.6 |
12/26/14 | 2.248 | 103.3595 | 2.1 |
01/02/15 | 2.126 | 104.4739 | 3.2 |
01/09/15 | 1.973 | 105.8909 | 4.6 |
01/16/15 | 1.826 | 107.2727 | 5.9 |
01/23/15 | 1.804 | 107.4813 | 6.1 |
01/30/15 | 1.683 | 108.6367 | 7.3 |
02/06/15 | 1.941 | 106.1899 | 4.9 |
02/13/15 | 2.043 | 105.2399 | 3.9 |
02/20/15 | 2.119 | 104.5383 | 3.2 |
02/27/15 | 2.016 | 105.4905 | 4.2 |
03/06/15 | 2.238 | 103.4503 | 2.2 |
03/13/15 | 2.103 | 104.6856 | 3.4 |
03/20/15 | 1.927 | 106.3211 | 5.0 |
03/27/15 | 1.951 | 106.0964 | 4.8 |
04/02/15 | 1.911 | 106.4712 | 5.1 |
04/10/15 | 1.950 | 106.1057 | 4.8 |
04/17/15 | 1.864 | 106.9136 | 5.6 |
04/24/15 | 1.917 | 106.4149 | 5.1 |
05/01/15 | 2.118 | 104.5475 | 3.2 |
05/08/15 | 2.153 | 104.2261 | 2.9 |
05/15/15 | 2.136 | 104.3821 | 3.1 |
05/22/15 | 2.211 | 103.6961 | 2.4 |
05/29/15 | 2.092 | 104.7869 | 3.5 |
06/05/15 | 2.400 | 101.9898 | 0.7 |
06/12/15 | 2.388 | 102.0972 | 0.8 |
06/19/15 | 2.270 | 103.1599 | 1.9 |
06/26/15 | 2.473 | 101.3394 | 0.1 |
07/03/15 | 2.383 | 102.1420 | 0.9 |
07/10/15 | 2.414 | 101.8647 | 0.6 |
07/17/15 | 2.346 | 102.4740 | 1.2 |
07/24/15 | 2.268 | 103.1781 | 1.9 |
07/31/15 | 2.207 | 103.7325 | 2.4 |
08/07/15 | 2.164 | 104.1254 | 2.8 |
08/14/15 | 2.196 | 103.8328 | 2.5 |
08/21/15 | 2.052 | 105.1565 | 3.9 |
08/28/15 | 2.182 | 103.9607 | 2.7 |
09/04/15 | 2.127 | 104.4647 | 3.2 |
09/11/15 | 2.181 | 103.9698 | 2.7 |
09/18/15 | 2.131 | 104.4280 | 3.1 |
09/25/15 | 2.168 | 104.0887 | 2.8 |
10/02/15 | 1.988 | 105.7510 | 4.4 |
10/09/15 | 2.096 | 104.7501 | 3.4 |
10/16/15 | 2.024 | 105.4161 | 4.1 |
10/23/15 | 2.083 | 104.8700 | 3.6 |
10/30/15 | 2.150 | 104.2536 | 3.0 |
11/06/15 | 2.332 | 102.6000 | 1.3 |
11/13/15 | 2.278 | 103.0875 | 1.8 |
11/20/15 | 2.260 | 103.2506 | 2.0 |
11/27/15 | 2.223 | 103.5868 | 2.3 |
12/04/15 | 2.276 | 103.1056 | 1.8 |
12/11/15 | 2.134 | 104.4004 | 3.1 |
12/18/15 | 2.197 | 103.8237 | 2.5 |
12/25/15 | 2.242 | 103.4140 | 2.1 |
01/01/16 | 2.269 | 103.1690 | 1.9 |
01/08/16 | 2.135 | 104.3913 | 3.1 |
01/15/16 | 2.036 | 105.3048 | 4.0 |
01/22/15 | 2.048 | 105.1936 | 3.9 |
01/29/16 | 1.923 | 106.3586 | 5.0 |
02/05/16 | 1.848 | 107.0646 | 5.7 |
02/12/16 | 1.744 | 108.0525 | 6.7 |
02/19/16 | 1.748 | 108.0143 | 6.7 |
02/26/16 | 1.766 | 107.8426 | 6.5 |
03/04/16 | 1.884 | 106.7251 | 5.4 |
03/11/16 | 1.977 | 105.8535 | 4.5 |
03/18/16 | 1.871 | 106.8476 | 5.5 |
03/25/16 | 1.900 | 106.5746 | 5.3 |
04/01/16 | 1.795 | 107.5667 | 6.2 |
04/08/16 | 1.722 | 108.2627 | 6.9 |
04/15/16 | 1.752 | 107.9761 | 6.6 |
04/22/16 | 1.886 | 106.7063 | 5.4 |
04/29/16 | 1.820 | 107.3296 | 6.0 |
05/06/16 | 1.780 | 107.7094 | 6.4 |
05/13/16 | 1.706 | 108.4160 | 7.1 |
05/20/16 | 1.849 | 107.0552 | 5.7 |
05/27/16 | 1.851 | 107.0363 | 5.7 |
06/03/16 | 1.704 | 108.4351 | 7.1 |
06/10/16 | 1.638 | 109.0699 | 7.7 |
06/17/16 | 1.618 | 109.2631 | 7.9 |
06/24/16 | 1.575 | 109.6797 | 8.3 |
07/01/16 | 1.443 | 110.9700 | 9.6 |
07/08/16 | 1.366 | 111.7306 | 10.3 |
07/15/16 | 1.595 | 109.4857 | 8.1 |
07/22/16 | 1.567 | 109.7575 | 8.4 |
07/29/16 | 1.458 | 110.8225 | 9.4 |
08/05/16 | 1.583 | 109.6021 | 8.2 |
08/12/16 | 1.514 | 110.2739 | 8.9 |
08/19/16 | 1.580 | 109.6312 | 8.3 |
08/26/16 | 1.635 | 109.0989 | 7.7 |
09/02/16 | 1.597 | 109.4663 | 8.1 |
09/09/16 | 1.675 | 108.7135 | 7.4 |
09/16/16 | 1.699 | 108.4831 | 7.1 |
09/23/16 | 1.614 | 109.3018 | 7.9 |
09/30/16 | 1.602 | 109.4179 | 8.1 |
10/07/16 | 1.732 | 108.1671 | 6.8 |
10/14/16 | 1.791 | 107.6048 | 6.3 |
10/21/16 | 1.738 | 108.1098 | 6.8 |
10/28/16 | 1.843 | 107.1119 | 5.8 |
11/04/16 | 1.784 | 107.6173 | 6.3 |
11/11/16 | 2.152 | 104.2353 | 2.9 |
11/18/16 | 2.340 | 102.5280 | 1.3 |
11/25/16 | 2.358 | 102.3662 | 1.1 |
12/01/16 | 2.389 | 102.0883 | 0.8 |
12/09/16 | 2.466 | 101.4015 | 0.1 |
12/16/16 | 2.597 | 100.2452 | -1.0 |
12/23/16 | 2.542 | 100.7289 | -0.5 |
12/30/16 | 2.447 | 101.5705 | 0.3 |
01/06/17 | 2.416 | 101.8469 | 0.6 |
01/13/17 | 2.381 | 102.1599 | 0.9 |
01/20/17 | 2.466 | 101.4015 | 0.1 |
01/27/17 | 2.479 | 101.2861 | 0.0 |
02/03/17 | 2.488 | 101.2063 | -0.1 |
02/10/17 | 2.408 | 101.9183 | 0.7 |
02/17/17 | 2.425 | 101.7665 | 0.5 |
02/24/17 | 2.314 | 102.7622 | 1.5 |
03/03/17 | 2.492 | 101.1708 | -0.1 |
03/10/17 | 2.584 | 100.3593 | -0.9 |
03/17/17 | 2.502 | 101.0823 | -0.2 |
03/24/17 | 2.399 | 101.9888 | 0.7 |
03/31/17 | 2.396 | 102.0256 | 0.8 |
04/07/17 | 2.373 | 102.2316 | 1.0 |
04/14/17 | 2.234 | 103.4867 | 2.2 |
04/21/17 | 2.233 | 103.4958 | 2.2 |
04/28/17 | 2.286 | 103.0151 | 1.7 |
05/05/17 | 2.352 | 102.4201 | 1.1 |
05/12/17 | 2.333 | 102.5910 | 1.3 |
05/19/17 | 2.243 | 103.4049 | 2.1 |
05/26/17 | 2.247 | 103.3686 | 2.1 |
06/02/17 | 2.161 | 104.1528 | 2.9 |
06/09/17 | 2.199 | 103.8055 | 2.5 |
06/16/17 | 2.154 | 104.2170 | 2.9 |
06/23/17 | 2.144 | 104.3087 | 3.0 |
06/30/17 | 2.304 | 102.8525 | 1.6 |
07/07/17 | 2.393 | 102.0524 | 0.8 |
07/14/17 | 2.323 | 102.6811 | 1.4 |
07/21/17 | 2.233 | 103.4985 | 2.2 |
07/28/17 | 2.288 | 102.9970 | 1.7 |
08/04/17 | 2.268 | 103.1781 | 1.9 |
08/11/17 | 2.189 | 103.8968 | 2.6 |
08/18/17 | 2.196 | 103.8328 | 2.5 |
08/25/17 | 2.171 | 104.0613 | 2.8 |
09/01/17 | 2.157 | 101.2573 | 2.9 |
09/08/17 | 2.061 | 105.0733 | 3.8 |
09/15/17 | 2.201 | 103.7872 | 2.5 |
09/22/17 | 2.263 | 103.2234 | 1.9 |
09/29/17 | 2.327 | 102.6450 | 1.4 |
10/06/17 | 2.368 | 102.2765 | 1.0 |
10/13/17 | 2.278 | 103.0875 | 1.8 |
10/20/17 | 2.379 | 102.1778 | 0.9 |
10/27/17 | 2.423 | 101.7844 | 0.5 |
11/03/17 | 2.343 | 102.5010 | 1.2 |
11/10/17 | 2.404 | 101.9541 | 0.7 |
11/17/17 | 2.354 | 102.4021 | 1.1 |
11/24/17 | 3.343 | 102.5010 | 1.2 |
12/01/17 | 2.361 | 102.3393 | 1.1 |
12/08/17 | 2.383 | 102.1420 | 0.9 |
12/15/17 | 2.355 | 102.3932 | 1.1 |
12/22/17 | 2.487 | 101.2151 | 0.0 |
12/29/17 | 2.411 | 101.8915 | 0.6 |
01/05/18 | 2.475 | 101.3216 | 0.1 |
01/12/18 | 2.550 | 100.6583 | -0.6 |
01/19/18 | 2.638 | 99.8864 | -1.4 |
01/26/18 | 2.661 | 99.6857 | -1.6 |
02/02/18 | 2.848 | 98.0713 | -3.1 |
02/09/18 | 2.830 | 98.2254 | -3.0 |
02/16/18 | 2.877 | 97.8236 | -3.4 |
02/23/18 | 2.870 | 97.8833 | -3.3 |
03/02/18 | 2.855 | 98.0114 | -3.2 |
03/09/18 | 2.893 | 97.6872 | -3.5 |
03/16/18 | 2.845 | 98.0969 | -3.1 |
03/23/18 | 2.826 | 98.2597 | -3.0 |
03/30/18 | 2.739 | 99.0087 | -2.2 |
04/06/18 | 2.778 | 98.6721 | -2.6 |
04/13/18 | 2.825 | 98.2682 | -3.0 |
04/20/18 | 2.953 | 97.1778 | -4.0 |
04/27/18 | 2.955 | 97.1609 | -4.1 |
05/04/18 | 2.943 | 97.2625 | -3.9 |
05/11/18 | 2.970 | 97.0340 | -4.2 |
05/18/18 | 3.065 | 96.2350 | -5.0 |
05/25/18 | 2.928 | 97.3897 | -3.8 |
06/01/18 | 2.889 | 97.7213 | -3.5 |
06/08/18 | 2.938 | 97.3049 | -3.9 |
06/15/18 | 2.922 | 97.4406 | -3.8 |
06/22/18 | 2.902 | 97.6106 | -3.6 |
06/29/18 | 2.850 | 98.0542 | -3.2 |
07/06/18 | 2.821 | 98.3025 | -2.9 |
07/13/18 | 2.830 | 98.2254 | -3.0 |
07/20/18 | 2.890 | 97.7128 | -3.5 |
07/27/18 | 2.959 | 97.1270 | -4.1 |
08/03/18 | 2.952 | 97.1863 | -4.0 |
08/10/18 | 2.859 | 97.9772 | -3.2 |
08/17/18 | 2.870 | 97.8833 | -3.3 |
08/24/18 | 2.823 | 98.2854 | -2.9 |
08/31/18 | 2.850 | 98.0542 | -3.2 |
09/07/18 | 2.936 | 97.3218 | -3.9 |
08/14/18 | 2.987 | 96.8905 | -4.3 |
09/21/18 | 3.067 | 96.2182 | -5.0 |
09/28/18 | 3.055 | 96.3187 | -4.9 |
10/05/18 | 3.231 | 94.8567 | -6.3 |
10/12/18 | 3.137 | 95.6344 | -5.6 |
10/19/18 | 3.198 | 95.1289 | -6.1 |
10/26/18 | 3.077 | 96.1346 | -5.1 |
11/02/18 | 3.216 | 94.9803 | -6.2 |
11/09/18 | 3.188 | 95.2115 | -6.0 |
11/16/18 | 3.075 | 96.1513 | -5.0 |
11/23/18 | 3.039 | 96.4529 | -4.7 |
11/30/18 | 3.014 | 96.6630 | -4.5 |
12/07/18 | 2.848 | 98.0713 | -3.1 |
12/14/18 | 2.892 | 97.6957 | -3.5 |
12/21/18 | 2.791 | 98.5602 | -2.7 |
12/28/18 | 2.736 | 99.0346 | -2.2 |
01/04/19 | 2.568 | 99.7119 | -1.5 |
01/11/19 | 2.700 | 99.3466 | -1.9 |
01/18/19 | 2.780 | 98.6549 | -2.6 |
01/25/19 | 2.750 | 98.9136 | -2.3 |
02/01/19 | 2.691 | 99.4247 | -1.8 |
02/08/19 | 2.636 | 99.039 | -1.3 |
02/15/19 | 2.667 | 99.6335 | -1.6 |
02/22/19 | 2.652 | 99.7642 | -1.5 |
03/01/19 | 2.747 | 98.9395 | -2.3 |
03/08/19 | 2.630 | 99.9563 | -1.3 |
03/15/19 | 2.593 | 100.2803 | -1.0 |
03/22/19 | 2.453 | 101.5171 | 0.3 |
03/29/19 | 2.416 | 101.8469 | 0.6 |
04/05/19 | 2.503 | 101.0734 | -0.2 |
04/12/19 | 2.557 | 100.5967 | -0.7 |
04/19/19 | 2.564 | 100.5351 | -0.7 |
04/26/19 | 2.505 | 101.0557 | -0.2 |
05/03/19 | 2.526 | 100.8700 | -0.4 |
05/10/19 | 2.457 | 101.4815 | 0.2 |
05/17/19 | 2.398 | 102.0077 | 0.7 |
05/24/19 | 2.323 | 102.6811 | 1.4 |
05/31/19 | 2.141 | 104.3362 | 3.0 |
06/07/19 | 2.082 | 104.8792 | 3.6 |
06/14/19 | 2.095 | 104.7593 | 3.5 |
06/21/19 | 2.062 | 105.0640 | 3.8 |
06/28/19 | 2.006 | 105.5834 | 4.3 |
07/05/19 | 2.045 | 105.2214 | 3.9 |
07/12/19 | 2.107 | 104.6487 | 3.3 |
07/19/19 | 2.049 | 105.1843 | 3.9 |
07/26/19 | 2.080 | 104.8977 | 3.6 |
08/02/19 | 1.860 | 106.9513 | 5.6 |
08/09/19 | 1.736 | 108.1289 | 6.8 |
08/16/19 | 1.540 | 110.0202 | 8.7 |
08/23/19 | 1.526 | 110.1567 | 8.8 |
08/30/19 | 1.504 | 110.3716 | 9.0 |
09/06/19 | 1.554 | 109.8839 | 8.5 |
09/13/19 | 1.894 | 106.6310 | 5.3 |
09/20/19 | 1.754 | 107.9570 | 6.6 |
09/27/19 | 1.676 | 108.7039 | 7.4 |
10/04/19 | 1.515 | 110.2641 | 8.9 |
10/11/19 | 1.753 | 107.9666 | 6.6 |
10/18/19 | 1.749 | 108.0047 | 6.7 |
10/25/19 | 1.800 | 107.5193 | 6.2 |
11/01/19 | 1.716 | 108.3202 | 7.0 |
11/08/19 | 1.929 | 106.3024 | 5.0 |
11/15/19 | 1.835 | 107.1876 | 5.9 |
11/22/19 | 1.773 | 107.7760 | 6.4 |
11/29/19 | 1.782 | 107.6903 | 6.4 |
12/06/19 | 1.838 | 107.1592 | 5.8 |
12/13/19 | 1.820 | 107.3296 | 6.0 |
12/20/19 | 1.915 | 106.4337 | 5.1 |
12/27/19 | 1.869 | 106.8664 | 5.5 |
01/03/20 | 1.791 | 107.6048 | 6.3 |
01/10/20 | 1.826 | 107.2727 | 5.9 |
01/17/20 | 1.836 | 107.1781 | 5.8 |
01/24/20 | 1.678 | 108.6847 | 9.3 |
01/31/20 | 1.521 | 110.2055 | 8.8 |
02/07/20 | 1.579 | 109.6409 | 8.3 |
02/14/20 | 1.587 | 109.5633 | 8.2 |
02/21/20 | 1.473 | 110.6753 | 9.3 |
02/28/20 | 1.148 | 113.9161 | 12.5 |
03/06/20 | 0.709 | 118.4650 | 17.0 |
03/13/20 | 0.955 | 115.8912 | 14.5 |
03/20/20 | 0.949 | 115.9533 | 14.5 |
03/27/20 | 0.731 | 118.2322 | 16.8 |
04/03/20 | 0.592 | 119.7116 | 18.2 |
04/10/20 | 0.729 | 118.2536 | 16.8 |
04/17/20 | 0.657 | 119.0192 | 17.5 |
04/20/20 | 0.598 | 119.6473 | 18.2 |
05/01/20 | 0.637 | 119.2304 | 17.7 |
05/08/20 | 0.679 | 118.7832 | 17.3 |
05/15/20 | 0.641 | 119.1877 | 17.7 |
05/22/20 | 0.661 | 118.9747 | 17.5 |
05/29/20 | 0.649 | 119.1025 | 17.6 |
06/05/20 | 0.912 | 116.3365 | 14.9 |
06/12/20 | 0.700 | 118.5604 | 17.1 |
06/19/20 | 0.686 | 118.7089 | 17.2 |
06/26/20 | 0.643 | 119.1664 | 17.7 |
07/03/20 | 0.673 | 118.8470 | 17.4 |
Note: price is calculated for an artificial 10-year note paying semi-annual coupon and maturing in ten years using the actual yields traded on the dates and the coupon of 2.625% on 11/04/10
Source:
http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/public/page/mdc_bonds.html?mod=mdc_topnav_2_3000
Table VI-7B provides the maturity distribution and average length in months of marketable interest-bearing debt held by private investors from 2007 to 2020. Total debt held by investors increased from $3635 billion in 2007 to $13,886 billion in Mar 2020 (Fiscal Year 2020) or increase by 282.0 percent. There are two concerns with the maturity distribution of US debt. (1) Growth of debt is moving total debt to the point of saturation in investors’ portfolio. In a new environment of risk appetite and nonzero fed funds rates with economic growth at historical trend of around 3 percent, yields on risk financial assets are likely to increase. Placement of new debt may require increasing interest rates in an environment of continuing placement of debt by the US Treasury without strong fiscal constraints. (2) Refinancing of maturing debt is likely to occur in an environment of higher interest rates, exerting pressure on future fiscal budgets. In Mar (fiscal year 2020), $4160 billion or 30.0 percent of outstanding debt held by investors matures in less than a year and $5690 billion or 41.0 percent of total debt matures in one to five years. Debt maturing in five years or less adds to $9,850 billion or 70.9 percent of total outstanding debt held by investors of $13,886 billion. This historical episode may be remembered as one in which the US managed its government debt with short-dated instruments during record low long-dated yields and on the verge of fiscal pressures on all interest rates. This strategy maximizes over time interest payments on government debt by taxpayers that is precisely the opposite of the objective of sound debt management and taxpayer welfare.
Table VI-7B, Maturity Distribution and Average Length in Months of Marketable Interest-Bearing Public Debt Held by Private Investors, Billions of Dollars
End of Fiscal Year or Month | 2007 | 2008 | 2009 | 2010 | 2011 | 2012 |
Total* | 3635 | 4745 | 6229 | 7676 | 7951 | 9040 |
<1 Year | 1176 | 2042 | 2605 | 2480 | 2504 | 2897 |
1-5 Years | 1310 | 1468 | 2075 | 2956 | 3085 | 3852 |
5-10 Years | 678 | 719 | 995 | 1529 | 1544 | 1488 |
10-20 Years | 292 | 352 | 351 | 341 | 309 | 271 |
>20 Years | 178 | 163 | 204 | 371 | 510 | 533 |
Average | 58 | 49 | 49 | 57 | 60 | 55 |
End of Fiscal Year or Month | 2013 | 2014 | 2015 | 2016 | 2017 | |
Total* | 9518 | 9829 | 10379 | 11184 | 11643 | |
<1 Year | 2940 | 2932 | 2923 | 3321 | 3263 | |
1-5 Years | 4135 | 4217 | 4356 | 4478 | 4746 | |
5-10 Years | 1648 | 1814 | 2084 | 2219 | 2321 | |
10-20 Years | 231 | 223 | 184 | 168 | 152 | |
>20 Years | 565 | 644 | 832 | 998 | 1161 | |
Average | 55 | 56 | 61 | 63 | 66 | |
End of Fiscal Year or Month | 2018 | 2019 | 2020 Jan | |||
Total* | 12881 | 14225 | 13,886 | |||
<1 Year | 3794 | 4147 | 4160 | |||
1-5 Years | 5181 | 5822 | 5690 | |||
5-10 Years | 2445 | 2625 | 2437 | |||
10-20 Years | 121 | 105 | 133 | |||
>20 Years | 1339 | 1526 | 1465 | |||
Average | 65 | 65 | 65 |
*Amount Outstanding Privately Held
Source: United States Treasury. 2020 Mar. Treasury Bulletin. Washington, Dec
https://www.fiscal.treasury.gov/reports-statements/treasury-bulletin/
Table VI-7C provides additional information required for understanding the deficit/debt situation of the United States. The table is divided into four parts: Treasury budget in the 2020 fiscal year beginning on Oct 1, 2019 and ending on Sep 30, 2020; federal fiscal data for the years from 2009 to 2019; federal fiscal data for the years from 2005 to 2008; and Treasury debt held by the public from 2005 to 2019. Receipts decreased 11.2 percent in the cumulative fiscal year 2020 ending in May 2020 relative to the cumulative in fiscal year 2019. Individual income taxes decreased 23.1 percent relative to the same fiscal period a year earlier. Outlays increased 29.4 percent relative to a year earlier. There are also receipts, outlays, deficit and debt for fiscal years 2013, 2014, 2015, 2016, 2017, 2018 and 2019. In fiscal year 2019, the deficit reached $984.4 billion or 4.6 percent of GDP. Outlays of 4,446.6 billion were 21.0 percent of GDP and receipts of $3,462.2 billion were 16.3 percent of GDP. It is quite difficult for the US to raise receipts above 18 percent of GDP. Total revenues of the US from 2009 to 2012 accumulate to $9021.2 billion, or $9.0 trillion, while expenditures or outlays accumulate to $14,104.5 billion, or $14.1 trillion, with the deficit accumulating to $5083.3 billion, or $5.1 trillion. Revenues decreased 6.5 percent from $9652.5 billion in the four years from 2005 to 2008 to $9021.2 billion in the years from 2009 to 2012. Decreasing revenues were caused by the global recession from IVQ2007 (Dec) to IIQ2009 (Jun) and by growth of only 2.1 percent on average in the cyclical expansion from IIIQ2009 to IQ2020. In contrast, the expansion from IQ1983 to IIIQ1993 was at the average annual growth rate of 3.6 percent and at 7.9 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1983 (Section I and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/05/mediocre-cyclical-united-states_31.html). Because of mediocre GDP growth, there are 41.3 million unemployed or underemployed in the United States for an effective unemployment/underemployment rate of 23.9 percent (Section I and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/06/creation-of-three-million-private.html). Weakness of growth and employment creation is analyzed in II Collapse of United States Dynamism of Income Growth and Employment Creation (https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/05/mediocre-cyclical-united-states.html). In contrast with the decline of revenue, outlays or expenditures increased 30.1 percent from $10,838.2 billion, or $10.8 trillion, in the four years from 2005 to 2008, to $14,104.5 billion, or $14.1 trillion, in the four years from 2009 to 2012. Increase in expenditures by 30.1 percent while revenue declined by 6.5 percent caused the increase in the federal deficit from $1185.8 billion in 2005-2008 to $5083.3 billion in 2009-2012. Federal revenue was 14.8 percent of GDP on average in the years from 2009 to 2012, which is well below 17.3 percent of GDP on average from 1962 to 2019. Federal outlays were 23.3 percent of GDP on average from 2009 to 2012, which is well above 20.1 percent of GDP on average from 1962 to 2019. The lower part of Table VI-7C shows that debt held by the public swelled from $5803 billion in 2008 to $13,117 billion in 2015, by $7314 billion or 126.0 percent. Debt held by the public as percent of GDP or economic activity jumped from 39.4 percent in 2008 to 79.2 percent in 2019, which is well above the average of 41.7 percent from 1962 to 2019. The United States faces tough adjustment because growth is unlikely to recover, creating limits on what can be obtained by increasing revenues, while continuing stress of social programs restricts what can be obtained by reducing expenditures. The Congressional Budget Office (CBO) provides a preliminary estimate of the impact of Public Law 116-136 of Mar 27, 2020, CARES Act or Coronavirus Aid, Relief and Economic Security Act (https://www.cbo.gov/system/files/2020-04/hr748.pdf). This preliminary estimate finds that the CARES Act “will increase federal deficits by about $1.8 trillion over the 2020-2030 period (https://www.cbo.gov/system/files/2020-04/hr748.pdf).
Table VI-7C, US, Treasury Budget in Fiscal Year to Date Million Dollars
May 2020 | Fiscal Year 2020 | Fiscal Year 2019 | ∆% |
Receipts | 2,019,240 | 2,274,902 | -11.2 |
Outlays | 3,899,536 | 3,013,541 | 29.4 |
Deficit | -1,880,296 | -738,638 | |
Individual Income Tax | 892,477 | 1,160,328 | -23.1 |
Corporation Income Tax | 86,399 | 113,086 | -23.6 |
Social Insurance | 637,597 | 605,046 | 5.4 |
Receipts | Outlays | Deficit (-), Surplus (+) | |
$ Billions | |||
Fiscal Year 2019 | 3,462.2 | 4,446.6 | -984.4 |
% GDP | 16.3 | 21.0 | -4.6 |
Fiscal Year 2018 | 3,329.9 | 4,109.0 | -779.1 |
% GDP | 16.4 | 20.2 | -3.8 |
Fiscal Year 2017 | 3,316.2 | 3,981.6 | -665.4 |
% GDP | 17.2 | 20.6 | -3.5 |
Fiscal Year 2016 | 3,268.0 | 3,852.6 | -584.7 |
% GDP | 17.6 | 20.8 | -3.2 |
Fiscal Year 2015 | 3,249.9 | 3,691.8 | -442.0 |
% GDP | 18.0 | 20.4 | -2.4 |
Fiscal Year 2014 | 3,021.5 | 3,506.3 | -484.8 |
% GDP | 17.4 | 20.2 | -2.8 |
Fiscal Year 2013 | 2,775.1 | 3,454.9 | -679.8 |
% GDP | 16.7 | 20.8 | -4.1 |
Fiscal Year 2012 | 2,450.0 | 3,526.6 | -1,076.6 |
% GDP | 15.3 | 22.0 | -6.7 |
Fiscal Year 2011 | 2,303.5 | 3,603.1 | -1,299.6 |
% GDP | 15.0 | 23.4 | -8.4 |
Fiscal Year 2010 | 2,162.7 | 3,457.1 | -1,294.4 |
% GDP | 14.6 | 23.3 | -8.7 |
Fiscal Year 2009 | 2,105.0 | 3,517.7 | -1,412.7 |
% GDP | 14.6 | 24.4 | -9.8 |
Total 2009-2012 | 9,021.2 | 14,104.5 | -5,083.3 |
Average % GDP 2009-2012 | 14.8 | 23.3 | -8.4 |
Fiscal Year 2008 | 2,524.0 | 2,982.5 | -458.6 |
% GDP | 17.1 | 20.2 | -3.1 |
Fiscal Year 2007 | 2,568.0 | 2,728.7 | -160.7 |
% GDP | 18.0 | 19.1 | -1.1 |
Fiscal Year 2006 | 2,406.9 | 2,655.1 | -248.2 |
% GDP | 17.6 | 19.5 | -1.8 |
Fiscal Year 2005 | 2,153.6 | 2,472.0 | -318.3 |
% GDP | 16.8 | 19.3 | -2.5 |
Total 2005-2008 | 9,652.5 | 10,838.2 | -1,185.8 |
Average % GDP 2005-2008 | 17.4 | 19.5 | -2.1 |
Debt Held by the Public | Billions of Dollars | Percent of GDP | |
2005 | 4,592 | 35.8 | |
2006 | 4,829 | 35.4 | |
2007 | 5,035 | 35.2 | |
2008 | 5,803 | 39.4 | |
2009 | 7,545 | 52.3 | |
2010 | 9,019 | 60.8 | |
2011 | 10,128 | 65.8 | |
2012 | 11,281 | 70.3 | |
2013 | 11,983 | 72.2 | |
2014 | 12,780 | 73.7 | |
2015 | 13,117 | 72.5 | |
2016 | 14,168 | 76.4 | |
2017 | 14,666 | 76.0 | |
2018 | 15,750 | 77.4 | |
2019 | 16,803 | 79.2 |
Source: https://www.fiscal.treasury.gov/reports-statements/mts/
https://www.treasury.gov/press-center/press-releases/Pages/sm0184.aspx https://home.treasury.gov/news/press-releases/sm806 CBO, The budget and economic outlook: 2018 to 2028. Washington, DC, Apr 9 https://www.cbo.gov/publication/53651
CBO, The budget and economic outlook: 2017-2027. Washington, DC, Jan 24, 2017 https://www.cbo.gov/publication/52370 CBO, An update to the budget and economic outlook: 2016 to 2026. Washington, DC, Aug 23, 2016.
https://www.cbo.gov/about/products/budget-economic-data#6
CBO (2012NovMBR). CBO (2011AugBEO); Office of Management and Budget 2011. Historical Tables. Budget of the US Government Fiscal Year 2011. Washington, DC: OMB; CBO. 2011JanBEO. Budget and Economic Outlook. Washington, DC, Jan. CBO. 2012AugBEO. Budget and Economic Outlook. Washington, DC, Aug 22. CBO. 2012Jan31. Historical budget data. Washington, DC, Jan 31. CBO. 2012NovCDR. Choices for deficit reduction. Washington, DC. Nov. CBO. 2013HBDFeb5. Historical budget data—February 2013 baseline projections. Washington, DC, Congressional Budget Office, Feb 5. CBO. 2013HBDFeb5. Historical budget data—February 2013 baseline projections. Washington, DC, Congressional Budget Office, Feb 5. CBO (2013Aug12). 2013AugHBD. Historical budget data—August 2013. Washington, DC, Congressional Budget Office, Aug. CBO, Historical Budget Data—February 2014, Washington, DC, Congressional Budget Office, Feb. CBO, Historical budget data—April 2014 release. Washington, DC, Congressional Budget Office, Apr. Congressional Budget Office, August 2014 baseline: an update to the budget and economic outlook: 2014 to 2024. Washington, DC, CBO, Aug 27, 2014. CBO, Monthly budget review: summary of fiscal year 2014. Washington, DC, Congressional Budget Office, Nov 10, 2014. CBO, The budget and economic outlook: 2015 to 2025. Washington, DC, Congressional Budget Office, Jan 26, 2015.
https://www.cbo.gov/about/products/budget-economic-data#6
https://www.cbo.gov/about/products/budget_economic_data#3 https://www.cbo.gov/about/products/budget_economic_data#2
Table VI-7E, US, Congressional Budget Office, 40-Year Averages of Revenues and Outlays Before and After Update of the US National Income Accounts by the Bureau of Economic Analysis, % of GDP
Before Update | After Update | |
Revenues | ||
Individual Income Taxes | 8.2 | 7.9 |
Social Insurance Taxes | 6.2 | 6.0 |
Corporate Income Taxes | 1.9 | 1.9 |
Other | 1.6 | 1.6 |
Total Revenues | 17.9 | 17.4 |
Outlays | ||
Mandatory | 10.2 | 9.9 |
Discretionary | 8.6 | 8.4 |
Net Interest | 2.2 | 2.2 |
Total Outlays | 21.0 | 20.4 |
Deficit | -3.1 | -3.0 |
Debt Held by the Public | 39.2 | 38.0 |
Source: CBO (2013Aug12Av). Kim Kowaleski and Amber Marcellino.
Table VI-7F provides the long-term budget outlook of the CBO for 2018, 2028 and 2048. Revenues increase from 16.6 percent of GDP in 2018 to 19.8 percent in 2047. The growing stock of debt raises net interest spending from 1.6 percent of GDP in 2018 to 3.8 percent in 2028 and 6.3 percent 2048. Total spending increases from 20.6 percent of GDP in 2018 to 29.3 percent in 2048. Federal debt held by the public rises to 152.0 percent of GDP in 2048. US fiscal affairs are in an unsustainable path with tough rigidities in spending and revenues.
Table IIA1-9, Congressional Budget Office, Long-term Budget Outlook, % of GDP
2018 | 2028 | 2048 | |
Revenues | 16.6 | 18.5 | 19.8 |
Total Noninterest Spending | 19.0 | 20.6 | 23.1 |
Social Security | 4.9 | 6.0 | 6.3 |
Medicare | 2.9 | 4.2 | 5.9 |
Medicaid, CHIP and Exchange Subsidies | 2.3 | 2.5 | 3.3 |
Other | 8.9 | 7.9 | 7.6 |
Net Interest | 1.6 | 3.1 | 6.3 |
Total Spending | 20.6 | 23.6 | 29.3 |
Revenues Minus Total Noninterest Spending | -2.4 | -2.1 | -3.3 |
Revenues Minus Total Spending | -3.9 | -5.1 | -9.5 |
Federal Debt Held by the Public | 78.0 | 96.0 | 152.0 |
Source: CBO, The 2018 long-term budget outlook. Washington, DC, Jun 26, 2018 https://www.cbo.gov/publication/53919
Chart IIA1-LTB18 of the CBO illustrates the rigidity of major health care programs and social security with limited upside potential in taxes.
Chart IIA1-LTB18, The extended baseline of CBO 2018-2048,
Source: CBO, The 2018 long-term budget outlook. Washington, DC, Jun 26, 2018 https://www.cbo.gov/publication/53919
Recovery of growth rates of the US economy is critical to resolving fiscal sustainability. The revealing Chart VI-7LTBO of the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) provides alternative paths of the debt/GDP ratio according to assumptions on the growth of productivity, federal borrowing rates and rates of excess cost growth for federal spending on Medicare and Medicaid. The extended baseline projects debt/GDP of 150.0 percent in 2047. With lower rate of growth of productivity, the debt/GDP ratio would increase to 244 percent in 2047. The debt/GDP ratio would be much lower at 85 percent in 2047 with higher rate of productivity growth.
Chart VI-LTBO, Congressional Budget Office, Paths of Federal Debt under Alternative Rates of Productivity Growth, Labor Force Participation and Other Assumptions
Source: Congressional Budget Office, The 2016 long-term budget outlook. Washington, DC, Jul 12 https://www.cbo.gov/publication/51580
Table VI-7G of the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) provides the data in Chart VI-LTBO. Economy policy must focus intensively on stimulating productivity growth that would recover the high rates of economic growth of the US over the long-term.
Table VI-7G, Congressional Budget Office, Long-term Budget Outlook, % of GDP, Alternative Paths of Federal Debt According to the Rate of Productivity Growth
Given Different Labor Force Participation Rates, Productivity Growth Rates, Federal Borrowing Rates, and Rates of Excess Cost Growth for Federal Spending on Medicare and Medicaida | |||
Extended Baseline | Given Rates That Lower | Given Rates That Raise | |
2000 | 34 | ||
2001 | 31 | ||
2002 | 33 | ||
2003 | 35 | ||
2004 | 36 | ||
2005 | 36 | ||
2006 | 35 | ||
2007 | 35 | ||
2008 | 39 | ||
2009 | 52 | ||
2010 | 61 | ||
2011 | 66 | ||
2012 | 70 | ||
2013 | 73 | ||
2014 | 74 | ||
2015 | 73 | ||
2016 | 77 | ||
2017 | 77 | 77 | 77 |
2018 | 77 | 76 | 79 |
2019 | 78 | 76 | 80 |
2020 | 79 | 76 | 82 |
2021 | 80 | 76 | 84 |
2022 | 81 | 77 | 86 |
2023 | 83 | 77 | 89 |
2024 | 84 | 77 | 91 |
2025 | 85 | 77 | 94 |
2026 | 87 | 78 | 97 |
2027 | 89 | 78 | 101 |
2028 | 91 | 78 | 105 |
2029 | 93 | 79 | 108 |
2030 | 95 | 79 | 113 |
2031 | 97 | 79 | 117 |
2032 | 99 | 80 | 122 |
2033 | 102 | 80 | 127 |
2034 | 105 | 81 | 133 |
2035 | 107 | 81 | 138 |
2036 | 110 | 82 | 145 |
2037 | 113 | 82 | 151 |
2038 | 116 | 83 | 158 |
2039 | 120 | 83 | 165 |
2040 | 123 | 84 | 173 |
2041 | 127 | 84 | 182 |
2042 | 130 | 84 | 190 |
2043 | 134 | 85 | 200 |
2044 | 138 | 85 | 210 |
2045 | 142 | 85 | 220 |
2046 | 146 | 85 | 232 |
2047 | 150 | 85 | 244 |
Source: CBO, The 2017 Long-term Budget Outlook. Washington, DC, Mar 30, 2017 https://www.cbo.gov/publication/52480 https://www.cbo.gov/about/products/budget-economic-data#1
Chart VI-8 of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System provides the yield of the ten-year constant maturity Treasury and the overnight fed funds rate from Jan 2, 1962 to Jul 1, 2020. The yield of the ten-year constant maturity Treasury stood at 7.67 percent on Feb 16, 1977. A peak was reached at 15.21 percent on Oct 26, 1981 during the inflation control effort by the Fed. There is a second local peak in Chart VI-8 on May 3, 1984 at 13.94 percent followed by another local peak at 8.14 percent on Nov 21, 1994 during another inflation control effort (see Appendix I The Great Inflation). There was sharp reduction of the yields from 5.44 percent on Apr 1, 2002 until they reached a low point of 3.13 percent on Jun 13, 2003. The fed funds rate was 1.18 percent on Jun 23, 2003 and the ten-year yield 3.36 percent. Yields rose again to 4.89 percent on Jun 14, 2004 with the fed funds rate at 1.02 percent and the ten-year yield stood at 5.23 percent on Jul 5, 2006. At the onset of the financial crisis on Sep 17, 2007, the fed funds rate was 5.33 percent and the ten-year yield 4.48 percent. On Dec 26, 2008, the fed funds rate was 0.09 percent and the ten-year yield 2.16 percent. Yields declined sharply during the financial crisis, reaching 2.08 percent on Dec 18, 2008, lowered by higher prices originating in sharply increasing demand in the flight to the US dollar and obligations of the US government. Yields rose again to 4.01 percent on Apr 5, 2010 but collapsed to 2.41 percent on Oct 8, 2010 because of higher demand originating in the flight from the European sovereign risk event. During higher risk appetite, yields rose to 3.75 percent on Feb 8, 2011 and reached 0.69 percent on Jul 1, 2020 with the fed funds rate at 0.08 percent. Chart VI-8A provides the fed funds rate and the yield of the ten-year constant maturity Treasury from Jan 2, 2001 to Jul 1, 2020. The final data point for Jul 1, 2020, shows the fed funds rate at 0.08 percent and the yield of the ten-year constant maturity Treasury at 0.69 percent. There has been a trend of decline of yields with oscillations. During periods of risk aversion investors seek protection in obligations of the US government, causing decline in their yields. In an eventual resolution of international financial risks with higher economic growth, there could be the trauma of rising yields with significant capital losses in portfolios of government securities. The data in Table VI-7 in the text is obtained from closing dates in New York published by the Wall Street Journal (http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/public/page/marketsdata.html?mod=WSJ_PRO_hps_marketdata).
Chart VI-8, US, Overnight Federal Funds Rate and Ten-Year Treasury Constant Maturity Yield, Jan 2, 1962 to Jul 1, 2020
Note: US Recessions in Shaded Areas
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
https://www.federalreserve.gov/datadownload/Choose.aspx?rel=H15
Chart VI-8A provides the fed funds rate and the yield of the ten-year constant maturity Treasury from Jan 2, 2001 to Jul 1, 2020. The final data point for Jul 1, 2020, shows the fed funds rate at 0.08 percent and the yield of the ten-year constant maturity Treasury at 0.68 percent. There has been a trend of decline of yields with oscillations. During periods of risk aversion investors seek protection in obligations of the US government, causing decline in their yields. In an eventual resolution of international financial risks with higher economic growth, there could be the trauma of rising yields with significant capital losses in portfolios of government securities. The data in Table VI-7 in the text is obtained from closing dates in New York published by the Wall Street Journal (http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/public/page/marketsdata.html?mod=WSJ_PRO_hps_marketdata).
Chart VI-8A, US, Overnight Federal Funds Rate and Ten-Year Treasury Constant Maturity Yield, Jan 2, 2001 to Jul 1, 2020
Note: US Recessions in Shaded Areas
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
https://www.federalreserve.gov/datadownload/Choose.aspx?rel=H15
Chart VI-9 of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System provides securities held outright by Federal Reserve banks from 2002 to 2020. The first data point in Chart VI-9 is the level for Dec 18, 2002 of $629,407 million and the final data point in Chart VI-9 is level of $6,126,948 million on Jul 1, 2020. On October 25, 2017, at the beginning of the FOMC programmed reduction of the balance sheet, Total Assets of Federal Reserve Banks stood at $4,461,117 million. Total Assets increased $2,547,923 million from $4,461,117 on Oct 25, 2017 to $7,009,040 on Jul 1, 2020. Total Assets of Federal Reserve Banks increased from $3,981,420 million on Feb 20, 2019 to $7,009,040 million on Jul 1, 2020 by $3,027,620 million or 76.0 percent. The policy of reducing the fed funds policy rate requires increasing the balance sheet. The line “Securities Held Outright” increased from $4,019,823 million on Oct 25, 2017 to $6,126,948 on Jul 1, 2020 or $2,107,125 million. Securities Held Outright increased from $3,617,939 million on Jul 24, 2019 to $6,126,948 on Jul 1, 2020 by $2,509,009 million or 69.3 percent. The Chair of the Federal Reserve Board, Jerome H. Powell, at the 61st Annual Meeting on the National Association for Business Economics, on Oct 28, 2019, in Denver, Colorado, stated (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/powell20191008a.htm): “Reserve balances are one among several items on the liability side of the Federal Reserve's balance sheet, and demand for these liabilities—notably, currency in circulation—grows over time. Hence, increasing the supply of reserves or even maintaining a given level over time requires us to increase the size of our balance sheet. As we indicated in our March statement on balance sheet normalization, at some point, we will begin increasing our securities holdings to maintain an appropriate level of reserves.18 That time is now upon us.
I want to emphasize that growth of our balance sheet for reserve management purposes should in no way be confused with the large-scale asset purchase programs that we deployed after the financial crisis. Neither the recent technical issues nor the purchases of Treasury bills we are contemplating to resolve them should materially affect the stance of monetary policy, to which I now turn.”
Chart VI-9, US, Securities Held Outright by Federal Reserve Banks, Wednesday Level, Dec 18, 2002 to Jul 1, 2020, USD Millions
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/bst_fedsbalancesheet.htm
Chart VI-9A of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System provides Total Assets by Federal Reserve banks from 2002 to 2020 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/datadownload/Choose.aspx?rel=H41). The first data point in Chart VI-9A is the level for Dec 18, 2002 of $720,761 million and the final data point in Chart VI-9A is level of $7,009,040 million on Jul 1, 2020. On October 25, 2017, at the beginning of the FOMC programmed reduction of the balance sheet, Total Assets of Federal Reserve Banks stood at $4,461,117 million. Total Assets increased $2,547,923 million from $4,461,117 on Oct 25, 2017 to $7,009,040 on Jul 1, 2020. Total Assets of Federal Reserve Banks increased from $3,981,420 million on Feb 20, 2019 to $7,009,040 million on Jul 1, 2020, by $3,027,620 million or 76.0 percent. The policy of reducing the fed funds policy rate requires increasing the balance sheet. The Chair of the Federal Reserve Board, Jerome H. Powell, at the 61st Annual Meeting on the National Association for Business Economics, on Oct 28, 2019, in Denver, Colorado, stated (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/powell20191008a.htm): “Reserve balances are one among several items on the liability side of the Federal Reserve's balance sheet, and demand for these liabilities—notably, currency in circulation—grows over time. Hence, increasing the supply of reserves or even maintaining a given level over time requires us to increase the size of our balance sheet. As we indicated in our March statement on balance sheet normalization, at some point, we will begin increasing our securities holdings to maintain an appropriate level of reserves.18 That time is now upon us.
I want to emphasize that growth of our balance sheet for reserve management purposes should in no way be confused with the large-scale asset purchase programs that we deployed after the financial crisis. Neither the recent technical issues nor the purchases of Treasury bills we are contemplating to resolve them should materially affect the stance of monetary policy, to which I now turn.”
Chart VI-9A, US, Total Assets by Federal Reserve Banks, Wednesday Level, Dec 18, 2002 to Jul 1, 2020, USD Millions
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/bst_fedsbalancesheet.htm
Chart VI-10 of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System provides the overnight Fed funds rate on business days from Jul 1, 1954 at 1.13 percent through Jan 10, 1979, at 9.91 percent per year, to Jul 1, 2020, at 0.08 percent per year. US recessions are in shaded areas according to the reference dates of the NBER (http://www.nber.org/cycles.html). In the Fed effort to control the “Great Inflation” of the 1970s (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/05/slowing-growth-global-inflation-great.html https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/04/new-economics-of-rose-garden-turned.html https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/03/is-there-second-act-of-us-great.html and Appendix I The Great Inflation; see Taylor 1993, 1997, 1998LB, 1999, 2012FP, 2012Mar27, 2012Mar28, 2012JMCB and http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2017/01/rules-versus-discretionary-authorities.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/rules-versus-discretionary-authorities.html), the fed funds rate increased from 8.34 percent on Jan 3, 1979 to a high in Chart VI-10 of 22.36 percent per year on Jul 22, 1981 with collateral adverse effects in the form of impaired savings and loans associations in the United States, emerging market debt and money-center banks (see Pelaez and Pelaez, Regulation of Banks and Finance (2009b), 72-7; Pelaez 1986, 1987). Another episode in Chart VI-10 is the increase in the fed funds rate from 3.15 percent on Jan 3, 1994, to 6.56 percent on Dec 21, 1994, which also had collateral effects in impairing emerging market debt in Mexico and Argentina and bank balance sheets in a world bust of fixed income markets during pursuit by central banks of non-existing inflation (Pelaez and Pelaez, International Financial Architecture (2005), 113-5). Another interesting policy impulse is the reduction of the fed funds rate from 7.03 percent on Jul 3, 2000, to 1.00 percent on Jun 22, 2004, in pursuit of equally non-existing deflation (Pelaez and Pelaez, International Financial Architecture (2005), 18-28, The Global Recession Risk (2007), 83-85), followed by increments of 25 basis points from Jun 2004 to Jun 2006, raising the fed funds rate to 5.25 percent on Jul 3, 2006 in Chart VI-10. Central bank commitment to maintain the fed funds rate at 1.00 percent induced adjustable-rate mortgages (ARMS) linked to the fed funds rate. Lowering the interest rate near the zero bound in 2003-2004 caused the illusion of permanent increases in wealth or net worth in the balance sheets of borrowers and also of lending institutions, securitized banking and every financial institution and investor in the world. The discipline of calculating risks and returns was seriously impaired. The objective of monetary policy was to encourage borrowing, consumption and investment but the exaggerated stimulus resulted in a financial crisis of major proportions as the securitization that had worked for a long period was shocked with policy-induced excessive risk, imprudent credit, high leverage and low liquidity by the incentive to finance everything overnight at interest rates close to zero, from adjustable rate mortgages (ARMS) to asset-backed commercial paper of structured investment vehicles (SIV).
The consequences of inflating liquidity and net worth of borrowers were a global hunt for yields to protect own investments and money under management from the zero interest rates and unattractive long-term yields of Treasuries and other securities. Monetary policy distorted the calculations of risks and returns by households, business and government by providing central bank cheap money. Short-term zero interest rates encourage financing of everything with short-dated funds, explaining the SIVs created off-balance sheet to issue short-term commercial paper with the objective of purchasing default-prone mortgages that were financed in overnight or short-dated sale and repurchase agreements (Pelaez and Pelaez, Financial Regulation after the Global Recession, 50-1, Regulation of Banks and Finance, 59-60, Globalization and the State Vol. I, 89-92, Globalization and the State Vol. II, 198-9, Government Intervention in Globalization, 62-3, International Financial Architecture, 144-9). ARMS were created to lower monthly mortgage payments by benefitting from lower short-dated reference rates. Financial institutions economized in liquidity that was penalized with near zero interest rates. There was no perception of risk because the monetary authority guaranteed a minimum or floor price of all assets by maintaining low interest rates forever or equivalent to writing an illusory put option on wealth. Subprime mortgages were part of the put on wealth by an illusory put on house prices. The housing subsidy of $221 billion per year created the impression of ever-increasing house prices. The suspension of auctions of 30-year Treasuries was designed to increase demand for mortgage-backed securities, lowering their yield, which was equivalent to lowering the costs of housing finance and refinancing. Fannie and Freddie purchased or guaranteed $1.6 trillion of nonprime mortgages and worked with leverage of 75:1 under Congress-provided charters and lax oversight. The combination of these policies resulted in high risks because of the put option on wealth by near zero interest rates, excessive leverage because of cheap rates, low liquidity because of the penalty in the form of low interest rates and unsound credit decisions because the put option on wealth by monetary policy created the illusion that nothing could ever go wrong, causing the credit/dollar crisis and global recession (Pelaez and Pelaez, Financial Regulation after the Global Recession, 157-66, Regulation of Banks, and Finance, 217-27, International Financial Architecture, 15-18, The Global Recession Risk, 221-5, Globalization and the State Vol. II, 197-213, Government Intervention in Globalization, 182-4). A final episode in Chart VI-10 is the reduction of the fed funds rate from 5.41 percent on Aug 9, 2007, to 2.97 percent on October 7, 2008, to 0.12 percent on Dec 5, 2008 and close to zero throughout a long period with the final point at 0.08 percent on Jul 1, 2020. Evidently, this behavior of policy would not have occurred had there been theory, measurements and forecasts to avoid these violent oscillations that are clearly detrimental to economic growth and prosperity without inflation. The Chair of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Janet L. Yellen, stated on Jul 10, 2015 that (http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20150710a.htm):
“Based on my outlook, I expect that it will be appropriate at some point later this year to take the first step to raise the federal funds rate and thus begin normalizing monetary policy. But I want to emphasize that the course of the economy and inflation remains highly uncertain, and unanticipated developments could delay or accelerate this first step. I currently anticipate that the appropriate pace of normalization will be gradual, and that monetary policy will need to be highly supportive of economic activity for quite some time. The projections of most of my FOMC colleagues indicate that they have similar expectations for the likely path of the federal funds rate. But, again, both the course of the economy and inflation are uncertain. If progress toward our employment and inflation goals is more rapid than expected, it may be appropriate to remove monetary policy accommodation more quickly. However, if progress toward our goals is slower than anticipated, then the Committee may move more slowly in normalizing policy.”
There is essentially the same view in the Testimony of Chair Yellen in delivering the Semiannual Monetary Policy Report to the Congress on Jul 15, 2015 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/yellen20150715a.htm). The FOMC (Federal Open Market Committee) raised the fed funds rate to ¼ to ½ percent at its meeting on Dec 16, 2015 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20151216a.htm).
It is a forecast mandate because of the lags in effect of monetary policy impulses on income and prices (Romer and Romer 2004). The intention is to reduce unemployment close to the “natural rate” (Friedman 1968, Phelps 1968) of around 5 percent and inflation at or below 2.0 percent. If forecasts were reasonably accurate, there would not be policy errors. A commonly analyzed risk of zero interest rates is the occurrence of unintended inflation that could precipitate an increase in interest rates similar to the Himalayan rise of the fed funds rate from 9.91 percent on Jan 10, 1979, at the beginning in Chart VI-10, to 22.36 percent on Jul 22, 1981. There is a less commonly analyzed risk of the development of a risk premium on Treasury securities because of the unsustainable Treasury deficit/debt of the United States (https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2018/10/global-contraction-of-valuations-of.html and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2017/04/mediocre-cyclical-economic-growth-with.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2017/01/twenty-four-million-unemployed-or.html and earlier and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2016/12/rising-yields-and-dollar-revaluation.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2016/07/unresolved-us-balance-of-payments.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2016/04/proceeding-cautiously-in-reducing.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2016/01/weakening-equities-and-dollar.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/09/monetary-policy-designed-on-measurable.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/06/fluctuating-financial-asset-valuations.html and earlier (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2015/03/irrational-exuberance-mediocre-cyclical.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/12/patience-on-interest-rate-increases.html
and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/09/world-inflation-waves-squeeze-of.html and earlier (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2014/02/theory-and-reality-of-cyclical-slow.html and earlier (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2013/02/united-states-unsustainable-fiscal.html). There is not a fiscal cliff or debt limit issue ahead but rather free fall into a fiscal abyss. The combination of the fiscal abyss with zero interest rates could trigger the risk premium on Treasury debt or Himalayan hike in interest rates.
Chart VI-10, US, Fed Funds Rate, Business Days, Jul 1, 1954 to Jul 1, 2020, Percent per Year
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
https://www.federalreserve.gov/datadownload/Choose.aspx?rel=H15
Chart VI-11 of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System provides the fed funds rate and the prime bank loan rate in business days from Aug 4, 1955 to Jul 1, 2020. The overnight fed funds rate was 2.0 percent on Aug 4, 1955 and the bank prime rate 3.25 percent. The fed funds overnight rate is the rate charged by a depository institution with idle reserves deposited at a federal reserve bank to exchange its deposits overnight to another depository institution in need of reserves. In a sense, it is the marginal cost of funding for a bank in the United States, or the cost of a unit of additional funding. The fed funds rate is the rate charged by a bank to another bank in an uncollateralized overnight loan. The fed funds rate is the traditional policy rate or rate used to implement policy directives of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC). Thus, there should be an association between the fed funds rate or cost of funding of a bank and its prime lending rate. Such an association is verified in Chart VI-11 with the rates moving quite closely over time. On January 10, 1979, the fed funds rate was set at 9.91 percent and banks set their prime lending rate at 11.75 percent. On Dec 16, 2008, the policy determining committee of the Fed decided (http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20081216b.htm): “The Federal Open Market Committee decided today to establish a target range for the federal funds rate of 0 to ¼ percent.” On Dec 14, 2016 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20161214a.htm), “the Committee decided to raise the target level for the federal funds rate to ½ to ¾ percent.” On Mar 15, 2017, “the Committee decided to raise the federal funds rate to ¾ to 1 percent (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20170315a.htm). The FOMC raised the fed funds rate to 1 to 1 ¼ percent at its meeting on Jun 14, 2017 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20170201a.htm). The FOMC increased the fed funds rate to 1¼ to 1½ percent on Dec 13, 2017 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20171213a.htm). The FOMC increased the fed funds rate to 1½ to 1¾ percent on Mar 21, 2018 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20180321a.htm). The FOMC increased the fed funds rate to 1¾ to 2.0 percent on Jun 13, 2018 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20180613a.htm). The FOMC increased the fed funds rate to 2.0 to 2¼ percent on Sep 26, 2018 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20180926a.htm). The FOMC increased the fed funds rate to 2¼ to 2½ percent on Dec 19, 2018 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20181219a.htm). The FOMC decreased the fed funds rate to 2 to 2¼ percent on Jul 31, 2019 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20190731a.htm). The FOMC decreased the fed funds rate to 1¾ to 2.0 percent on Sep 18, 2019 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20190918a.htm).
The FOMC decreased the fed funds rate to 1½ to 1¾ percent on Oct 30, 2019 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20191030a.htm). The FOMC decreased the fed funds rate to 1 to 1¼ percent on Mar 3, 2020 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20200303a.htm). The FOMC decreased the fed funds rate to 0 to ¼ percent on Mar 15, 2020 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20200315a.htm).
The final segment of Chart VI-11 shows similar movement of the fed funds rate and the prime bank loan rate following the fixing of the fed funds rate to approximately zero. In the final data point of Chart VI-11 on Jul 1, 2020, the fed funds rate is 0.08 percent and the prime rate 3.25 percent. The causes of the financial crisis and global recession were interest rate and housing subsidies and affordability policies that encouraged high leverage and risks, low liquidity and unsound credit (Pelaez and Pelaez, Financial Regulation after the Global Recession (2009a), 157-66, Regulation of Banks and Finance (2009b), 217-27, International Financial Architecture (2005), 15-18, The Global Recession Risk (2007), 221-5, Globalization and the State Vol. II (2008b), 197-213, Government Intervention in Globalization (2008c), 182-4). Several past comments of this blog elaborate on these arguments, among which: http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/07/causes-of-2007-creditdollar-crisis.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/professor-mckinnons-bubble-economy.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/world-inflation-quantitative-easing.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/treasury-yields-valuation-of-risk.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2010/11/quantitative-easing-theory-evidence-and.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2010/12/is-fed-printing-money-what-are.html Gradual unwinding of 1 percent fed funds rates from Jun 2003 to Jun 2004 by seventeen consecutive increases of 25 percentage points from Jun 2004 to Jun 2006 to reach 5.25 percent caused default of subprime mortgages and adjustable-rate mortgages linked to the overnight fed funds rate. The zero-interest rate has penalized liquidity and increased risks by inducing carry trades from zero interest rates to speculative positions in risk financial assets. There is no exit from zero interest rates without provoking another financial crash. The yields of Treasury securities inverted on Mar 22, 2019 with the ten-year yield at 2.44 percent below those of 2.49 percent for one-month, 2.48 percent for two months, 2.46 percent for three months, 2.48 percent for six months and 2.45 percent for one year (https://www.treasury.gov/resource-center/data-chart-center/interest-rates/Pages/TextView.aspx?data=yield). The final segment after 2001 shows the effects of unconventional monetary policy of extremely low, below inflation fed funds rate in lowering yields. This was an important cause of the global recession and financial crisis inducing as analyzed by Taylor (2018Oct 19, 2) “search for yield, excessive risk taking, a boom and bust in the housing market, and eventually the financial crisis and recession.” Monetary policy deviated from the Taylor Rule (Taylor 2018Oct19 see Taylor 1993, 1997, 1998LB, 1999, 2012FP, 2012Mar27, 2012Mar28, 2012JMCB, 2019Oct19 and http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2017/01/rules-versus-discretionary-authorities.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/rules-versus-discretionary-authorities.html)). An explanation is in the research of Adrian, Estrella and Shin (2018, 21-22): “Our findings suggest that the monetary tightening of 2004-2006 period ultimately did achieve a slowdown in real activity not because of its impact on the level of longer term interest rates, but rather because of its impact on the slope of the yield curve. In fact, while the level of the 10-year yield only increased 38 basis points between June 2004 and 2006, the term spread declined 325 basis points (from 3.44 to .19 percent). The fact that the slope flattened meant that intermediary profitability was compressed, thus shifting the supply of credit, and hence inducing changes in real activity. The 18 month lag between the end of the tightening cycle, and the beginning of the recession is perfectly compatible with effective monetary tightening.” See (https://www.newyorkfed.org/research/capital_markets/ycfaq.html). A major difference in the current cycle is the balance sheet of the Fed with purchases used to lower interest rates in specific segments and maturities such as mortgage-backed securities and longer terms.
Chart VI-11, US, Fed Funds Rate and Prime Bank Loan, Aug 4, 1955 to Jul 1, 2020, Percent per Year
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
https://www.federalreserve.gov/datadownload/Choose.aspx?rel=H15
Lending has become more complex over time. The critical fact of current world financial markets is the combination of “unconventional” monetary policy with intermittent shocks of financial risk aversion. There are two interrelated unconventional monetary policies. First, unconventional monetary policy consists of (1) reducing short-term policy interest rates toward the “zero bound” such as fixing the fed funds rate at 0 to ¼ percent by decision of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) since Dec 16, 2008 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20081216b.htm). Second, unconventional monetary policy also includes a battery of measures to also reduce long-term interest rates of government securities and asset-backed securities such as mortgage-backed securities. When inflation is low, the central bank lowers interest rates to stimulate aggregate demand in the economy, which consists of consumption and investment. When inflation is subdued and unemployment high, monetary policy would lower interest rates to stimulate aggregate demand, reducing unemployment. When interest rates decline to zero, unconventional monetary policy would consist of policies such as large-scale purchases of long-term securities to lower their yields. A major portion of credit in the economy is financed with long-term asset-backed securities. Loans for purchasing houses, automobiles and other consumer products are bundled in securities that in turn are sold to investors. Corporations borrow funds for investment by issuing corporate bonds. Loans to small businesses are also financed by bundling them in long-term bonds. Securities markets bridge the needs of higher returns by investors obtaining funds from savers that are channeled to consumers and business for consumption and investment. Lowering the yields of these long-term bonds could lower costs of financing purchases of consumer durables and investment by business. The essential mechanism of transmission from lower interest rates to increases in aggregate demand is portfolio rebalancing. Withdrawal of bonds in a specific maturity segment or directly in a bond category such as currently mortgage-backed securities causes reductions in yield that are equivalent to increases in the prices of the bonds. There can be secondary increases in purchases of those bonds in private portfolios in pursuit of their increasing prices. Lower yields translate into lower costs of buying homes and consumer durables such as automobiles and also lower costs of investment for business.
Monetary policy can lower short-term interest rates quite effectively. Lowering long-term yields is somewhat more difficult. The critical issue is that monetary policy cannot ensure that increasing credit at low interest cost increases consumption and investment. There is a large variety of possible allocation of funds at low interest rates from consumption and investment to multiple risk financial assets. Monetary policy does not control how investors will allocate asset categories. A critical financial practice is to borrow at low short-term interest rates to invest in high-risk, leveraged financial assets. Investors may increase in their portfolios asset categories such as equities, emerging market equities, high-yield bonds, currencies, commodity futures and options and multiple other risk financial assets including structured products. If there is risk appetite, the carry trade from zero interest rates to risk financial assets will consist of short positions at short-term interest rates (or borrowing) and short dollar assets with simultaneous long positions in high-risk, leveraged financial assets such as equities, commodities and high-yield bonds. Low interest rates may induce increases in valuations of risk financial assets that may fluctuate in accordance with perceptions of risk aversion by investors and the public. During periods of muted risk aversion, carry trades from zero interest rates to exposures in risk financial assets cause temporary waves of inflation that may foster instead of preventing financial instability (Section I and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2017/06/fomc-interest-rate-increase-planned.html and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2017/05/dollar-devaluation-world-inflation.html). During periods of risk aversion such as fears of disruption of world financial markets and the global economy resulting from collapse of the European Monetary Union, carry trades are unwound with sharp deterioration of valuations of risk financial assets. More technical discussion is in IA Appendix: Transmission of Unconventional Monetary Policy at http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/11/united-states-unsustainable-fiscal.html.
Chart VI-12 of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System provides the fed funds rate, prime bank loan rate and the yield of a corporate bond rated Baa by Moody’s. On Jan 10, 1979, the fed funds rate was fixed at 9.91 percent and banks fixed the prime loan rate at 11.75 percent. Reflecting differences in risk, the fed funds rate was 8.76 percent on Jan 2, 1986, the prime rate 9.50 percent and the Baa Corporate bond yield 11.38 percent. The yield of the Baa corporate bond collapsed toward the bank prime loan rate after the end of extreme risk aversion in the beginning of 2009. The final data point in Chart VI-12 is for Jul 7, 2016, with the fed funds rate at 0.40 percent, the bank prime rate at 3.50 percent and the yield of the Baa corporate bond at 4.19 percent. Empirical tests of the transmission of unconventional monetary policy to actual increases in consumption and investment or aggregate demand find major hurdles (see IA Appendix: Transmission of Unconventional Monetary Policy at http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/11/united-states-unsustainable-fiscal.html).
Chart VI-12, US, Fed Funds Rate, Prim Bank Loan Rate and Yield of Moody’s Baa Corporate Bond, Business Days, Aug 4, 1955 to Jul 7, 2016, Percent per Year
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
https://www.federalreserve.gov/datadownload/Choose.aspx?rel=H15
Chart VI-12A of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System provides the overnight fed funds rate and the bank prime rate on business days from Jan 5, 2007 to Jul 1, 2020. There is a jump in the rates and yield with the increase in fed funds rates target range from 0 to ½ percent to ¼ to ½ percent on Dec 16, 2015 by the Federal Open Market Committee (http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20151216a.htm), ½ to ¾ percent on Dec 14, 2016 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20161214a.htm) and ¾ to 1 percent on Mar 15, 2017 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20170315a.htm). The FOMC raised the fed funds rate to 1 to 1¼ percent at its meeting on Jun 14, 2017 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20170201a.htm). The FOMC increased the fed funds rate to 1¼ to 1½ percent on Dec 13, 2017 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20171213a.htm). The FOMC increased the fed funds rate to 1½ to 1¾ percent on Mar 21, 2018 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20180321a.htm). The FOMC increased the fed funds rate to 1¾ to 2.0 percent on Jun 13, 2018 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20180613a.htm). The FOMC increased the fed funds rate to 2.0 to 2¼ percent on Sep 26, 2018 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20180926a.htm). The FOMC increased the fed funds rate to 2¼ to 2½ percent on Dec 19, 2018 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20181219a.htm). The FOMC decreased the fed funds rate to 2 to 2¼ on Jul 31, 2019 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20190731a.htm). The FOMC decreased the fed funds rate to 1¾ to 2.0 percent on Sep 18, 2019 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20190918a.htm). The FOMC decreased the fed funds rate to 1½ to 1¾ on Oct 30, 2019 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20191030a.htm). The FOMC decreased the fed funds rate to 1 to 1¼ percent on Mar 3, 2020 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20200303a.htm). The FOMC decreased the fed funds rate to 0 to ¼ percent on Mar 15, 2020 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20200315a.htm). The final segment of Chart VI-11 shows similar movement of the fed funds rate and the prime bank loan rate following the fixing of the fed funds rate to approximately zero. In the final data point of Chart VI-12A on Jul 1, 2020, the fed funds rate is 0.08 percent and the prime rate 3.25 percent. The causes of the financial crisis and global recession were interest rate and housing subsidies and affordability policies that encouraged high leverage and risks, low liquidity and unsound credit (Pelaez and Pelaez, Financial Regulation after the Global Recession (2009a), 157-66, Regulation of Banks and Finance (2009b), 217-27, International Financial Architecture (2005), 15-18, The Global Recession Risk (2007), 221-5, Globalization and the State Vol. II (2008b), 197-213, Government Intervention in Globalization (2008c), 182-4). Several past comments of this blog elaborate on these arguments, among which: http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/07/causes-of-2007-creditdollar-crisis.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/professor-mckinnons-bubble-economy.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/world-inflation-quantitative-easing.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/treasury-yields-valuation-of-risk.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2010/11/quantitative-easing-theory-evidence-and.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2010/12/is-fed-printing-money-what-are.html Gradual unwinding of 1 percent fed funds rates from Jun 2003 to Jun 2004 by seventeen consecutive increases of 25 percentage points from Jun 2004 to Jun 2006 to reach 5.25 percent caused default of subprime mortgages and adjustable-rate mortgages linked to the overnight fed funds rate. The zero-interest rate has penalized liquidity and increased risks by inducing carry trades from zero interest rates to speculative positions in risk financial assets. There is no exit from zero interest rates without provoking another financial crash. The yields of Treasury securities inverted on Mar 22, 2019 with the ten-year yield at 2.44 percent below those of 2.49 percent for one-month, 2.48 percent for two months, 2.46 percent for three months, 2.48 percent for six months and 2.45 percent for one year (https://www.treasury.gov/resource-center/data-chart-center/interest-rates/Pages/TextView.aspx?data=yield). Unconventional monetary policy of extremely low interest rates was an important cause of the global recession and financial crisis inducing as analyzed by Taylor (2018Oct 19, 2) “search for yield, excessive risk taking, a boom and bust in the housing market, and eventually the financial crisis and recession.” Monetary policy deviated from the Taylor Rule (Taylor 2018Oct19 see Taylor 1993, 1997, 1998LB, 1999, 2012FP, 2012Mar27, 2012Mar28, 2012JMCB, 2019Oct19 and http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2017/01/rules-versus-discretionary-authorities.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/rules-versus-discretionary-authorities.html)). An explanation is in the research of Adrian, Estrella and Shin (2018, 21-22): “Our findings suggest that the monetary tightening of 2004-2006 period ultimately did achieve a slowdown in real activity not because of its impact on the level of longer term interest rates, but rather because of its impact on the slope of the yield curve. In fact, while the level of the 10-year yield only increased 38 basis points between June 2004 and 2006, the term spread declined 325 basis points (from 3.44 to .19 percent). The fact that the slope flattened meant that intermediary profitability was compressed, thus shifting the supply of credit, and hence inducing changes in real activity. The 18 month lag between the end of the tightening cycle, and the beginning of the recession is perfectly compatible with effective monetary tightening.” See (https://www.newyorkfed.org/research/capital_markets/ycfaq.html). A major difference in the current cycle is the balance sheet of the Fed with purchases used to lower interest rates in specific segments and maturities such as mortgage-backed securities and longer terms.
Chart VI-12A, US, Fed Funds Rate and Prime Bank Loan Rate, Business Days, Jan 5, 2007 to Jul 1, 2020, Percent per Year
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
https://www.federalreserve.gov/datadownload/Choose.aspx?rel=H15
Chart VI-12B of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System provides the fed funds rate and prime bank loan rate on business days from Jan 2, 2001 to Jul 1, 2020. The behavior over time is that of controlled interest rates. Unconventional monetary policy with zero interest rates and quantitative easing is quite difficult to unwind because of the adverse effects of raising interest rates on valuations of risk financial assets and home prices, including the very own valuation of the securities held outright in the Fed balance sheet. Gradual unwinding of 1 percent fed funds rates from Jun 2003 to Jun 2004 by seventeen consecutive increases of 25 percentage points from Jun 2004 to Jun 2006 to reach 5.25 percent caused default of subprime mortgages and adjustable-rate mortgages linked to the overnight fed funds rate. The zero-interest rate has penalized liquidity and increased risks by inducing carry trades from zero interest rates to speculative positions in risk financial assets. There is no exit from zero interest rates without provoking another financial crash. The final segment shows the repetition of this policy with minute increases in interest rates. The causes of the financial crisis and global recession were interest rate and housing subsidies and affordability policies that encouraged high leverage and risks, low liquidity and unsound credit (Pelaez and Pelaez, Financial Regulation after the Global Recession (2009a), 157-66, Regulation of Banks and Finance (2009b), 217-27, International Financial Architecture (2005), 15-18, The Global Recession Risk (2007), 221-5, Globalization and the State Vol. II (2008b), 197-213, Government Intervention in Globalization (2008c), 182-4). Several past comments of this blog elaborate on these arguments, among which: http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/07/causes-of-2007-creditdollar-crisis.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/professor-mckinnons-bubble-economy.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/world-inflation-quantitative-easing.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/treasury-yields-valuation-of-risk.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2010/11/quantitative-easing-theory-evidence-and.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2010/12/is-fed-printing-money-what-are.html Gradual unwinding of 1 percent fed funds rates from Jun 2003 to Jun 2004 by seventeen consecutive increases of 25 percentage points from Jun 2004 to Jun 2006 to reach 5.25 percent caused default of subprime mortgages and adjustable-rate mortgages linked to the overnight fed funds rate. The zero-interest rate has penalized liquidity and increased risks by inducing carry trades from zero interest rates to speculative positions in risk financial assets. There is no exit from zero interest rates without provoking another financial crash. The yields of Treasury securities inverted on Mar 22, 2019 with the ten-year yield at 2.44 percent below those of 2.49 percent for one-month, 2.48 percent for two months, 2.46 percent for three months, 2.48 percent for six months and 2.45 percent for one year (https://www.treasury.gov/resource-center/data-chart-center/interest-rates/Pages/TextView.aspx?data=yield). The final segment after 2001 shows the effects of unconventional monetary policy of extremely low, below inflation fed funds rate in lowering yields. This was an important cause of the global recession and financial crisis inducing as analyzed by Taylor (2018Oct 19, 2) “search for yield, excessive risk taking, a boom and bust in the housing market, and eventually the financial crisis and recession.” Monetary policy deviated from the Taylor Rule (Taylor 2018Oct19 see Taylor 1993, 1997, 1998LB, 1999, 2012FP, 2012Mar27, 2012Mar28, 2012JMCB, 2019Oct19 and http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2017/01/rules-versus-discretionary-authorities.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/rules-versus-discretionary-authorities.html)). An explanation is in the research of Adrian, Estrella and Shin (2018, 21-22): “Our findings suggest that the monetary tightening of 2004-2006 period ultimately did achieve a slowdown in real activity not because of its impact on the level of longer term interest rates, but rather because of its impact on the slope of the yield curve. In fact, while the level of the 10-year yield only increased 38 basis points between June 2004 and 2006, the term spread declined 325 basis points (from 3.44 to .19 percent). The fact that the slope flattened meant that intermediary profitability was compressed, thus shifting the supply of credit, and hence inducing changes in real activity. The 18 month lag between the end of the tightening cycle, and the beginning of the recession is perfectly compatible with effective monetary tightening.” See (https://www.newyorkfed.org/research/capital_markets/ycfaq.html). A major difference in the current cycle is the balance sheet of the Fed with purchases used to lower interest rates in specific segments and maturities such as mortgage-backed securities and longer terms.
Chart VI-12B, US, Fed Funds Rate and Prime Bank Loan Rate, Business Days, Jan 2, 2001 to Jul 1, 2020, Percent per Year
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
https://www.federalreserve.gov/datadownload/Choose.aspx?rel=H15
Interest rate risk in the US is showing amplifying fluctuations. Chart VI-13 of the Board of Governors provides the conventional mortgage rate for a fixed-rate 30-year mortgage. The rate stood at 5.87 percent on Jan 8, 2004, increasing to 6.79 percent on Jul 6, 2006. The rate bottomed at 3.35 percent on May 2, 2013. Fear of duration risk in longer maturities such as mortgage-backed securities caused continuing increases in the conventional mortgage rate that rose to 4.51 percent on Jul 11, 2013, 4.58 percent on Aug 22, 2013 and 3.42 percent on Oct 6, 2016, which is the last data point in Chart VI-13. The thirty-year mortgage rate was 3.07 percent on Jul 2, 2020 (http://www.freddiemac.com/finance/ http://www.freddiemac.com/pmms/index.html). The current decline of yields is encouraging a surge in mortgage applications that could be reversed in a new increase. Shayndi Raice and Nick Timiraos, writing on “Banks cut as mortgage boom ends,” on Jan 16, 2014, published in the Wall Street Journal (http://online.wsj.com/news/articles/SB10001424052702303754404579310940019239208), analyze the drop in mortgage applications to a 13-year low, as measured by the Mortgage Bankers Association. Nick Timiraos, writing on “Demand for home loans plunges,” on Apr 24, 2014, published in the Wall Street Journal (http://online.wsj.com/news/articles/SB10001424052702304788404579522051733228402?mg=reno64-wsj), analyzes data in Inside Mortgage Finance that mortgage lending of $235 billion in IQ2014 is 58 percent lower than a year earlier and 23 percent below IVQ2013. Mortgage lending collapsed to the lowest level in 14 years. In testimony before the Committee on the Budget of the US Senate on May 8, 2004, Chair Yellen provides analysis of the current economic situation and outlook (http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/yellen20140507a.htm): “One cautionary note, though, is that readings on housing activity--a sector that has been recovering since 2011--have remained disappointing so far this year and will bear watching.”
Chart VI-13, US, Conventional Mortgage Rate, Jan 8, 2004 to Oct 6, 2016
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/update
Table IIB-8, US, Fed Funds Rate, Thirty Year Treasury Bond and Conventional Mortgage Rate, Monthly, Percent per Year, Dec 2012 to Jan 2020
Fed Funds Rate | Yield of Thirty Year Constant Maturity | Conventional Mortgage Rate | |
2012-12 | 0.16 | 2.88 | 3.35 |
2013-01 | 0.14 | 3.08 | 3.41 |
2013-02 | 0.15 | 3.17 | 3.53 |
2013-03 | 0.14 | 3.16 | 3.57 |
2013-04 | 0.15 | 2.93 | 3.45 |
2013-05 | 0.11 | 3.11 | 3.54 |
2013-06 | 0.09 | 3.4 | 4.07 |
2013-07 | 0.09 | 3.61 | 4.37 |
2013-08 | 0.08 | 3.76 | 4.46 |
2013-09 | 0.08 | 3.79 | 4.49 |
2013-10 | 0.09 | 3.68 | 4.19 |
2013-11 | 0.08 | 3.8 | 4.26 |
2013-12 | 0.09 | 3.89 | 4.46 |
2014-01 | 0.07 | 3.77 | 4.43 |
2014-02 | 0.07 | 3.66 | 4.3 |
2014-03 | 0.08 | 3.62 | 4.34 |
2014-04 | 0.09 | 3.52 | 4.34 |
2014-05 | 0.09 | 3.39 | 4.19 |
2014-06 | 0.1 | 3.42 | 4.16 |
2014-07 | 0.09 | 3.33 | 4.13 |
2014-08 | 0.09 | 3.2 | 4.12 |
2014-09 | 0.09 | 3.26 | 4.16 |
2014-10 | 0.09 | 3.04 | 4.04 |
2014-11 | 0.09 | 3.04 | 4 |
2014-12 | 0.12 | 2.83 | 3.86 |
2015-01 | 0.11 | 2.46 | 3.67 |
2015-02 | 0.11 | 2.57 | 3.71 |
2015-03 | 0.11 | 2.63 | 3.77 |
2015-04 | 0.12 | 2.59 | 3.67 |
2015-05 | 0.12 | 2.96 | 3.84 |
2015-06 | 0.13 | 3.11 | 3.98 |
2015-07 | 0.13 | 3.07 | 4.05 |
2015-08 | 0.14 | 2.86 | 3.91 |
2015-09 | 0.14 | 2.95 | 3.89 |
2015-10 | 0.12 | 2.89 | 3.8 |
2015-11 | 0.12 | 3.03 | 3.94 |
2015-12 | 0.24 | 2.97 | 3.96 |
2016-01 | 0.34 | 2.86 | 3.87 |
2016-02 | 0.38 | 2.62 | 3.66 |
2016-03 | 0.36 | 2.68 | 3.69 |
2016-04 | 0.37 | 2.62 | 3.61 |
2016-05 | 0.37 | 2.63 | 3.6 |
2016-06 | 0.38 | 2.45 | 3.57 |
2016-07 | 0.39 | 2.23 | 3.44 |
2016-08 | 0.4 | 2.26 | 3.44 |
2016-09 | 0.4 | 2.35 | 3.46 |
2016-10 | 0.4 | 2.5 | 3.47 |
2016-11 | 0.41 | 2.86 | 3.77 |
2016-12 | 0.54 | 3.11 | 4.2 |
2017-01 | 0.65 | 3.02 | 4.15 |
2017-02 | 0.66 | 3.03 | 4.17 |
2017-03 | 0.79 | 3.08 | 4.2 |
2017-04 | 0.9 | 2.94 | 4.05 |
2017-05 | 0.91 | 2.96 | 4.01 |
2017-06 | 1.04 | 2.8 | 3.9 |
2017-07 | 1.15 | 2.88 | 3.97 |
2017-08 | 1.16 | 2.8 | 3.88 |
2017-09 | 1.15 | 2.78 | 3.81 |
2017-10 | 1.15 | 2.88 | 3.9 |
2017-11 | 1.16 | 2.8 | 3.92 |
2017-12 | 1.3 | 2.77 | 3.95 |
2018-01 | 1.41 | 2.88 | 4.03 |
2018-02 | 1.42 | 3.13 | 4.33 |
2018-03 | 1.51 | 3.09 | 4.44 |
2018-04 | 1.69 | 3.07 | 4.47 |
2018-05 | 1.7 | 3.13 | 4.59 |
2018-06 | 1.82 | 3.05 | 4.57 |
2018-07 | 1.91 | 3.01 | 4.53 |
2018-08 | 1.91 | 3.04 | 4.55 |
2018-09 | 1.95 | 3.15 | 4.63 |
2018-10 | 2.19 | 3.34 | 4.83 |
2018-11 | 2.2 | 3.36 | 4.87 |
2018-12 | 2.27 | 3.10 | 4.64 |
2019-01 | 2.40 | 3.04 | 4.46 |
2019-02 | 2.40 | 3.02 | 4.37 |
2019-03 | 2.41 | 2.98 | 4.27 |
2019-04 | 2.42 | 2.94 | 4.14 |
2019-05 | 2.39 | 2.82 | 4.07 |
2019-06 | 2.38 | 2.57 | 3.80 |
2019-07 | 2.40 | 2.57 | 3.77 |
2019-08 | 2.13 | 2.12 | 3.62 |
2019-09 | 2.04 | 2.16 | 3.61 |
2019-10 | 1.83 | 2.19 | 3.69 |
2019-11 | 1.55 | 2.28 | 3.70 |
2019-12 | 1.55 | 2.30 | 3.72 |
2020-01 | 1.55 | 2.22 | 3.62 |
2020-02 | 1.58 | 1.97 | 3.47 |
2020-03 | 0.65 | 1.46 | 3.45 |
2020-04 | 0.05 | 1.27 | 3.31 |
2020-05 | 0.05 | 1.38 | 3.23 |
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
https://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/H15/default.htm
http://www.freddiemac.com/pmms/pmms30.html
There is a false impression of the existence of a monetary policy “science,” measurements and forecasting with which to steer the economy into “prosperity without inflation.” Market participants are remembering the Great Bond Crash of 1994 shown in Table VI-7G when monetary policy pursued nonexistent inflation, causing trillions of dollars of losses in fixed income worldwide while increasing the fed funds rate from 3 percent in Jan 1994 to 6 percent in Dec. The exercise in Table VI-7G shows a drop of the price of the 30-year bond by 18.1 percent and of the 10-year bond by 14.1 percent. CPI inflation remained almost the same and there is no valid counterfactual that inflation would have been higher without monetary policy tightening because of the long lag in effect of monetary policy on inflation (see Culbertson 1960, 1961, Friedman 1961, Batini and Nelson 2002, Romer and Romer 2004). The pursuit of nonexistent deflation during the past ten years has resulted in the largest monetary policy accommodation in history that created the 2007 financial market crash and global recession and is currently preventing smoother recovery while creating another financial crash in the future. The issue is not whether there should be a central bank and monetary policy but rather whether policy accommodation in doses from zero interest rates to trillions of dollars in the fed balance sheet endangers economic stability.
Table VI-7G, Fed Funds Rates, Thirty and Ten-Year Treasury Yields and Prices, 30-Year Mortgage Rates and 12-month CPI Inflation 1994
1994 | FF | 30Y | 30P | 10Y | 10P | MOR | CPI |
Jan | 3.00 | 6.29 | 100 | 5.75 | 100 | 7.06 | 2.52 |
Feb | 3.25 | 6.49 | 97.37 | 5.97 | 98.36 | 7.15 | 2.51 |
Mar | 3.50 | 6.91 | 92.19 | 6.48 | 94.69 | 7.68 | 2.51 |
Apr | 3.75 | 7.27 | 88.10 | 6.97 | 91.32 | 8.32 | 2.36 |
May | 4.25 | 7.41 | 86.59 | 7.18 | 88.93 | 8.60 | 2.29 |
Jun | 4.25 | 7.40 | 86.69 | 7.10 | 90.45 | 8.40 | 2.49 |
Jul | 4.25 | 7.58 | 84.81 | 7.30 | 89.14 | 8.61 | 2.77 |
Aug | 4.75 | 7.49 | 85.74 | 7.24 | 89.53 | 8.51 | 2.69 |
Sep | 4.75 | 7.71 | 83.49 | 7.46 | 88.10 | 8.64 | 2.96 |
Oct | 4.75 | 7.94 | 81.23 | 7.74 | 86.33 | 8.93 | 2.61 |
Nov | 5.50 | 8.08 | 79.90 | 7.96 | 84.96 | 9.17 | 2.67 |
Dec | 6.00 | 7.87 | 81.91 | 7.81 | 85.89 | 9.20 | 2.67 |
Notes: FF: fed funds rate; 30Y: yield of 30-year Treasury; 30P: price of 30-year Treasury assuming coupon equal to 6.29 percent and maturity in exactly 30 years; 10Y: yield of 10-year Treasury; 10P: price of 10-year Treasury assuming coupon equal to 5.75 percent and maturity in exactly 10 years; MOR: 30-year mortgage; CPI: percent change of CPI in 12 months
Sources: yields and mortgage rates http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/data.htm CPI ftp://ftp.bls.gov/pub/special.requests/cpi/cpiai.t
Chart VI-14 provides the overnight fed funds rate, the yield of the 10-year Treasury constant maturity bond, the yield of the 30-year constant maturity bond and the conventional mortgage rate from Jan 1991 to Dec 1996. In Jan 1991, the fed funds rate was 6.91 percent, the 10-year Treasury yield 8.09 percent, the 30-year Treasury yield 8.27 percent and the conventional mortgage rate 9.64 percent. Before monetary policy tightening in Oct 1993, the rates and yields were 2.99 percent for the fed funds, 5.33 percent for the 10-year Treasury, 5.94 for the 30-year Treasury and 6.83 percent for the conventional mortgage rate. After tightening in Nov 1994, the rates and yields were 5.29 percent for the fed funds rate, 7.96 percent for the 10-year Treasury, 8.08 percent for the 30-year Treasury and 9.17 percent for the conventional mortgage rate.
Chart VI-14, US, Overnight Fed Funds Rate, 10-Year Treasury Constant Maturity, 30-Year Treasury Constant Maturity and Conventional Mortgage Rate, Monthly, Jan 1991 to Dec 1996
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/update/
Chart VI-15 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics provides the all items consumer price index from Jan 1991 to Dec 1996. There does not appear acceleration of consumer prices requiring aggressive tightening.
Chart VI-15, US, Consumer Price Index All Items, Jan 1991 to Dec 1996
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics
https://www.bls.gov/cpi/data.htm
Chart IV-16 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics provides 12-month percentage changes of the all items consumer price index from Jan 1991 to Dec 1996. Inflation collapsed during the recession from Jul 1990 (III) and Mar 1991 (I) and the end of the Kuwait War on Feb 25, 1991 that stabilized world oil markets. CPI inflation remained almost the same and there is no valid counterfactual that inflation would have been higher without monetary policy tightening because of the long lag in effect of monetary policy on inflation (see Culbertson 1960, 1961, Friedman 1961, Batini and Nelson 2002, Romer and Romer 2004). Policy tightening had adverse collateral effects in the form of emerging market crises in Mexico and Argentina and fixed income markets worldwide.
Chart VI-16, US, Consumer Price Index All Items, Twelve-Month Percentage Change, Jan 1991 to Dec 1996
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics
https://www.bls.gov/cpi/data.htm
VII Economic Indicators. Crude oil input in refineries increased 1.3 percent to 13,739 thousand
barrels per day on average in the four weeks ending on Jun 26, 2020 from 13,558 thousand barrels per day in the four weeks ending on Jun 19, 2020, as shown in Table VII-1. The rate of capacity utilization in refineries continues at low level of 74.2 percent on Jun 26, 2020, which is lower than 93.9 percent on Jun 28, 2019 and close to 73.3 percent on Jun 19, 2020. Hurricane Harvey reduced capacity utilization with recent recovery followed by decline in the global recession, with output in the US reaching a high in Feb 2020 (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html), in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event and marginal recovery. Imports of crude oil decreased 3.3 percent from 3,843 thousand barrels per day on average in the four weeks ending on Jun 19, 2020 to 3,716 thousand barrels per day in the week of Jun 26, 2020. The Energy Information Administration (EIA) informs that: “US crude oil imports averaged 6.0 million barrels per day last week, decreased by 0.6 million barrels per day from the previous week. Over the past four weeks, crude oil imports averaged about 6.5 million barrels per day, 11.3 percent less than the same four-week period last year” (https://www.eia.gov/petroleum/supply/weekly/). Marginally increased utilization in refineries with decreasing imports at the margin in the prior week resulted in decrease of commercial crude oil stocks by 7.2 million barrels from 540.7 million barrels on Jun 19 to 533.5 million barrels on Jun 26. The US Energy Information Administration (EIA) states: “US commercial crude oil inventories (excluding those in the Strategic Petroleum Reserve) increased by 1.9 million in the previous week. At 490.9 million barrels [on Apr 24, 2015], US crude oil inventories are at the highest level for this time of year in at least 80 years” (https://www.eia.gov/petroleum/supply/weekly/). Motor gasoline production increased 3.4 percent to 8,549 thousand barrels per day in the week of Jun 26 from 8,267 thousand barrels per day on average in the week of Jun 19. Gasoline stocks increased 1.2 million barrels and stocks of fuel oil decreased 0.6 million barrels. Supply of gasoline changed from 9,691 thousand barrels per day on Jun 28, 2019, to 8,234 thousand barrels per day on Jun 19, 2020, or by minus 15.0 percent, while fuel oil supply decreased 13.1 percent. Part of the prior fall in consumption of gasoline had been due to high prices and part to the growth recession while current decline originates in the lockdown of economic activity in the global recession, with output in the US reaching a high in Feb 2020 (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html), in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event. WTI crude oil price traded at $38.53/barrel on Jun 26, 2020, decreasing 33.8 percent relative to $58.20/barrel on Jun 28, 2019. Gasoline prices decreased 19.9 percent from Jul 1, 2019 to Jun 29, 2020. Increases in prices of crude oil and gasoline relative to a year earlier are moderating because year earlier prices are already reflecting the commodity price surge and commodity prices have been weakening.
Table VII-1, US, Energy Information Administration Weekly Petroleum Status Report
Four Weeks Ending Thousand Barrels/Day | 06/26/20 | 06/19/20 | 06/28/19 |
Crude Oil Refineries Input | 13,739 Week ∆%: 1.3% | 13,558 | 17,239 |
Refinery Capacity Utilization % | 74.2 | 73.3 | 93.9 |
Motor Gasoline Production | 8,549 Week ∆%: 3.4% | 8,267 | 10,290 |
Distillate Fuel Oil Production | 4,611 Week ∆%: -0.5% | 4,634 | 5,313 |
Crude Oil Imports | 3,716 Week ∆%: -3.3% | 3,843 | 4,004 |
Motor Gasoline Supplied | 8,234 ∆% 2020/2019 = -15.0% | 7,982 | 9,691 |
Distillate Fuel Oil Supplied | 3,525 ∆% 2020/2019 = -13.1% | 3,260 | 4,056 |
06/26/20 | 06/19/20 | 06/28/19 | |
Crude Oil Stocks | 533.5 ∆= -7.2 MB | 540.7 | 468.5 |
Motor Gasoline Million B | 256.5 ∆= 1.2 MB | 255.3 | 230.6 |
Distillate Fuel Oil Million B | 174.1 | 174.7 | 126.8 |
WTI Crude Oil Price $/B | 38.53 ∆% 2020/2019 = -33.8 | 39.72 | 58.20 |
06/29/20 | 06/22/20 | 07/01/19 | |
Regular Motor Gasoline $/G | 2.174 ∆% 2020/2019 | 2.129 | 2.713 |
B: barrels; G: gallon
Source: US Energy Information Administration
https://www.eia.gov/petroleum/supply/weekly/
Chart VII-1 of the US Energy Information Administration (EIA) shows commercial stocks of crude oil in the US. There have been fluctuations around an upward trend since 2005. Crude oil stocks trended downwardly during a few weeks but with fluctuations followed by sharp increases alternating with declines. Stocks reached 533,527 thousand barrels in the week of Jun 26, 2020.
Chart VII-1, US, Weekly Crude Oil Ending Stocks
Source: US Energy Information Administration
https://www.eia.gov/dnav/pet/hist/LeafHandler.ashx?n=PET&s=WCESTUS1&f=W
Chart VII-2 of the US Energy Information Administration provides US average retail prices of regular gasoline. The US average was $2.174/gallon on Jun 29, 2020, decreasing $0.539 relative to the price a year earlier on a comparable day.
Chart VII-2, US, Regular Gasoline Prices
Source: US Energy Information Administration
https://www.eia.gov/petroleum/weekly/
There is no explanation for the jump of oil prices to $149/barrel in 2008 during a sharp global recession other than carry trades from zero interest rates to commodity futures. The peak in Chart VII-3 is $145.18/barrel on Jul 14, 2008 in the midst of deep global recession, falling to $33.87/barrel on Dec 19, 2008 (data for US Energy Information Administration http://www.eia.gov/dnav/pet/hist/LeafHandler.ashx?n=PET&s=RCLC1&f=D). Prices collapsed in the flight to government obligations caused by proposals of withdrawing “toxic assets” in the Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP), as analyzed by Cochrane and Zingales (2009). Risk appetite with zero interest rates after stress tests of US banks resulted in another upward trend of commodity prices after 2009 with fluctuations during periods of risk aversion. The price of the crude oil contract was $39.70/barrel on Jun 29, 2020.
Chart VII-3, US, Crude Oil Futures Contract
Source: US Energy Information Administration
https://www.eia.gov/dnav/pet/hist/RCLC1D.htm
There is typically significant difference between initial claims for unemployment insurance adjusted and not adjusted for seasonality provided in Table VII-2. Seasonally adjusted claims decreased 55,000 from 1,482,000 on Jun 20, 2020 to 1,427,000 on Jun 27, 2020 in the global recession, with output in the US reaching a high in Feb 2020 (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html), in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event. Claims not adjusted for seasonality decreased 14,575 from 1,460,056 on Jun 20, 2020 to 1,445,481 on Jun 27, 2020.
Table VII-2, US, Initial Claims for Unemployment Insurance
SA | NSA | 4-week MA SA | |
1,427,000 | 1,445,481 | 1,503,750 | |
Jun 20, 2020 | 1,482,000 | 1,460,056 | 1,621,250 |
Change | -55,000 | -14,575 | -117,500 |
Jun 13, 2020 | 1,540,000 | 1,463,363 | 1,781,500 |
Prior Year | 222,000 | 224,565 | 221,250 |
Note: SA: seasonally adjusted; NSA: not seasonally adjusted; MA: moving average
Source: https://www.dol.gov/ui/data.pdf
Table VII-2A provides the SA and NSA number of uninsured that increased 266,351 NSA from 17,654,303 on Jun 13, 2020 to 17,920,654 on Jun 20, 2020.
Table VII-2A, US, Insured Unemployment
SA | NSA | 4-week MA SA | |
Jun 20, 2020 | 19,290,000 | 17,920,654 | 19,854,000 |
Jun 13, 2020 | 19,231,000 | 17,654,303 | 20,348,500 |
Change | +59,000 | +266,351 | -494,500 |
Jun 06, 2020 | 20,289,000 | 18,422,711 | 20,751,000 |
Prior Year | 1,699,000 | 1,588,879 | 1,692,000 |
Note: SA: seasonally adjusted; NSA: not seasonally adjusted; MA: moving average
Source: https://www.dol.gov/ui/data.pdf
Table VII-3 provides seasonally adjusted and not seasonally adjusted claims in the comparable week for the years from 2001 to 2020. Data for earlier years are less comparable because of population and labor force growth. Seasonally adjusted claims typically are lower than claims not adjusted for seasonality. Claims not seasonally adjusted decreased from 563,387 on Jun 27, 2009 to 231,539 on Jun 30, 2018 and 224,565 on Jun 29, 2019, increasing to 1,445,481 on Jun 27, 2020 in the global recession, with output in the US reaching a high in Feb 2020 (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html), in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event. There is strong indication of significant decline in the level of layoffs in the US before the COVID-19 event. Hiring has not recovered (https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/06/global-recession-with-output-in-us.html and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/05/recovery-without-hiring-twenty-million.html). There is continuing unemployment and underemployment of 41.3 million or 23.9 percent of the effective labor force (Section I and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/06/creation-of-three-million-private.html).
Table VII-3, US, Unemployment Insurance Weekly Claims
Not Seasonally Adjusted Claims | Seasonally Adjusted Claims | |
Jun 30, 2001 | 375,885 | 394,000 |
Jun 9, 2002 | 358,658 | 386,000 |
Jun 28, 2003 | 394,214 | 429,000 |
Jun 26, 2004 | 318,746 | 348,000 |
Jun 25, 2005 | 286,681 | 311,000 |
Jul 01, 2006 | 304,638 | 316,000 |
Jun 30, 2007 | 300,348 | 317,000 |
Jun 28, 2008 | 368,544 | 392,000 |
Jun 27, 2009 | 563,387 | 594,000 |
Jun 26, 2010 | 444,712 | 464,000 |
Jun 25, 2011 | 406,633 | 421,000 |
Jun 30, 2012 | 369,826 | 372,000 |
Jun 29, 2013 | 335,424 | 340,000 |
Jun 28, 2014 | 305,791 | 308,000 |
Jun 27, 2015 | 274,646 | 275,000 |
Jul 02, 2016 | 263,437 | 256,000 |
Jul 01, 2017 | 252,886 | 248,000 |
Jun 30, 2018 | 231,539 | 228,000 |
Jun 29, 2019 | 224,565 | 222,000 |
Jun 27, 2020 | 1,445,481 | 1,427,000 |
Source: https://oui.doleta.gov/unemploy/claims.asp
VIII Interest Rates. It is quite difficult to measure inflationary expectations because they tend to break abruptly from past inflation. There could still be an influence of past and current inflation in the calculation of future inflation by economic agents. Table VIII-1 provides inflation of the CPI. In the three months from Mar to May 2020, CPI inflation for all items seasonally adjusted was minus 5.1 percent in annual equivalent, obtained by calculating accumulated inflation from Mar 2020 to May 2020 and compounding for a full year. In the 12 months ending in May 2020, CPI inflation of all items not seasonally adjusted was 0.1 percent. Inflation in May 2020 seasonally adjusted was minus 0.1 percent relative to Apr 2020, or minus 1.2 percent annual equivalent (https://www.bls.gov/cpi/). The second row provides the same measurements for the CPI of all items excluding food and energy: 1.2 percent in 12 months, minus 2.4 percent in annual equivalent Mar 2020-May 2020 and minus 0.1 percent in May 2020 or minus 1.2 percent in annual equivalent. The Wall Street Journal provides the yields of US Treasury securities (http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/public/page/mdc_bonds.html?mod=mdc_topnav_2_3000). The shortest term is 0.122 percent for one month, 0.144 percent for three months, 0.160 percent for six months, 0.160 percent for one year, 0.156 percent for two years, 0.186 percent for three years, 0.299 percent for five years, 0.502 percent for seven years, 0.673 percent for ten years and 1.432 percent for 30 years. The Irving Fisher (1930) definition of real interest rates is approximately the difference between nominal interest rates, which are those estimated by the Wall Street Journal, and the rate of inflation expected in the term of the security, which could behave as in Table VIII-1. Inflation in Jun 2017 is low in 12 months because of the unwinding of carry trades from zero interest rates to commodity futures prices but could ignite again with subdued risk aversion. Real interest rates in the US have been negative during substantial periods in the past decade while monetary policy pursues a policy of attaining its “dual mandate” of (https://www.federalreserve.gov/aboutthefed.htm):
“Conducting the nation's monetary policy by influencing the monetary and credit conditions in the economy in pursuit of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates”
Negative real rates of interest distort calculations of risk and returns from capital budgeting by firms, through lending by financial intermediaries to decisions on savings, housing and purchases of households. Inflation on near zero interest rates misallocates resources away from their most productive uses and creates uncertainty of the future path of adjustment to higher interest rates that inhibit sound decisions.
Table VIII-1, US, Consumer Price Index Percentage Changes 12 months NSA and Annual Equivalent ∆%
% RI | ∆% 12 Months May 2020/May | ∆% Annual Equivalent Mar 2020 to May 2020 SA | ∆% May 2020/Apr 2020 SA | |
CPI All Items | 100.000 | 0.1 | -5.1 | -0.1 |
CPI ex Food and Energy | 80.052 | 1.2 | -2.4 | -0.1 |
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics https://www.bls.gov/cpi/
Professionals use a variety of techniques in measuring interest rate risk (Fabozzi, Buestow and Johnson, 2006, Chapter Nine, 183-226):
- Full valuation approach in which securities and portfolios are shocked by 50, 100, 200 and 300 basis points to measure their impact on asset values
- Stress tests requiring more complex analysis and translation of possible events with high impact even if with low probability of occurrence into effects on actual positions and capital
- Value at Risk (VaR) analysis of maximum losses that are likely in a time horizon
- Duration and convexity that are short-hand convenient measurement of changes in prices resulting from changes in yield captured by duration and convexity
- Yield volatility
Analysis of these methods is in Pelaez and Pelaez (International Financial Architecture (2005), 101-162) and Pelaez and Pelaez, Globalization and the State, Vol. (I) (2008a), 78-100). Frederick R. Macaulay (1938) introduced the concept of duration in contrast with maturity for analyzing bonds. Duration is the sensitivity of bond prices to changes in yields. In economic jargon, duration is the yield elasticity of bond price to changes in yield, or the percentage change in price after a percentage change in yield, typically expressed as the change in price resulting from change of 100 basis points in yield. The mathematical formula is the negative of the yield elasticity of the bond price or –[dB/d(1+y)]((1+y)/B), where d is the derivative operator of calculus, B the bond price, y the yield and the elasticity does not have dimension (Hallerbach 2001). The duration trap of unconventional monetary policy is that duration is higher the lower the coupon and higher the lower the yield, other things being constant. Coupons and yields are historically low because of unconventional monetary policy. Duration dumping during a rate increase may trigger the same crossfire selling of high duration positions that magnified the credit crisis. Traders reduced positions because capital losses in one segment, such as mortgage-backed securities, triggered haircuts and margin increases that reduced capital available for positioning in all segments, causing fire sales in multiple segments (Brunnermeier and Pedersen 2009; see Pelaez and Pelaez, Regulation of Banks and Finance (2008b), 217-24). Financial markets are currently experiencing fear of duration and riskier asset classes resulting from the debate within and outside the Fed on increasing interest rates. Table VIII-2 provides the rate of the yield curve of Treasury securities on Jul 2, 2020, Dec 31, 2013, May 1, 2013, Jul 3, 2019, and Jul 3, 2006. There is oscillating steepening of the yield curve for longer maturities, which are also the ones with highest duration. The 10-year yield increased from 1.45 percent on Jul 26, 2012 to 3.04 percent on Dec 31, 2013 and 0.68 percent on Jul 2, 2020, as measured by the United States Treasury. Assume that a bond with maturity in 10 years were issued on Dec 31, 2013, at par or price of 100 with coupon of 1.45 percent. The price of that bond would be 86.3778 with instantaneous increase of the yield to 3.04 percent for loss of 13.6 percent and far more with leverage. Assume that the yield of a bond with exactly ten years to maturity and coupon of 0.68 percent would jump instantaneously from yield of 0.68 percent on Jul 2, 2020 to 5.15 percent as occurred on Jul 3, 2006 when the economy was closer to full employment. The price of the hypothetical bond issued with coupon of 0.68 percent would drop from 100 to 65.4038 after an instantaneous increase of the yield to 5.15 percent. The price loss would be 34.6 percent. Losses absorb capital available for positioning triggering crossfire sales in multiple asset classes (Brunnermeier and Pedersen 2009). What is the path of adjustment of zero interest rates on fed funds and artificially low bond yields? There is no painless exit from unconventional monetary policy. Chris Dieterich, writing on “Bond investors turn to cash,” on Jul 25, 2013, published in the Wall Street Journal (http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424127887323971204578625900935618178.html), uses data of the Investment Company Institute (https://www.ici.org/) in showing withdrawals of $43 billion in taxable mutual funds in Jun, which is the largest in history, with flows into cash investments such as $8.5 billion in the week of Jul 17 into money-market funds.
Table VIII-2, United States, Treasury Yields
07/02/20 | 12/31/13 | 05/01/13 | 07/03/19 | 07/03/06 | |
1 M | 0.13 | 0.01 | 0.03 | 2.25 | 4.69 |
2M | 0.14 | NA | NA | 2.20 | NA |
3 M | 0.14 | 0.07 | 0.06 | 2.21 | 5.08 |
6 M | 0.16 | 0.10 | 0.08 | 2.08 | 5.31 |
1 Y | 0.16 | 0.13 | 0.11 | 1.91 | 5.26 |
2 Y | 0.16 | 0.38 | 0.20 | 1.77 | 5.17 |
3 Y | 0.19 | 0.78 | 0.30 | 1.71 | 5.14 |
5 Y | 0.29 | 1.75 | 0.65 | 1.74 | 5.11 |
7 Y | 0.50 | 2.45 | 1.07 | 1.83 | 5.12 |
10 Y | 0.68 | 3.04 | 1.66 | 1.96 | 5.15 |
20 Y | 1.20 | 3.72 | 2.44 | 2.25 | 5.33 |
30 Y | 1.43 | 3.96 | 2.83 | 2.47 | 5.20 |
M: Months; Y: Years
Source: United States Treasury
There are collateral effects of unconventional monetary policy. Chart VIII-1 of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System provides the rate on the overnight fed funds rate and the yields of the 10-year constant maturity Treasury and the Baa seasoned corporate bond. Table VIII-3 provides the data for selected points in Chart VIII-1. There are two important economic and financial events, illustrating the ease of inducing carry trade with extremely low interest rates and the resulting financial crash and recession of abandoning extremely low interest rates.
- The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) lowered the target of the fed funds rate from 7.03 percent on Jul 3, 2000, to 1.00 percent on Jun 22, 2004, in pursuit of non-existing deflation (Pelaez and Pelaez, International Financial Architecture (2005), 18-28, The Global Recession Risk (2007), 83-85). Central bank commitment to maintain the fed funds rate at 1.00 percent induced adjustable-rate mortgages (ARMS) linked to the fed funds rate. Lowering the interest rate near the zero bound in 2003-2004 caused the illusion of permanent increases in wealth or net worth in the balance sheets of borrowers and also of lending institutions, securitized banking and every financial institution and investor in the world. The discipline of calculating risks and returns was seriously impaired. The objective of monetary policy was to encourage borrowing, consumption and investment. The exaggerated stimulus resulted in a financial crisis of major proportions as the securitization that had worked for a long period was shocked with policy-induced excessive risk, imprudent credit, high leverage and low liquidity by the incentive to finance everything overnight at interest rates close to zero, from adjustable rate mortgages (ARMS) to asset-backed commercial paper of structured investment vehicles (SIV). The consequences of inflating liquidity and net worth of borrowers were a global hunt for yields to protect own investments and money under management from the zero interest rates and unattractive long-term yields of Treasuries and other securities. Monetary policy distorted the calculations of risks and returns by households, business and government by providing central bank cheap money. Short-term zero interest rates encourage financing of everything with short-dated funds, explaining the SIVs created off-balance sheet to issue short-term commercial paper with the objective of purchasing default-prone mortgages that were financed in overnight or short-dated sale and repurchase agreements (Pelaez and Pelaez, Financial Regulation after the Global Recession, 50-1, Regulation of Banks and Finance, 59-60, Globalization and the State Vol. I, 89-92, Globalization and the State Vol. II, 198-9, Government Intervention in Globalization, 62-3, International Financial Architecture, 144-9). ARMS were created to lower monthly mortgage payments by benefitting from lower short-dated reference rates. Financial institutions economized in liquidity that was penalized with near zero interest rates. There was no perception of risk because the monetary authority guaranteed a minimum or floor price of all assets by maintaining low interest rates forever or equivalent to writing an illusory put option on wealth. Subprime mortgages were part of the put on wealth by an illusory put on house prices. The housing subsidy of $221 billion per year created the impression of ever-increasing house prices. The suspension of auctions of 30-year Treasuries was designed to increase demand for mortgage-backed securities, lowering their yield, which was equivalent to lowering the costs of housing finance and refinancing. Fannie and Freddie purchased or guaranteed $1.6 trillion of nonprime mortgages and worked with leverage of 75:1 under Congress-provided charters and lax oversight. The combination of these policies resulted in high risks because of the put option on wealth by near zero interest rates, excessive leverage because of cheap rates, low liquidity by the penalty in the form of low interest rates and unsound credit decisions. The put option on wealth by monetary policy created the illusion that nothing could ever go wrong, causing the credit/dollar crisis and global recession (Pelaez and Pelaez, Financial Regulation after the Global Recession, 157-66, Regulation of Banks, and Finance, 217-27, International Financial Architecture, 15-18, The Global Recession Risk, 221-5, Globalization and the State Vol. II, 197-213, Government Intervention in Globalization, 182-4). The FOMC implemented increments of 25 basis points of the fed funds target from Jun 2004 to Jun 2006, raising the fed funds rate to 5.25 percent on Jul 3, 2006, as shown in Chart VIII-1. The gradual exit from the first round of unconventional monetary policy from 1.00 percent in Jun 2004 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/press/monetary/2004/20040630/default.htm) to 5.25 percent in Jun 2006 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20060629a.htm) caused the financial crisis and global recession.
- On Dec 16, 2008, the policy determining committee of the Fed decided (http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20081216b.htm): “The Federal Open Market Committee decided today to establish a target range for the federal funds rate of 0 to 1/4 percent.” Policymakers emphasize frequently that there are tools to exit unconventional monetary policy at the right time. At the confirmation hearing on nomination for Chair of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Vice Chair Yellen (2013Nov14 http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/yellen20131114a.htm), states that: “The Federal Reserve is using its monetary policy tools to promote a more robust recovery. A strong recovery will ultimately enable the Fed to reduce its monetary accommodation and reliance on unconventional policy tools such as asset purchases. I believe that supporting the recovery today is the surest path to returning to a more normal approach to monetary policy.” Perception of withdrawal of $2671 billion, or $2.7 trillion, of bank reserves (http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h41/current/h41.htm#h41tab1), would cause Himalayan increase in interest rates that would provoke another recession. There is no painless gradual or sudden exit from zero interest rates because reversal of exposures created on the commitment of zero interest rates forever.
In his classic restatement of the Keynesian demand function in terms of “liquidity preference as behavior toward risk,” James Tobin (http://www.nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economic-sciences/laureates/1981/tobin-bio.html) identifies the risks of low interest rates in terms of portfolio allocation (Tobin 1958, 86):
“The assumption that investors expect on balance no change in the rate of interest has been adopted for the theoretical reasons explained in section 2.6 rather than for reasons of realism. Clearly investors do form expectations of changes in interest rates and differ from each other in their expectations. For the purposes of dynamic theory and of analysis of specific market situations, the theories of sections 2 and 3 are complementary rather than competitive. The formal apparatus of section 3 will serve just as well for a non-zero expected capital gain or loss as for a zero expected value of g. Stickiness of interest rate expectations would mean that the expected value of g is a function of the rate of interest r, going down when r goes down and rising when r goes up. In addition to the rotation of the opportunity locus due to a change in r itself, there would be a further rotation in the same direction due to the accompanying change in the expected capital gain or loss. At low interest rates expectation of capital loss may push the opportunity locus into the negative quadrant, so that the optimal position is clearly no consols, all cash. At the other extreme, expectation of capital gain at high interest rates would increase sharply the slope of the opportunity locus and the frequency of no cash, all consols positions, like that of Figure 3.3. The stickier the investor's expectations, the more sensitive his demand for cash will be to changes in the rate of interest (emphasis added).”
Tobin (1969) provides more elegant, complete analysis of portfolio allocation in a general equilibrium model. The major point is equally clear in a portfolio consisting of only cash balances and a perpetuity or consol. Let g be the capital gain, r the rate of interest on the consol and re the expected rate of interest. The rates are expressed as proportions. The price of the consol is the inverse of the interest rate, (1+re). Thus, g = [(r/re) – 1]. The critical analysis of Tobin is that at extremely low interest rates there is only expectation of interest rate increases, that is, dre>0, such that there is expectation of capital losses on the consol, dg<0. Investors move into positions combining only cash and no consols. Valuations of risk financial assets would collapse in reversal of long positions in carry trades with short exposures in a flight to cash. There is no exit from a central bank created liquidity trap without risks of financial crash and another global recession. The net worth of the economy depends on interest rates. In theory, “income is generally defined as the amount a consumer unit could consume (or believe that it could) while maintaining its wealth intact” (Friedman 1957, 10). Income, Y, is a flow that is obtained by applying a rate of return, r, to a stock of wealth, W, or Y = rW (Friedman 1957). According to a subsequent statement: “The basic idea is simply that individuals live for many years and that therefore the appropriate constraint for consumption is the long-run expected yield from wealth r*W. This yield was named permanent income: Y* = r*W” (Darby 1974, 229), where * denotes permanent. The simplified relation of income and wealth can be restated as:
W = Y/r (1)
Equation (1) shows that as r goes to zero, r→0, W grows without bound, W→∞. Unconventional monetary policy lowers interest rates to increase the present value of cash flows derived from projects of firms, creating the impression of long-term increase in net worth. An attempt to reverse unconventional monetary policy necessarily causes increases in interest rates, creating the opposite perception of declining net worth. As r→∞, W = Y/r →0. There is no exit from unconventional monetary policy without increasing interest rates with resulting pain of financial crisis and adverse effects on production, investment and employment.
Dan Strumpf and Pedro Nicolaci da Costa, writing on “Fed’s Yellen: Stock Valuations ‘Generally are Quite High,’” on May 6, 2015, published in the Wall Street Journal (http://www.wsj.com/articles/feds-yellen-cites-progress-on-bank-regulation-1430918155?tesla=y ), quote Chair Yellen at open conversation with Christine Lagarde, Managing Director of the IMF, finding “equity-market valuations” as “quite high” with “potential dangers” in bond valuations. The DJIA fell 0.5 percent on May 6, 2015, after the comments and then increased 0.5 percent on May 7, 2015 and 1.5 percent on May 8, 2015.
Fri May 1 | Mon 4 | Tue 5 | Wed 6 | Thu 7 | Fri 8 |
DJIA 18024.06 -0.3% 1.0% | 18070.40 0.3% 0.3% | 17928.20 -0.5% -0.8% | 17841.98 -1.0% -0.5% | 17924.06 -0.6% 0.5% | 18191.11 0.9% 1.5% |
There are two approaches in theory considered by Bordo (2012Nov20) and Bordo and Lane (2013). The first approach is in the classical works of Milton Friedman and Anna Jacobson Schwartz (1963a, 1987) and Karl Brunner and Allan H. Meltzer (1973). There is a similar approach in Tobin (1969). Friedman and Schwartz (1963a, 66) trace the effects of expansionary monetary policy into increasing initially financial asset prices: “It seems plausible that both nonbank and bank holders of redundant balances will turn first to securities comparable to those they have sold, say, fixed-interest coupon, low-risk obligations. But as they seek to purchase these they will tend to bid up the prices of those issues. Hence they, and also other holders not involved in the initial central bank open-market transactions, will look farther afield: the banks, to their loans; the nonbank holders, to other categories of securities-higher risk fixed-coupon obligations, equities, real property, and so forth.”
The second approach is by the Austrian School arguing that increases in asset prices can become bubbles if monetary policy allows their financing with bank credit. Professor Michael D. Bordo provides clear thought and empirical evidence on the role of “expansionary monetary policy” in inflating asset prices (Bordo2012Nov20, Bordo and Lane 2013). Bordo and Lane (2013) provide revealing narrative of historical episodes of expansionary monetary policy. Bordo and Lane (2013) conclude that policies of depressing interest rates below the target rate or growth of money above the target influences higher asset prices, using a panel of 18 OECD countries from 1920 to 2011. Bordo (2012Nov20) concludes: “that expansionary money is a significant trigger” and “central banks should follow stable monetary policies…based on well understood and credible monetary rules.” Taylor (2007, 2009) explains the housing boom and financial crisis in terms of expansionary monetary policy. Professor Martin Feldstein (2016), at Harvard University, writing on “A Federal Reserve oblivious to its effects on financial markets,” on Jan 13, 2016, published in the Wall Street Journal (http://www.wsj.com/articles/a-federal-reserve-oblivious-to-its-effect-on-financial-markets-1452729166), analyzes how unconventional monetary policy drove values of risk financial assets to high levels. Quantitative easing and zero interest rates distorted calculation of risks with resulting vulnerabilities in financial markets.
Another hurdle of exit from zero interest rates is “competitive easing” that Professor Raghuram Rajan, governor of the Reserve Bank of India, characterizes as disguised “competitive devaluation” (http://www.centralbanking.com/central-banking-journal/interview/2358995/raghuram-rajan-on-the-dangers-of-asset-prices-policy-spillovers-and-finance-in-india). The fed has been considering increasing interest rates. The European Central Bank (ECB) announced, on Mar 5, 2015, the beginning on Mar 9, 2015 of its quantitative easing program denominated as Public Sector Purchase Program (PSPP), consisting of “combined monthly purchases of EUR 60 bn [billion] in public and private sector securities” (http://www.ecb.europa.eu/mopo/liq/html/pspp.en.html). Expectation of increasing interest rates in the US together with euro rates close to zero or negative cause revaluation of the dollar (or devaluation of the euro and of most currencies worldwide). US corporations suffer currency translation losses of their foreign transactions and investments (http://www.fasb.org/jsp/FASB/Pronouncement_C/SummaryPage&cid=900000010318) while the US becomes less competitive in world trade (Pelaez and Pelaez, Globalization and the State, Vol. I (2008a), Government Intervention in Globalization (2008c)). The DJIA fell 1.5 percent on Mar 6, 2015 and the dollar revalued 2.2 percent from Mar 5 to Mar 6, 2015. The euro has devalued 41.4 percent relative to the dollar from the high on Jul 15, 2008 to Jul 3, 2020.
Fri 27 Feb | Mon 3/2 | Tue 3/3 | Wed 3/4 | Thu 3/5 | Fri 3/6 |
USD/ EUR 1.1197 1.6% 0.0% | 1.1185 0.1% 0.1% | 1.1176 0.2% 0.1% | 1.1081 1.0% 0.9% | 1.1030 1.5% 0.5% | 1.0843 3.2% 1.7% |
Chair Yellen explained the removal of the word “patience” from the advanced guidance at the press conference following the FOMC meeting on Mar 18, 2015 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/mediacenter/files/FOMCpresconf20150318.pdf):
“In other words, just because we removed the word “patient” from the statement doesn’t mean we are going to be impatient. Moreover, even after the initial increase in the target funds rate, our policy is likely to remain highly accommodative to support continued progress toward our objectives of maximum employment and 2 percent inflation.”
Exchange rate volatility is increasing in response of “impatience” in financial markets with monetary policy guidance and measures:
Fri Mar 6 | Mon 9 | Tue 10 | Wed 11 | Thu 12 | Fri 13 |
USD/ EUR 1.0843 3.2% 1.7% | 1.0853 -0.1% -0.1% | 1.0700 1.3% 1.4% | 1.0548 2.7% 1.4% | 1.0637 1.9% -0.8% | 1.0497 3.2% 1.3% |
Fri Mar 13 | Mon 16 | Tue 17 | Wed 18 | Thu 19 | Fri 20 |
USD/ EUR 1.0497 3.2% 1.3% | 1.0570 -0.7% -0.7% | 1.0598 -1.0% -0.3% | 1.0864 -3.5% -2.5% | 1.0661 -1.6% 1.9% | 1.0821 -3.1% -1.5% |
Fri Apr 24 | Mon 27 | Tue 28 | Wed 29 | Thu 30 | May Fri 1 |
USD/ EUR 1.0874 -0.6% -0.4% | 1.0891 -0.2% -0.2% | 1.0983 -1.0% -0.8% | 1.1130 -2.4% -1.3% | 1.1223 -3.2% -0.8% | 1.1199 -3.0% 0.2% |
In a speech at Brown University on May 22, 2015, Chair Yellen stated (http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20150522a.htm):
“For this reason, if the economy continues to improve as I expect, I think it will be appropriate at some point this year to take the initial step to raise the federal funds rate target and begin the process of normalizing monetary policy. To support taking this step, however, I will need to see continued improvement in labor market conditions, and I will need to be reasonably confident that inflation will move back to 2 percent over the medium term. After we begin raising the federal funds rate, I anticipate that the pace of normalization is likely to be gradual. The various headwinds that are still restraining the economy, as I said, will likely take some time to fully abate, and the pace of that improvement is highly uncertain.”
The US dollar appreciated 3.8 percent relative to the euro in the week of May 22, 2015:
Fri May 15 | Mon 18 | Tue 19 | Wed 20 | Thu 21 | Fri 22 |
USD/ EUR 1.1449 -2.2% -0.3% | 1.1317 1.2% 1.2% | 1.1150 2.6% 1.5% | 1.1096 3.1% 0.5% | 1.1113 2.9% -0.2% | 1.1015 3.8% 0.9% |
The Managing Director of the International Monetary Fund (IMF), Christine Lagarde, warned on Jun 4, 2015, that: (http://blog-imfdirect.imf.org/2015/06/04/u-s-economy-returning-to-growth-but-pockets-of-vulnerability/):
“The Fed’s first rate increase in almost 9 years is being carefully prepared and telegraphed. Nevertheless, regardless of the timing, higher US policy rates could still result in significant market volatility with financial stability consequences that go well beyond US borders. I weighing these risks, we think there is a case for waiting to raise rates until there are more tangible signs of wage or price inflation than are currently evident. Even after the first rate increase, a gradual rise in the federal fund rates will likely be appropriate.”
The President of the European Central Bank (ECB), Mario Draghi, warned on Jun 3, 2015 that (http://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/pressconf/2015/html/is150603.en.html):
“But certainly one lesson is that we should get used to periods of higher volatility. At very low levels of interest rates, asset prices tend to show higher volatility…the Governing Council was unanimous in its assessment that we should look through these developments and maintain a steady monetary policy stance.”
The Chair of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Janet L. Yellen, stated on Jul 10, 2015 that (http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20150710a.htm):
“Based on my outlook, I expect that it will be appropriate at some point later this year to take the first step to raise the federal funds rate and thus begin normalizing monetary policy. But I want to emphasize that the course of the economy and inflation remains highly uncertain, and unanticipated developments could delay or accelerate this first step. I currently anticipate that the appropriate pace of normalization will be gradual, and that monetary policy will need to be highly supportive of economic activity for quite some time. The projections of most of my FOMC colleagues indicate that they have similar expectations for the likely path of the federal funds rate. But, again, both the course of the economy and inflation are uncertain. If progress toward our employment and inflation goals is more rapid than expected, it may be appropriate to remove monetary policy accommodation more quickly. However, if progress toward our goals is slower than anticipated, then the Committee may move more slowly in normalizing policy.”
There is essentially the same view in the Testimony of Chair Yellen in delivering the Semiannual Monetary Policy Report to the Congress on Jul 15, 2015 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/yellen20150715a.htm).
At the press conference after the meeting of the FOMC on Sep 17, 2015, Chair Yellen states (http://www.federalreserve.gov/mediacenter/files/FOMCpresconf20150917.pdf 4):
“The outlook abroad appears to have become more uncertain of late, and heightened concerns about growth in China and other emerging market economies have led to notable volatility in financial markets. Developments since our July meeting, including the drop in equity prices, the further appreciation of the dollar, and a widening in risk spreads, have tightened overall financial conditions to some extent. These developments may restrain U.S. economic activity somewhat and are likely to put further downward pressure on inflation in the near term. Given the significant economic and financial interconnections between the United States and the rest of the world, the situation abroad bears close watching.”
Some equity markets fell on Fri Sep 18, 2015:
Fri Sep 11 | Mon 14 | Tue 15 | Wed 16 | Thu 17 | Fri 18 |
DJIA 16433.09 2.1% 0.6% | 16370.96 -0.4% -0.4% | 16599.85 1.0% 1.4% | 16739.95 1.9% 0.8% | 16674.74 1.5% -0.4% | 16384.58 -0.3% -1.7% |
Nikkei 225 18264.22 2.7% -0.2% | 17965.70 -1.6% -1.6% | 18026.48 -1.3% 0.3% | 18171.60 -0.5% 0.8% | 18432.27 0.9% 1.4% | 18070.21 -1.1% -2.0% |
DAX 10123.56 0.9% -0.9% | 10131.74 0.1% 0.1% | 10188.13 0.6% 0.6% | 10227.21 1.0% 0.4% | 10229.58 1.0% 0.0% | 9916.16 -2.0% -3.1% |
Frank H. Knight (1963, 233), in Risk, uncertainty and profit, distinguishes between measurable risk and unmeasurable uncertainty. Chair Yellen, in a lecture on “Inflation dynamics and monetary policy,” on Sep 24, 2015 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20150924a.htm), states that (emphasis added):
· “The economic outlook, of course, is highly uncertain”
· “Considerable uncertainties also surround the outlook for economic activity”
· “Given the highly uncertain nature of the outlook…”
Is there a “science” or even “art” of central banking under this extreme uncertainty in which policy does not generate higher volatility of money, income, prices and values of financial assets?
Lingling Wei, writing on Oct 23, 2015, on China’s central bank moves to spur economic growth,” published in the Wall Street Journal (http://www.wsj.com/articles/chinas-central-bank-cuts-rates-1445601495), analyzes the reduction by the People’s Bank of China (http://www.pbc.gov.cn/ http://www.pbc.gov.cn/english/130437/index.html) of borrowing and lending rates of banks by 50 basis points and reserve requirements of banks by 50 basis points. Paul Vigna, writing on Oct 23, 2015, on “Stocks rally out of correction territory on latest central bank boost,” published in the Wall Street Journal (http://blogs.wsj.com/moneybeat/2015/10/23/stocks-rally-out-of-correction-territory-on-latest-central-bank-boost/), analyzes the rally in financial markets following the statement on Oct 22, 2015, by the President of the European Central Bank (ECB) Mario Draghi of consideration of new quantitative measures in Dec 2015 (https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=0814riKW25k&rel=0) and the reduction of bank lending/deposit rates and reserve requirements of banks by the People’s Bank of China on Oct 23, 2015. The dollar revalued 2.8 percent from Oct 21 to Oct 23, 2015, following the intended easing of the European Central Bank. The DJIA rose 2.8 percent from Oct 21 to Oct 23 and the DAX index of German equities rose 5.4 percent from Oct 21 to Oct 23, 2015.
Fri Oct 16 | Mon 19 | Tue 20 | Wed 21 | Thu 22 | Fri 23 |
USD/ EUR 1.1350 0.1% 0.3% | 1.1327 0.2% 0.2% | 1.1348 0.0% -0.2% | 1.1340 0.1% 0.1% | 1.1110 2.1% 2.0% | 1.1018 2.9% 0.8% |
DJIA 17215.97 0.8% 0.4% | 17230.54 0.1% 0.1% | 17217.11 0.0% -0.1% | 17168.61 -0.3% -0.3% | 17489.16 1.6% 1.9% | 17646.70 2.5% 0.9% |
Dow Global 2421.58 0.3% 0.6% | 2414.33 -0.3% -0.3% | 2411.03 -0.4% -0.1% | 2411.27 -0.4% 0.0% | 2434.79 0.5% 1.0% | 2458.13 1.5% 1.0% |
DJ Asia Pacific 1402.31 1.1% 0.3% | 1398.80 -0.3% -0.3% | 1395.06 -0.5% -0.3% | 1402.68 0.0% 0.5% | 1396.03 -0.4% -0.5% | 1415.50 0.9% 1.4% |
Nikkei 225 18291.80 -0.8% 1.1% | 18131.23 -0.9% -0.9% | 18207.15 -0.5% 0.4% | 18554.28 1.4% 1.9% | 18435.87 0.8% -0.6% | 18825.30 2.9% 2.1% |
Shanghai 3391.35 6.5% 1.6% | 3386.70 -0.1% -0.1% | 3425.33 1.0% 1.1% | 3320.68 -2.1% -3.1% | 3368.74 -0.7% 1.4% | 3412.43 0.6% 1.3% |
DAX 10104.43 0.1% 0.4% | 10164.31 0.6% 0.6% | 10147.68 0.4% -0.2% | 10238.10 1.3% 0.9% | 10491.97 3.8% 2.5% | 10794.54 6.8% 2.9% |
Ben Leubsdorf, writing on “Fed’s Yellen: December is “Live Possibility” for First Rate Increase,” on Nov 4, 2015, published in the Wall Street Journal (http://www.wsj.com/articles/feds-yellen-december-is-live-possibility-for-first-rate-increase-1446654282) quotes Chair Yellen that a rate increase in “December would be a live possibility.” The remark of Chair Yellen was during a hearing on supervision and regulation before the Committee on Financial Services, US House of Representatives (http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/yellen20151104a.htm) and a day before the release of the employment situation report for Oct 2015 (Section I). The dollar revalued 2.4 percent during the week. The euro has devalued 41.4 percent relative to the dollar from the high on Jul 15, 2008 to Jul 3, 2020.
Fri Oct 30 | Mon 2 | Tue 3 | Wed 4 | Thu 5 | Fri 6 | |
USD/ EUR 1.1007 0.1% -0.3% | 1.1016 -0.1% -0.1% | 1.0965 0.4% 0.5% | 1.0867 1.3% 0.9% | 1.0884 1.1% -0.2% | 1.0742 2.4% 1.3% |
The release on Nov 18, 2015 of the minutes of the FOMC (Federal Open Market Committee) meeting held on Oct 28, 2015 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/fomcminutes20151028.htm) states:
“Most participants anticipated that, based on their assessment of the current economic situation and their outlook for economic activity, the labor market, and inflation, these conditions [for interest rate increase] could well be met by the time of the next meeting. Nonetheless, they emphasized that the actual decision would depend on the implications for the medium-term economic outlook of the data received over the upcoming intermeeting period… It was noted that beginning the normalization process relatively soon would make it more likely that the policy trajectory after liftoff could be shallow.”
Markets could have interpreted a symbolic increase in the fed funds rate at the meeting of the FOMC on Dec 15-16, 2015 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/fomccalendars.htm) followed by “shallow” increases, explaining the sharp increase in stock market values and appreciation of the dollar after the release of the minutes on Nov 18, 2015:
Fri Nov 13 | Mon 16 | Tue 17 | Wed 18 | Thu 19 | Fri 20 |
USD/ EUR 1.0774 -0.3% 0.4% | 1.0686 0.8% 0.8% | 1.0644 1.2% 0.4% | 1.0660 1.1% -0.2% | 1.0735 0.4% -0.7% | 1.0647 1.2% 0.8% |
DJIA 17245.24 -3.7% -1.2% | 17483.01 1.4% 1.4% | 17489.50 1.4% 0.0% | 17737.16 2.9% 1.4% | 17732.75 2.8% 0.0% | 17823.81 3.4% 0.5% |
DAX 10708.40 -2.5% -0.7% | 10713.23 0.0% 0.0% | 10971.04 2.5% 2.4% | 10959.95 2.3% -0.1% | 11085.44 3.5% 1.1% | 11119.83 3.8% 0.3% |
In testimony before The Joint Economic Committee of Congress on Dec 3, 2015 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/yellen20151203a.htm), Chair Yellen reiterated that the FOMC (Federal Open Market Committee) “anticipates that even after employment and inflation are near mandate-consistent levels, economic condition may, for some time, warrant keeping the target federal funds rate below the Committee views as normal in the longer run.” Todd Buell and Katy Burne, writing on “Draghi says ECB could step up stimulus efforts if necessary,” on Dec 4, 2015, published in the Wall Street Journal (http://www.wsj.com/articles/draghi-says-ecb-could-step-up-stimulus-efforts-if-necessary-1449252934), analyze that the President of the European Central Bank (ECB), Mario Draghi, reassured financial markets that the ECB will increase stimulus if required to raise inflation the euro area to targets. The USD depreciated 3.1 percent on Thu Dec 3, 2015 after weaker than expected measures by the European Central Bank. DJIA fell 1.4 percent on Dec 3 and increased 2.1 percent on Dec 4. DAX fell 3.6 percent on Dec 3.
Fri Nov 27 | Mon 30 | Tue 1 | Wed 2 | Thu 3 | Fri 4 |
USD/ EUR 1.0594 0.5% 0.2% | 1.0565 0.3% 0.3% | 1.0634 -0.4% -0.7% | 1.0616 -0.2% 0.2% | 1.0941 -3.3% -3.1% | 1.0885 -2.7% 0.5% |
DJIA 17798.49 -0.1% -0.1% | 17719.92 -0.4% -0.4% | 17888.35 0.5% 1.0% | 17729.68 -0.4% -0.9% | 17477.67 -1.8% -1.4% | 17847.63 0.3% 2.1% |
DAX 11293.76 1.6% -0.2% | 11382.23 0.8% 0.8% | 11261.24 -0.3% -1.1% | 11190.02 -0.9% -0.6% | 10789.24 -4.5% -3.6% | 10752.10 -4.8% -0.3% |
At the press conference following the meeting of the FOMC on Dec 16, 2015, Chair Yellen states (http://www.federalreserve.gov/mediacenter/files/FOMCpresconf20151216.pdf page 8):
“And we recognize that monetary policy operates with lags. We would like to be able to move in a prudent, and as we've emphasized, gradual manner. It's been a long time since the Federal Reserve has raised interest rates, and I think it's prudent to be able to watch what the impact is on financial conditions and spending in the economy and moving in a timely fashion enables us to do this.”
The implication of this statement is that the state of the art is not accurate in analyzing the effects of monetary policy on financial markets and economic activity. The US dollar appreciated and equities fluctuated:
Fri Dec 11 | Mon 14 | Tue 15 | Wed 16 | Thu 17 | Fri 18 |
USD/ EUR 1.0991 -1.0% -0.4% | 1.0993 0.0% 0.0% | 1.0932 0.5% 0.6% | 1.0913 0.7% 0.2% | 1.0827 1.5% 0.8% | 1.0868 1.1% -0.4% |
DJIA 17265.21 -3.3% -1.8% | 17368.50 0.6% 0.6% | 17524.91 1.5% 0.9% | 17749.09 2.8% 1.3% | 17495.84 1.3% -1.4% | 17128.55 -0.8% -2.1% |
DAX 10340.06 -3.8% -2.4% | 10139.34 -1.9% -1.9% | 10450.38 -1.1% 3.1% | 10469.26 1.2% 0.2% | 10738.12 3.8% 2.6% | 10608.19 2.6% -1.2% |
On January 29, 2016, the Policy Board of the Bank of Japan introduced a new policy to attain the “price stability target of 2 percent at the earliest possible time” (https://www.boj.or.jp/en/announcements/release_2016/k160129a.pdf). The new framework consists of three dimensions: quantity, quality and interest rate. The interest rate dimension consists of rates paid to current accounts that financial institutions hold at the Bank of Japan of three tiers zero, positive and minus 0.1 percent. The quantitative dimension consists of increasing the monetary base at the annual rate of 80 trillion yen. The qualitative dimension consists of purchases by the Bank of Japan of Japanese government bonds (JGBs), exchange traded funds (ETFs) and Japan real estate investment trusts (J-REITS). The yen devalued sharply relative to the dollar and world equity markets soared after the new policy announced on Jan 29, 2016:
Fri 22 | Mon 25 | Tue 26 | Wed 27 | Thu 28 | Fri 29 |
JPY/ USD 118.77 -1.5% -0.9% | 118.30 0.4% 0.4% | 118.42 0.3% -0.1% | 118.68 0.1% -0.2% | 118.82 0.0% -0.1% | 121.13 -2.0% -1.9% |
DJIA 16093.51 0.7% 1.3% | 15885.22 -1.3% -1.3% | 16167.23 0.5% 1.8% | 15944.46 -0.9% -1.4% | 16069.64 -0.1% 0.8% | 16466.30 2.3% 2.5% |
Nikkei 16958.53 -1.1% 5.9% | 17110.91 0.9% 0.9% | 16708.90 -1.5% -2.3% | 17163.92 1.2% 2.7% | 17041.45 0.5% -0.7% | 17518.30 3.3% 2.8% |
Shanghai 2916.56 0.5% 1.3 | 2938.51 0.8% 0.8% | 2749.79 -5.7% -6.4% | 2735.56 -6.2% -0.5% | 2655.66 -8.9% -2.9% | 2737.60 -6.1% 3.1% |
DAX 9764.88 2.3% 2.0% | 9736.15 -0.3% -0.3% | 9822.75 0.6% 0.9% | 9880.82 1.2% 0.6% | 9639.59 -1.3% -2.4% | 9798.11 0.3% 1.6% |
In testimony on the Semiannual Monetary Policy Report to the Congress on Feb 10-11, 2016, Chair Yellen (http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/yellen20160210a.htm) states: “U.S. real gross domestic product is estimated to have increased about 1-3/4 percent in 2015. Over the course of the year, subdued foreign growth and the appreciation of the dollar restrained net exports. In the fourth quarter of last year, growth in the gross domestic product is reported to have slowed more sharply, to an annual rate of just 3/4 percent; again, growth was held back by weak net exports as well as by a negative contribution from inventory investment.”
Jon Hilsenrath, writing on “Yellen Says Fed Should Be Prepared to Use Negative Rates if Needed,” on Feb 11, 2016, published in the Wall Street Journal (http://www.wsj.com/articles/yellen-reiterates-concerns-about-risks-to-economy-in-senate-testimony-1455203865), analyzes the statement of Chair Yellen in Congress that the FOMC (Federal Open Market Committee) is considering negative interest rates on bank reserves. The Wall Street Journal provides yields of two and ten-year sovereign bonds with negative interest rates on shorter maturities where central banks pay negative interest rates on excess bank reserves:
Sovereign Yields 2/12/16 | Japan | Germany | USA |
2 Year | -0.168 | -0.498 | 0.694 |
10 Year | 0.076 | 0.262 | 1.744 |
On Mar 10, 2016, the European Central Bank (ECB) announced (1) reduction of the refinancing rate by 5 basis points to 0.00 percent; decrease the marginal lending rate to 0.25 percent; reduction of the deposit facility rate to 0,40 percent; increase of the monthly purchase of assets to €80 billion; include nonbank corporate bonds in assets eligible for purchases; and new long-term refinancing operations (https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/pr/date/2016/html/pr160310.en.html). The President of the ECB, Mario Draghi, stated in the press conference (https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/pressconf/2016/html/is160310.en.html): “How low can we go? Let me say that rates will stay low, very low, for a long period of time, and well past the horizon of our purchases…We don’t anticipate that it will be necessary to reduce rates further. Of course, new facts can change the situation and the outlook.”
The dollar devalued relative to the euro and open stock markets traded lower after the announcement on Mar 10, 2016, but stocks rebounded on Mar 11:
Fri 4 | Mon 7 | Tue 8 | Wed 9 | Thu10 | Fri 11 |
USD/ EUR 1.1006 -0.7% -0.4% | 1.1012 -0.1% -0.1% | 1.1013 -0.1% 0.0% | 1.0999 0.1% 0.1% | 1.1182 -1.6% -1.7% | 1.1151 -1.3% 0.3% |
DJIA 17006.77 2.2% 0.4% | 17073.95 0.4% 0.4% | 16964.10 -0.3% -0.6% | 17000.36 0.0% 0.2% | 16995.13 -0.1% 0.0% | 17213.31 1.2% 1.3% |
DAX 9824.17 3.3% 0.7% | 9778.93 -0.5% 0.5% | 9692.82 -1.3% -0.9% | 9723.09 -1.0% 0.3% | 9498.15 -3.3% -2.3% | 9831.13 0.1% 3.5% |
At the press conference after the FOMC meeting on Sep 21, 2016, Chair Yellen states (http://www.federalreserve.gov/mediacenter/files/FOMCpresconf20160921.pdf ): “However, the economic outlook is inherently uncertain.” In the address to the Jackson Hole symposium on Aug 26, 2016, Chair Yellen states: “I believe the case for an increase in in federal funds rate has strengthened in recent months…And, as ever, the economic outlook is uncertain, and so monetary policy is not on a preset course” (http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20160826a.htm). In a speech at the World Affairs Council of Philadelphia, on Jun 6, 2016 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20160606a.htm), Chair Yellen finds that “there is considerable uncertainty about the economic outlook.” There are fifteen references to this uncertainty in the text of 18 pages double-spaced. In the Semiannual Monetary Policy Report to the Congress on Jun 21, 2016, Chair Yellen states (http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/yellen20160621a.htm), “Of course, considerable uncertainty about the economic outlook remains.” Frank H. Knight (1963, 233), in Risk, uncertainty and profit, distinguishes between measurable risk and unmeasurable uncertainty. Is there a “science” or even “art” of central banking under this extreme uncertainty in which policy does not generate higher volatility of money, income, prices and values of financial assets?
What is truly important is the fixing of the overnight fed funds at 0 to ¼ percent (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20200610a.htm): “The ongoing public health crisis will weigh heavily on economic activity, employment, and inflation in the near term, and poses considerable risks to the economic outlook over the medium term. In light of these developments, the Committee decided to maintain the target range for the federal funds rate at 0 to 1/4 percent. The Committee expects to maintain this target range until it is confident that the economy has weathered recent events and is on track to achieve its maximum employment and price stability goals.” There are multiple new policy measures, including purchases of Treasury securities and mortgage-backed securities for the balance sheet of the Fed (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20200610a.htm): “To support the flow of credit to households and businesses, over coming months the Federal Reserve will increase its holdings of Treasury securities and agency residential and commercial mortgage-backed securities at least at the current pace to sustain smooth market functioning, thereby fostering effective transmission of monetary policy to broader financial conditions. In addition, the Open Market Desk will continue to offer large-scale overnight and term repurchase agreement operations. The Committee will closely monitor developments and is prepared to adjust its plans as appropriate.”
In the Opening Remarks to the Press Conference on Oct 30, 2019, the Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, Jerome H. Powell, stated (https://www.federalreserve.gov/mediacenter/files/FOMCpresconf20191030.pdf): “We see the current stance of monetary policy as likely to remain appropriate as long as incoming information about the economy remains broadly consistent with our outlook of moderate economic growth, a strong labor market, and inflation near our symmetric 2 percent objective. We believe monetary policy is in a good place to achieve these outcomes. Looking ahead, we will be monitoring the effects of our policy actions, along with other information bearing on the outlook, as we assess the appropriate path of the target range for the fed funds rate. Of course, if developments emerge that cause a material reassessment of our outlook, we would respond accordingly. Policy is not on a preset course.” In the Opening Remarks to the Press Conference on Jan 30, 2019, the Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, Jerome H. Powell, stated (https://www.federalreserve.gov/mediacenter/files/FOMCpresconf20190130.pdf): “Today, the FOMC decided that the cumulative effects of those developments over the last several months warrant a patient, wait-and-see approach regarding future policy changes. In particular, our statement today says, “In light of global economic and financial developments and muted inflation pressures, the Committee will be patient as it determines what future adjustments to the target range for the federal funds rate may be appropriate.” This change was not driven by a major shift in the baseline outlook for the economy. Like many forecasters, we still see “sustained expansion of economic activity, strong labor market conditions, and inflation near … 2 percent” as the likeliest case. But the cross-currents I mentioned suggest the risk of a less-favorable outlook. In addition, the case for raising rates has weakened somewhat. The traditional case for rate increases is to protect the economy from risks that arise when rates are too low for too long, particularly the risk of too-high inflation. Over the past few months, that risk appears to have diminished. Inflation readings have been muted, and the recent drop in oil prices is likely to Page 3 of 5 push headline inflation lower still in coming months. Further, as we noted in our post-meeting statement, while survey-based measures of inflation expectations have been stable, financial market measures of inflation compensation have moved lower. Similarly, the risk of financial imbalances appears to have receded, as a number of indicators that showed elevated levels of financial risk appetite last fall have moved closer to historical norms. In this environment, we believe we can best support the economy by being patient in evaluating the outlook before making any future adjustment to policy.” The FOMC is initiating the “normalization” or reduction of the balance sheet of securities held outright for monetary policy (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20190130c.htm) with significant changes (https://www.federalreserve.gov/mediacenter/files/FOMCpresconf20190320.pdf). In the opening remarks to the Mar 20, 2019, the Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, Jerome H. Powell, stated (https://www.federalreserve.gov/mediacenter/files/FOMCpresconf20190320.pdf): “In discussing the Committee’s projections, it is useful to note what those projections are, as well as what they are not. The SEP includes participants’ individual projections of the most likely economic scenario along with their views of the appropriate path of the federal funds rate in that scenario. Views about the most likely scenario form one input into our policy discussions. We also discuss other plausible scenarios, including the risk of more worrisome outcomes. These and other scenarios and many other considerations go into policy, but are not reflected in projections of the most likely case. Thus, we always emphasize that the interest rate projections in the SEP are not a Committee decision. They are not a Committee plan. As Chair Yellen noted some years ago, the FOMC statement, rather than the dot plot, is the device that the Committee uses to express its opinions about the likely path of rates.”
In the Introductory Statement on Jul 25, 2019, in Frankfurt am Main, the President of the European Central Bank, Mario Draghi, stated (https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/pressconf/2019/html/ecb.is190725~547f29c369.en.html): “Based on our regular economic and monetary analyses, we decided to keep the key ECB interest rates unchanged. We expect them to remain at their present or lower levels at least through the first half of 2020, and in any case for as long as necessary to ensure the continued sustained convergence of inflation to our aim over the medium term.
We intend to continue reinvesting, in full, the principal payments from maturing securities purchased under the asset purchase programme for an extended period of time past the date when we start raising the key ECB interest rates, and in any case for as long as necessary to maintain favourable liquidity conditions and an ample degree of monetary accommodation.” At its meeting on September 12, 2019, the Governing Council of the ECB (European Central Bank), decided to (https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/pr/date/2019/html/ecb.mp190912~08de50b4d2.en.html): (1) decrease the deposit facility by 10 basis points to minus 0.50 percent while maintaining at 0.00 the main refinancing operations rate and at 0.25 percent the marginal lending facility rate; (2) restart net purchases of securities at the monthly rate of €20 billion beginning on Nov 1, 2019; (3) reinvest principal payments from maturing securities; (4) adapt long-term refinancing operations to maintain “favorable bank lending conditions;” and (5) exempt part of the “negative deposit facility rate” on bank excess liquidity.
The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) decided to lower the target range of the federal funds rate by 0.50 percent to 1.0 to 1¼ percent on Mar 3, 2020 in a decision outside the calendar meetings (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20200303a.htm):
March 03, 2020
Federal Reserve issues FOMC statement
For release at 10:00 a.m. EST
The fundamentals of the U.S. economy remain strong. However, the coronavirus poses evolving risks to economic activity. In light of these risks and in support of achieving its maximum employment and price stability goals, the Federal Open Market Committee decided today to lower the target range for the federal funds rate by 1/2 percentage point, to 1 to 1‑1/4 percent. The Committee is closely monitoring developments and their implications for the economic outlook and will use its tools and act as appropriate to support the economy.
Voting for the monetary policy action were Jerome H. Powell, Chair; John C. Williams, Vice Chair; Michelle W. Bowman; Lael Brainard; Richard H. Clarida; Patrick Harker; Robert S. Kaplan; Neel Kashkari; Loretta J. Mester; and Randal K. Quarles.
For media inquiries, call 202-452-2955.
Implementation Note issued March 3, 2020
The decisions of the FOMC (Federal Open Market Committee) depend on incoming data. There are unexpected swings in valuations of risk financial assets by “carry trades” from interest rates below inflation to exposures in stocks, commodities and their derivatives. Another issue is the unexpected “data surprises” such as the sharp decline in 12 months rates of increase of real disposable income, or what is left after taxes and inflation, and the price indicator of the FOMC, prices of personal consumption expenditures (PCE) excluding food and energy. There is no science or art of monetary policy that can deal with this uncertainty.
Real Disposable Personal Income | Real Personal Consumption Expenditures | Prices of Personal Consumption Expenditures | PCE Prices Excluding Food and Energy |
∆%12M | ∆%12M | ∆%12M | ∆%12M |
6/2017 | 6/2017 | 6/2017 | 6/2017 |
1.2 | 2.4 | 1.4 | 1.5 |
In presenting the Semiannual Monetary Policy Report to Congress on Jul 17, 2018, the Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Jerome H. Powell, stated (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/powell20180717a.htm): “With a strong job market, inflation close to our objective, and the risks to the outlook roughly balanced, the FOMC believes that--for now--the best way forward is to keep gradually raising the federal funds rate. We are aware that, on the one hand, raising interest rates too slowly may lead to high inflation or financial market excesses. On the other hand, if we raise rates too rapidly, the economy could weaken and inflation could run persistently below our objective. The Committee will continue to weigh a wide range of relevant information when deciding what monetary policy will be appropriate. As always, our actions will depend on the economic outlook, which may change as we receive new data.”
At an address to The Clearing House and The Bank Policy Institute Annual Conference (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/clarida20181127a.htm), in New York City, on Nov 27, 2018, the Vice Chairman of the Fed, Richard H. Clarida, analyzes the data dependence of monetary policy. An important hurdle is critical unobserved parameters of monetary policy (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/clarida20181127a.htm): “But what if key parameters that describe the long-run destination of the economy are unknown? This is indeed the relevant case that the FOMC and other monetary policymakers face in practice. The two most important unknown parameters needed to conduct‑‑and communicate‑‑monetary policy are the rate of unemployment consistent with maximum employment, u*, and the riskless real rate of interest consistent with price stability, r*. As a result, in the real world, monetary policy should, I believe, be data dependent in a second sense: that incoming data can reveal at each FOMC meeting signals that will enable it to update its estimates of r* and u* in order to obtain its best estimate of where the economy is heading.” Current robust economic growth, employment creation and inflation close to the Fed’s 2 percent objective suggest continuing “gradual policy normalization.” Incoming data can be used to update u* and r* in designing monetary policy that attains price stability and maximum employment. Clarida also finds that the current expansion will be the longest in history if it continues into 2019. In an address at The Economic Club of New York, New York City, Nov 28, 2018 (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/powell20181128a.htm), the Chairman of the Fed, Jerome H. Powell, stated (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/powell20181128a.htm): “For seven years during the crisis and its painful aftermath, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) kept our policy interest rate unprecedentedly low--in fact, near zero--to support the economy as it struggled to recover. The health of the economy gradually but steadily improved, and about three years ago the FOMC judged that the interests of households and businesses, of savers and borrowers, were no longer best served by such extraordinarily low rates. We therefore began to raise our policy rate gradually toward levels that are more normal in a healthy economy. Interest rates are still low by historical standards, and they remain just below the broad range of estimates of the level that would be neutral for the economy‑‑that is, neither speeding up nor slowing down growth. My FOMC colleagues and I, as well as many private-sector economists, are forecasting continued solid growth, low unemployment, and inflation near 2 percent.” The market focused on policy rates “just below the broad range of estimates of the level that would be neutral for the economy—that is, neither speeding up nor slowing down growth.” There was a relief rally in the stock market of the United States:
Fri 23 | Mon 26 | Tue 27 | Wed 28 | Thu 29 | Fri 30 |
USD/EUR 1.1339 0.7% 0.6% | 1.1328 0.1% 0.1% | 1.1293 0.4% 0.3% | 1.1368 -0.3% -0.7% | 1.1394 -0.5% -0.2% | 1.1320 0.2% 0.6% |
DJIA 24285.95 -4.4% -0.7% | 24640.24 1.5% 1.5% | 24748.73 1.9% 0.4% | 25366.43 4.4% 2.5% | 25338.84 4.3% -0.1% | 25538.46 5.2% 0.8% |
At a meeting of the American Economic Association in Atlanta on Friday, January 4, 2019, the Chairman of the Fed, Jerome H. Powell, stated that the Fed would be “patient” with interest rate increases, adjusting policy “quickly and flexibly” if required (https://www.aeaweb.org/webcasts/2019/us-federal-reserve-joint-interview). Treasury yields declined and stocks jumped.
Fri 28 | Mon 31 | Tue 1 | Wed 2 | Thu 3 | Fri 4 |
10Y Note 2.736 | 2.683 | 2.683 | 2.663 | 2.560 | 2.658 |
2Y Note 2.528 | 2.500 | 2.500 | 2.488 | 2.387 | 2.480 |
DJIA 23062.40 2.7% -0.3% | 23327.46 1.1% 1.1% | 23327.46 1.1% 0.0% | 23346.24 1.2% 0.1% | 22686.22 -1.6% -2.8% | 23433.16 1.6% 3.3% |
Dow Global 2718.19 1.3% 0.8% | 2734.40 0.6% 0.6% | 2734.40 0.6% 0.0% | 2729.74 0.4% -0.2% | 2707.29 -0.4% -0.8% | 2773.12 2.0% 2.4% |
Frank H. Knight (1963, 233), in Risk, uncertainty and profit, distinguishes between measurable risk and unmeasurable uncertainty. The FOMC statement on Jun 19, 2019 analyzes uncertainty in the outlook (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20190619a.htm): “The Committee continues to view sustained expansion of economic activity, strong labor market conditions, and inflation near the Committee's symmetric 2 percent objective as the most likely outcomes, but uncertainties about this outlook have increased. In light of these uncertainties and muted inflation pressures, the Committee will closely monitor the implications of incoming information for the economic outlook and will act as appropriate to sustain the expansion, with a strong labor market and inflation near its symmetric 2 percent objective.” In the Semiannual Monetary Policy Report to the Congress, on Jul 10, 2019, Chair Jerome H. Powell states (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/powell20190710a.htm): “Since our May meeting, however, these crosscurrents have reemerged, creating greater uncertainty. Apparent progress on trade turned to greater uncertainty, and our contacts in business and agriculture report heightened concerns over trade developments. Growth indicators from around the world have disappointed on net, raising concerns that weakness in the global economy will continue to affect the U.S. economy. These concerns may have contributed to the drop in business confidence in some recent surveys and may have started to show through to incoming data.
”(emphasis added). European Central Bank President, Mario Draghi, stated at a meeting on “Twenty Years of the ECB’s Monetary Policy,” in Sintra, Portugal, on Jun 18, 2019, that (https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/key/date/2019/html/ecb.sp190618~ec4cd2443b.en.html): “In this environment, what matters is that monetary policy remains committed to its objective and does not resign itself to too-low inflation. And, as I emphasised at our last monetary policy meeting, we are committed, and are not resigned to having a low rate of inflation forever or even for now. In the absence of improvement, such that the sustained return of inflation to our aim is threatened, additional stimulus will be required. In our recent deliberations, the members of the Governing Council expressed their conviction in pursuing our aim of inflation close to 2% in a symmetric fashion. Just as our policy framework has evolved in the past to counter new challenges, so it can again. In the coming weeks, the Governing Council will deliberate how our instruments can be adapted commensurate to the severity of the risk to price stability.” At its meeting on September 12, 2019, the Governing Council of the ECB (European Central Bank), decided to (https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/pr/date/2019/html/ecb.mp190912~08de50b4d2.en.html): (1) decrease the deposit facility by 10 basis points to minus 0.50 percent while maintaining at 0.00 the main refinancing operations rate and at 0.25 percent the marginal lending facility rate; (2) restart net purchases of securities at the monthly rate of €20 billion beginning on Nov 1, 2019; (3) reinvest principal payments from maturing securities; (4) adapt long-term refinancing operations to maintain “favorable bank lending conditions;” and (5) exempt part of the “negative deposit facility rate” on bank excess liquidity. The harmonized index of consumer prices of the euro zone increased 1.2 percent in the 12 months ending in May 2019 and the PCE inflation excluding food and energy increased 1.6 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr 2019. Inflation below 2 percent with symmetric targets in both the United States and the euro zone together with apparently weakening economic activity could lead to interest rate cuts. Stock markets jumped worldwide in renewed risk appetite during the week of Jun 19, 2019 in part because of anticipation of major central bank rate cuts and also because of domestic factors:
Fri 14 | Mon 17 | Tue 18 | Wed 19 | Thu 20 | Fri 21 |
DJIA 26089.61 0.4% -0.1% | 26112.53 0.1% 0.1% | 26465.54 1.4% 1.4% | 26504.00 1.6% 0.1% | 26753.17 2.5% 0.9% | 26719.13 2.4% -0.1% |
Dow Global 2998.79 0.2% -0.4% | 2999.93 0.0% 0.0% | 3034.59 1.2% 1.2% | 3050.80 1.7% 0.5% | 3077.81 2.6% 0.9% | 3081.62 2.8% 0.1% |
DJ Asia Pacific NA | NA | NA | NA | NA | NA |
Nikkei 21116.89 1.1% 0.4% | 21124.00 0.0% 0.0% | 20972.71 -0.7% -0.7% | 21333.87 1.0% 1.7% | 21462.86 1.6% 0.6% | 21258.64 0.7% -1.0% |
Shanghai 2881.97 1.9% -1.0% | 2887.62 0.2% 0.2% | 2890.16 0.3% 0.1% | 2917.80 1.2% 1.0% | 2987.12 3.6% 2.4% | 3001.98 4.2% 0.5% |
DAX 12096.40 0.4% -0.6% | 12085.82 -0.1% -0.1% | 12331.75 1.9% 2.0% | 12308.53 1.8% -0.2% | 12355.39 2.1% 0.4% | 12339.92 2.0% -0.1% |
BOVESPA 98040.06 0.2% -0.7% | 97623.25 -0.4% -0.4% | 99404.39 1.4% 1.8% | 100303.41 2.3% 0.9% | 100303.41 2.3% 0.0% | 102012.64 4.1% 1.7% |
Chart VIII-1, Fed Funds Rate and Yields of Ten-year Treasury Constant Maturity and Baa Seasoned Corporate Bond, Jan 2, 2001 to Oct 6, 2016
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/
Chart VIII-1A, Fed Funds Rate and Yield of Ten-year Treasury Constant Maturity, Jan 2, 2001 to Jul 1, 2020
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/
Table VIII-3, Selected Data Points in Chart VIII-1, % per Year
Fed Funds Overnight Rate | 10-Year Treasury Constant Maturity | Seasoned Baa Corporate Bond | |
1/2/2001 | 6.67 | 4.92 | 7.91 |
10/1/2002 | 1.85 | 3.72 | 7.46 |
7/3/2003 | 0.96 | 3.67 | 6.39 |
6/22/2004 | 1.00 | 4.72 | 6.77 |
6/28/2006 | 5.06 | 5.25 | 6.94 |
9/17/2008 | 2.80 | 3.41 | 7.25 |
10/26/2008 | 0.09 | 2.16 | 8.00 |
10/31/2008 | 0.22 | 4.01 | 9.54 |
4/6/2009 | 0.14 | 2.95 | 8.63 |
4/5/2010 | 0.20 | 4.01 | 6.44 |
2/4/2011 | 0.17 | 3.68 | 6.25 |
7/25/2012 | 0.15 | 1.43 | 4.73 |
5/1/13 | 0.14 | 1.66 | 4.48 |
9/5/13 | 0.089 | 2.98 | 5.53 |
11/21/2013 | 0.09 | 2.79 | 5.44 |
11/26/13 | 0.09 | 2.74 | 5.34 (11/26/13) |
12/5/13 | 0.09 | 2.88 | 5.47 |
12/11/13 | 0.09 | 2.89 | 5.42 |
12/18/13 | 0.09 | 2.94 | 5.36 |
12/26/13 | 0.08 | 3.00 | 5.37 |
1/1/2014 | 0.08 | 3.00 | 5.34 |
1/8/2014 | 0.07 | 2.97 | 5.28 |
1/15/2014 | 0.07 | 2.86 | 5.18 |
1/22/2014 | 0.07 | 2.79 | 5.11 |
1/30/2014 | 0.07 | 2.72 | 5.08 |
2/6/2014 | 0.07 | 2.73 | 5.13 |
2/13/2014 | 0.06 | 2.73 | 5.12 |
2/20/14 | 0.07 | 2.76 | 5.15 |
2/27/14 | 0.07 | 2.65 | 5.01 |
3/6/14 | 0.08 | 2.74 | 5.11 |
3/13/14 | 0.08 | 2.66 | 5.05 |
3/20/14 | 0.08 | 2.79 | 5.13 |
3/27/14 | 0.08 | 2.69 | 4.95 |
4/3/14 | 0.08 | 2.80 | 5.04 |
4/10/14 | 0.08 | 2.65 | 4.89 |
4/17/14 | 0.09 | 2.73 | 4.89 |
4/24/14 | 0.10 | 2.70 | 4.84 |
5/1/14 | 0.09 | 2.63 | 4.77 |
5/8/14 | 0.08 | 2.61 | 4.79 |
5/15/14 | 0.09 | 2.50 | 4.72 |
5/22/14 | 0.09 | 2.56 | 4.81 |
5/29/14 | 0.09 | 2.45 | 4.69 |
6/05/14 | 0.09 | 2.59 | 4.83 |
6/12/14 | 0.09 | 2.58 | 4.79 |
6/19/14 | 0.10 | 2.64 | 4.83 |
6/26/14 | 0.10 | 2.53 | 4.71 |
7/2/14 | 0.10 | 2.64 | 4.84 |
7/10/14 | 0.09 | 2.55 | 4.75 |
7/17/14 | 0.09 | 2.47 | 4.69 |
7/24/14 | 0.09 | 2.52 | 4.72 |
7/31/14 | 0.08 | 2.58 | 4.75 |
8/7/14 | 0.09 | 2.43 | 4.71 |
8/14/14 | 0.09 | 2.40 | 4.69 |
8/21/14 | 0.09 | 2.41 | 4.69 |
8/28/14 | 0.09 | 2.34 | 4.57 |
9/04/14 | 0.09 | 2.45 | 4.70 |
9/11/14 | 0.09 | 2.54 | 4.79 |
9/18/14 | 0.09 | 2.63 | 4.91 |
9/25/14 | 0.09 | 2.52 | 4.79 |
10/02/14 | 0.09 | 2.44 | 4.76 |
10/09/14 | 0.08 | 2.34 | 4.68 |
10/16/14 | 0.09 | 2.17 | 4.64 |
10/23/14 | 0.09 | 2.29 | 4.71 |
11/13/14 | 0.09 | 2.35 | 4.82 |
11/20/14 | 0.10 | 2.34 | 4.86 |
11/26/14 | 0.10 | 2.24 | 4.73 |
12/04/14 | 0.12 | 2.25 | 4.78 |
12/11/14 | 0.12 | 2.19 | 4.72 |
12/18/14 | 0.13 | 2.22 | 4.78 |
12/23/14 | 0.13 | 2.26 | 4.79 |
12/30/14 | 0.06 | 2.20 | 4.69 |
1/8/15 | 0.12 | 2.03 | 4.57 |
1/15/15 | 0.12 | 1.77 | 4.42 |
1/22/15 | 0.12 | 1.90 | 4.49 |
1/29/15 | 0.11 | 1.77 | 4.35 |
2/05/15 | 0.12 | 1.83 | 4.43 |
2/12/15 | 0.12 | 1.99 | 4.53 |
2/19/15 | 0.12 | 2.11 | 4.64 |
2/26/15 | 0.11 | 2.03 | 4.47 |
3/5/215 | 0.11 | 2.11 | 4.58 |
3/12/15 | 0.11 | 2.10 | 4.56 |
3/19/15 | 0.12 | 1.98 | 4.48 |
3/26/15 | 0.11 | 2.01 | 4.56 |
4/03/15 | 0.12 | 1.92 | 4.47 |
4/9/15 | 0.12 | 1.97 | 4.50 |
4/16/15 | 0.13 | 1.90 | 4.45 |
4/23/15 | 0.13 | 1.96 | 4.50 |
5/1/15 | 0.08 | 2.05 | 4.65 |
5/7/15 | 0.13 | 2.18 | 4.82 |
5/14/15 | 0.13 | 2.23 | 4.97 |
5/21/15 | 0.12 | 2.19 | 4.94 |
5/28/15 | 0.12 | 2.13 | 4.88 |
6/04/15 | 0.13 | 2.31 | 5.03 |
6/11/15 | 0.13 | 2.39 | 5.10 |
6/18/15 | 0.14 | 2.35 | 5.17 |
6/25/15 | 0.13 | 2.40 | 5.20 |
7/1/15 | 0.13 | 2.43 | 5.26 |
7/9/15 | 0.13 | 2.32 | 5.20 |
7/16/15 | 0.14 | 2.36 | 5.24 |
7/23/15 | 0.13 | 2.28 | 5.13 |
7/30/15 | 0.14 | 2.28 | 5.16 |
8/06/15 | 0.14 | 2.23 | 5.15 |
8/20/15 | 0.15 | 2.09 | 5.13 |
8/27/15 | 0.14 | 2.18 | 5.33 |
9/03/15 | 0.14 | 2.18 | 5.35 |
9/10/15 | 0.14 | 2.23 | 5.35 |
9/17/15 | 0.14 | 2.21 | 5.39 |
9/25/15 | 0.14 | 2.13 | 5.29 |
10/01/15 | 0.13 | 2.05 | 5.36 |
10/08/15 | 0.13 | 2.12 | 5.40 |
10/15/15 | 0.13 | 2.04 | 5.33 |
10/22/15 | 0.12 | 2.04 | 5.30 |
10/29/15 | 0.12 | 2.19 | 5.40 |
11/05/15 | 0.12 | 2.26 | 5.44 |
11/12/15 | 0.12 | 2.32 | 5.51 |
11/19/15 | 0.12 | 2.24 | 5.44 |
11/25/15 | 0.12 | 2.23 | 5.44 |
12/03/15 | 0.13 | 2.33 | 5.51 |
12/10/15 | 0.14 | 2.24 | 5.43 |
12/17/15 | 0.37 | 2.24 | 5.45 |
12/23/15 | 0.36 | 2.27 | 5.53 |
12/30/15 | 0.35 | 2.31 | 5.54 |
1/07/2016 | 0.36 | 2.16 | 5.44 |
01/14/16 | 0.36 | 2.10 | 5.46 |
01/20/16 | 0.37 | 2.01 | 5.41 |
01/29/16 | 0.38 | 2.00 | 5.48 |
02/04/16 | 0.38 | 1.87 | 5.40 |
02/11/16 | 0.38 | 1.63 | 5.26 |
02/18/16 | 0.38 | 1.75 | 5.37 |
02/25/16 | 0.37 | 1.71 | 5.27 |
03/03/16 | 0.37 | 1.83 | 5.30 |
03/10/16 | 0.36 | 1.93 | 5.23 |
03/17/16 | 0.37 | 1.91 | 5.11 |
03/24/16 | 0.37 | 1.91 | 4.97 |
03/31/16 | 0.25 | 1.78 | 4.90 |
04/07/16 | 0.37 | 1.70 | 4.76 |
04/14/16 | 0.37 | 1.80 | 4.79 |
04/21/16 | 0.37 | 1.88 | 4.79 |
04/28/16 | 0.37 | 1.84 | 4.73 |
05/05/16 | 0.37 | 1.76 | 4.62 |
05/12/16 | 0.37 | 1.75 | 4.66 |
05/19/16 | 0.37 | 1.85 | 4.70 |
05/26/16 | 0.37 | 1.83 | 4.69 |
06/02/16 | 0.37 | 1.81 | 4.64 |
06/09/16 | 0.37 | 1.68 | 4.53 |
06/16/16 | 0.38 | 1.57 | 4.47 |
06/23/16 | 0.39 | 1.74 | 4.60 |
06/30/16 | 0.36 | 1.49 | 4.41 |
07/07/16 | 0.40 | 1.40 | 4.19 |
07/14/16 | 0.40 | 1.53 | 4.23 |
07/21/16 | 0.40 | 1.57 | 4.25 |
07/28/16 | 0.40 | 1.52 | 4.20 |
08/04/16 | 0.40 | 1.51 | 4.27 |
08/11/16 | 0.40 | 1.57 | 4.27 |
08/18/16 | 0.40 | 1.53 | 4.23 |
08/25/16 | 0.40 | 1.58 | 4.21 |
09/01/16 | 0.40 | 1.57 | 4.19 |
09/08/16 | 0.40 | 1.61 | 4.28 |
09/15/16 | 0.40 | 1.71 | 4.43 |
09/22/16 | 0.40 | 1.63 | 4.32 |
09/29/16 | 0.40 | 1.56 | 4.23 |
10/06/16 | 0.40 | 1.75 | 4.36 |
10/13/16 | 0.40 | 1.75 | NA* |
10/20/16 | 0.41 | 1.76 | NA* |
10/27/16 | 0.41 | 1.85 | NA* |
11/03/16 | 0.41 | 1.82 | NA* |
11/09/16 | 0.41 | 2.07 | NA* |
11/17/16 | 0.41 | 2.29 | NA* |
11/23/16 | 0.40 | 2.36 | NA* |
12/01/16 | 0.40 | 2.45 | NA* |
12/08/16 | 0.41 | 2.40 | NA* |
12/15/16 | 0.66 | 2.60 | NA* |
12/22/16 | 0.66 | 2.55 | NA* |
12/29/16 | 0.66 | 2.49 | NA* |
01/05/17 | 0.66 | 2.37 | NA* |
01/12/17 | 0.66 | 2.36 | NA* |
01/19/17 | 0.66 | 2.42 | NA* |
01/26/17 | 0.66 | 2.51 | NA* |
02/02/17 | 0.66 | 2.48 | NA* |
02/09/17 | 0.66 | 2.40 | NA* |
02/16/17 | 0.66 | 2.45 | NA* |
02/23/17 | 0.66 | 2.38 | NA* |
03/02/17 | 0.66 | 2.49 | NA* |
03/09/17 | 0.66 | 2.60 | NA* |
03/16/17 | 0.91 | 2.53 | NA* |
03/23/17 | 0.91 | 2.41 | NA* |
03/30/17 | 0.91 | 2.42 | NA* |
04/06/17 | 0.91 | 2.34 | NA* |
04/13/17 | 0.91 | 2.24 | NA* |
04/21/17 | 0.91 | 2.24 | NA* |
04/27/17 | 0.91 | 2.30 | NA* |
05/04/17 | 0.91 | 2.36 | NA* |
05/11/17 | 0.91 | 2.39 | NA* |
05/18/17 | 0.91 | 2.23 | NA* |
05/25/17 | 0.91 | 2.25 | NA* |
06/01/17 | 0.90 | 2.21 | NA* |
06/08/17 | 0.91 | 2.19 | NA* |
06/15/17 | 1.16 | 2.16 | NA* |
06/22/17 | 1.16 | 2.15 | NA* |
06/29/17 | 1.16 | 2.27 | NA* |
07/06/17 | 1.16 | 2.37 | NA* |
07/13/17 | 1.16 | 2.35 | NA* |
07/20/17 | 1.16 | 2.27 | NA* |
07/27/17 | 1.16 | 2.32 | NA* |
08/03/17 | 1.16 | 2.24 | NA* |
08/10/17 | 1.16 | 2.20 | NA* |
08/17/17 | 1.16 | 2.19 | NA* |
08/24/17 | 1.16 | 2.19 | NA* |
08/31/17 | 1.07 | 2.12 | NA* |
09/07/17 | 1.16 | 2.05 | NA* |
09/14/17 | 1.16 | 2.20 | NA* |
09/21/17 | 1.16 | 2.27 | NA* |
09/28/17 | 1.16 | 2.31 | NA* |
10/05/17 | 1.16 | 2.35 | NA* |
10/12/17 | 1.16 | 2.33 | NA* |
10/19/17 | 1.16 | 2.33 | NA* |
10/26/17 | 1.16 | 2.46 | NA* |
11/02/17 | 1.16 | 2.35 | NA* |
11/09/17 | 1.16 | 2.32 | NA* |
11/16/17 | 1.16 | 2.37 | NA* |
11/22/17 | 1.16 | 2.32 | NA* |
11/30/17 | 1.16 | 2.42 | NA* |
12/07/17 | 1.16 | 2.37 | NA* |
12/14/17 | 1.41 | 2.35 | NA* |
12/21/17 | 1.42 | 2.48 | NA* |
12/28/17 | 1.42 | 2.43 | NA* |
01/04/18 | 1.42 | 2.46 | NA* |
01/11/18 | 1.42 | 2.54 | NA* |
01/18/18 | 1.42 | 2.62 | NA* |
01/25/18 | 1.42 | 2.63 | NA* |
02/01/18 | 1.42 | 2.78 | NA* |
02/08/18 | 1.42 | 2.85 | NA* |
02/15/18 | 1.42 | 2.90 | NA* |
02/22/18 | 1.42 | 2.92 | NA* |
03/01/18 | 1.42 | 2.81 | NA* |
03/08/18 | 1.42 | 2.86 | NA* |
03/15/18 | 1.43 | 2.82 | NA* |
03/22/18 | 1.68 | 2.83 | NA* |
03/29/18 | 1.68 | 2.74 | NA* |
04/05/18 | 1.69 | 2.83 | NA* |
04/12/18 | 1.69 | 2.83 | NA* |
04/19/18 | 1.69 | 2.92 | NA* |
04/26/18 | 1.70 | 3.00 | NA* |
05/03/18 | 1.70 | 2.94 | NA* |
05/10/18 | 1.70 | 2.97 | NA* |
05/17/18 | 1.70 | 3.11 | NA* |
05/24/18 | 1.70 | 2.98 | NA* |
05/31/18 | 1.70 | 2.83 | NA* |
06/07/18 | 1.70 | 2.93 | NA* |
06/14/18 | 1.90 | 2.94 | NA* |
06/21/18 | 1.92 | 2.90 | NA* |
06/28/18 | 1.91 | 2.84 | NA* |
07/05/18 | 1.91 | 2.84 | NA* |
07/12/18 | 1.91 | 2.85 | NA* |
07/19/18 | 1.91 | 2.84 | NA* |
07/26/18 | 1.91 | 2.98 | NA* |
08/02/18 | 1.91 | 2.98 | NA* |
08/09/18 | 1.91 | 2.93 | NA* |
08/16/18 | 1.92 | 2.87 | NA* |
08/23/18 | 1.92 | 2.82 | NA* |
08/30/18 | 1.92 | 2.86 | NA* |
09/06/18 | 1.92 | 2.88 | NA* |
09/13/18 | 1.92 | 2.97 | NA* |
09/20/18 | 1.92 | 3.07 | NA* |
09/27/18 | 2.18 | 3.06 | NA* |
10/04/18 | 2.18 | 3.19 | NA* |
10/11/18 | 2.18 | 3.14 | NA* |
10/18/18 | 2.19 | 3.17 | NA* |
10/25/18 | 2.20 | 3.14 | NA* |
11/01/18 | 2.20 | 3.14 | NA* |
11/08/18 | 2.20 | 3.24 | NA* |
11/15/18 | 2.20 | 3.11 | NA* |
11/21/18 | 2.20 | 3.06 | NA* |
11/29/18 | 2.20 | 3.03 | NA* |
12/06/18 | 2.20 | 2.87 | NA* |
12/13/18 | 2.19 | 2.91 | NA* |
12/20/18 | 2.40 | 2.79 | NA* |
12/27/18 | 2.40 | 2.77 | NA* |
01/03/19 | 2.40 | 2.56 | NA* |
01/10/19 | 2.40 | 2.74 | NA* |
01/17/19 | 2.40 | 2.75 | NA* |
01/24/19 | 2.40 | 2.72 | NA* |
01/31/19 | 2.40 | 2.63 | NA* |
02/07/19 | 2.40 | 2.63 | NA* |
02/14/19 | 2.40 | 2.66 | NA* |
02/21/19 | 2.40 | 2.69 | NA* |
02/28/19 | 2.40 | 2.73 | NA* |
03/07/19 | 2.40 | 2.64 | NA* |
03/14/19 | 2.40 | 2.63 | NA* |
03/21/19 | 2.41 | 2.54 | NA* |
03/28/19 | 2.41 | 2.39 | NA* |
04/04/19 | 2.41 | 2.51 | NA* |
04/11/19 | 2.41 | 2.51 | NA* |
04/18/19 | 2.43 | 2.57 | NA* |
04/25/19 | 2.44 | 2.54 | NA* |
05/02/19 | 2.41 | 2.55 | NA* |
05/09/19 | 2.38 | 2.45 | NA* |
05/16/19 | 2.39 | 2.40 | NA* |
05/23/19 | 2.38 | 2.31 | NA* |
05/30/19 | 2.39 | 2.22 | NA* |
06/06/19 | 2.37 | 2.12 | NA* |
06/13/19 | 2.37 | 2.10 | NA* |
06/20/19 | 2.37 | 2.01 | NA* |
06/27/19 | 2.38 | 2.01 | NA* |
07/03/19 | 2.41 | 1.96 | NA |
07/11/19 | 2.40 | 1.85 | NA* |
07/18/19 | 2.41 | 2.04 | NA* |
07/25/19 | 2.40 | 2.08 | NA* |
08/01/19 | 2.14 | 1.90 | NA* |
08/08/19 | 2.12 | 1.72 | NA* |
08/15/19 | 2.13 | 1.52 | NA* |
08/22/19 | 2.12 | 1.62 | NA* |
08/29/19 | 2.12 | 1.50 | NA* |
09/05/19 | 2.13 | 1.57 | NA* |
09/12/19 | 2.13 | 1.79 | NA* |
09/19/19 | 1.90 | 1.79 | NA* |
09/26/19 | 1.85 | 1.70 | NA* |
10/03/19 | 1.83 | 1.54 | NA* |
10/10/19 | 1.83 | 1.67 | NA* |
10/17/19 | 1.85 | 1.76 | NA* |
10/24/19 | 1.85 | 1.77 | NA* |
10/31/19 | 1.58 | 1.69 | NA* |
11/07/19 | 1.55 | 1.92 | NA* |
11/14/19 | 1.55 | 1.82 | NA* |
11/21/19 | 1.55 | 1.77 | NA* |
11/27/19 | 1.55 | 1.77 | NA* |
12/05/19 | 1.55 | 1.80 | NA* |
12/12/19 | 1.55 | 1.90 | NA* |
12/19/19 | 1.55 | 1.92 | NA* |
12/26/19 | 1.55 | 1.90 | NA* |
01/02/20 | 1.55 | 1.88 | NA* |
01/09/20 | 1.55 | 1.85 | NA* |
01/16/20 | 1.54 | 1.81 | NA* |
01/23/20 | 1.55 | 1.74 | NA* |
01/30/20 | 1.60 | 1.57 | NA* |
02/06/20 | 1.59 | 1.65 | NA* |
02/13/20 | 1.59 | 1.61 | NA* |
02/20/20 | 1.59 | 1.59 | NA* |
02/27/20 | 1.58 | 1.30 | NA* |
03/05/20 | 1.09 | 0.92 | NA* |
03/12/20 | 1.10 | 0.88 | NA* |
03/19/20 | 0.20 | 1.12 | NA* |
03/26/20 | 0.10 | 0.83 | NA* |
04/02/20 | 0.05 | 0.63 | NA* |
04/09/20 | 0.05 | 0.73 | NA* |
04/16/20 | 0.05 | 0.61 | NA* |
04/23/20 | 0.04 | 0.61 | NA* |
04/30/20 | 0.05 | 0.64 | NA* |
05/07/20 | 0.05 | 0.63 | NA* |
05/14/20 | 0.05 | 0.63 | NA* |
05/21/20 | 0.05 | 0.68 | NA* |
05/28/20 | 0.05 | 0.70 | NA* |
06/04/20 | 0.09 | 0.82 | NA* |
06/11/20 | 0.12 | 0.66 | NA* |
06/18/20 | 0.09 | 0.71 | NA* |
06/25/20 | 0.08 | 0.68 | NA* |
07/01/20 | 0.08 | 0.69 | NA |
*Note: The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System discontinued the publication of the BAA bond yield.
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
https://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/
Chart VIII-2 of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System provides the rate of US dollars (USD) per euro (EUR), USD/EUR. The rate appreciated from USD 1.1390/EUR on Jun 26, 2019 to USD 1.1215/EUR on Jun 26, 2020 or 1.5 percent. The euro has devalued 41.4 percent relative to the dollar from the high on Jul 15, 2008 to Jul 3, 2020. US corporations with foreign transactions and net worth experience losses in their balance sheets in converting revenues from depreciated currencies to the dollar. Corporate profits with IVA and CCA decreased at 0.2 percent in IIIQ2019 and increased at 0.6 percent after taxes. Corporate profits with IVA and CCA increased at 2.6 percent in IVQ2019 and increased at 2.1 percent after taxes. Corporate profits with IVA and CCA decreased at 12.3 percent in IVQ2019 and decreased at 12.4 percent after taxes. Corporate profits with IVA and CCA decreased at 6.9 percent in IQ2020 relative to IQ2019 and profits after tax with IVA and CCA decreased 6.6 percent in IQ2020 relative to IQ2019. Net dividends increased at 1.7 percent in IIQ2019. Net dividends decreased at 0.5 percent in IIIQ2019. Net dividends increased at 1.0 percent in IVQ2019. Net dividends increased at 1.7 percent in IQ2020. Net dividends increased 3.9 percent in IQ2020 relative to a year earlier. Undistributed profits increased at 9.4 percent in IIQ2019. Undistributed profits increased at 3.6 percent in IIIQ2019. Undistributed profits increased at 5.1 percent in IVQ2019. Undistributed profits decreased at 46.6 percent in IQ2020. Undistributed profits decreased at 36.5 percent in IQ2020 relative to IQ2019. The investment decision of United States corporations has been fractured in the current economic cycle in preference of cash. There is increase in corporate profits from devaluing the dollar with unconventional monetary policy of zero interest rates and decrease of corporate profits in revaluing the dollar with attempts at “normalization” or increases in interest rates. Conflicts arise while other central banks differ in their adjustment process. The current account deficit seasonally adjusted at 2.1 percent in IIQ2018 increases to 2.4 percent in IIIQ2018. The current account deficit increases to 2.8 percent in IVQ2018. The current account deficit decreases to 2.6 percent in IQ2019. The current account deficit decreases to 2.4 percent in IIQ2019. The absolute value of the net international investment position increases from minus $8.9 trillion in IIQ2018 to minus $9.7 trillion in IIIQ2018. The absolute value of the net international investment position stabilizes to $9.6 trillion in IIIQ2018. The absolute value of the net international investment position increases at $10.1 trillion in IQ2019. The absolute value of the net international investment position stabilizes to $10.1 trillion in IIQ2019. The BEA explains as follows (https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2019-09/intinv219.pdf):
“The U.S. net international investment position, the difference between U.S. residents’ foreign financial assets and liabilities, was –$10.56 trillion at the end of the second quarter of 2019, according to statistics released by the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA). Assets totaled $28.01 trillion and liabilities were $38.56 trillion.
At the end of the first quarter, the net investment position was –$10.16 trillion (Table1.”
The BEA explains further (https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2019-09/intinv219.pdf):
“U.S. assets increased by $952.7 billion, to a total of $28.01 trillion, at the end of the second quarter, reflecting increases in all major categories of assets, particularly in portfolio investment and direct investment assets. Portfolio investment assets increased by $366.4 billion, to $12.68 trillion, and direct investment assets increased by $232.8 billion, to $8.39 trillion. These increases were driven mainly by foreign stock price increases that raised the value of these assets.
U.S. liabilities increased by $1.35 trillion, to a total of $38.56 trillion, at the end of the second quarter, reflecting increases in all major categories of liabilities, particularly in portfolio investment liabilities. Portfolio investment liabilities increased by $665.3 billion, to $20.62 trillion, driven mainly by U.S. stock and bond price increases that raised the value of these liabilities.”
Chart VIII-2, Exchange Rate of US Dollars (USD) per Euro (EUR), Jun 26, 2019 to Jun 26, 2020
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
https://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/H10/default.htm
Chart VIII-3 of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System provides the yield of the 10-year Treasury constant maturity note from 0.62 percent on Apr 3, 2020 to 0.69 percent on Jul 1, 2020. There is turbulence in financial markets originating in a combination of intentions of decreasing the US policy fed funds rate, quantitative easing in the United States, Europe and Japan and increasing perception of financial/economic risks.
Chart VIII-3, Yield of Ten-year Constant Maturity Treasury, Apr 3, 2020 to Jul 1, 2020
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
https://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15
IX Conclusion. The departing theoretical framework of Bordo and Haubrich (2012DR) is the plucking model of Friedman (1964, 1988). Friedman (1988, 1) recalls, “I was led to the model in the course of investigating the direction of influence between money and income. Did the common cyclical fluctuation in money and income reflect primarily the influence of money on income or of income on money?” Friedman (1964, 1988) finds useful for this purpose to analyze the relation between expansions and contractions. Analyzing the business cycle in the United States between 1870 and 1961, Friedman (1964, 15) found that “a large contraction in output tends to be followed on the average by a large business expansion; a mild contraction, by a mild expansion.” The depth of the contraction opens up more room in the movement toward full employment (Friedman 1964, 17):
“Output is viewed as bumping along the ceiling of maximum feasible output except that every now and then it is plucked down by a cyclical contraction. Given institutional rigidities and prices, the contraction takes in considerable measure the form of a decline in output. Since there is no physical limit to the decline short of zero output, the size of the decline in output can vary widely. When subsequent recovery sets in, it tends to return output to the ceiling; it cannot go beyond, so there is an upper limit to output and the amplitude of the expansion tends to be correlated with the amplitude of the contraction.”
Kim and Nelson (1999) test the asymmetric plucking model of Friedman (1964, 1988) relative to a symmetric model using reference cycles of the NBER and find evidence supporting the Friedman model. Bordo and Haubrich (2012DR) analyze 27 cycles beginning in 1872, using various measures of financial crises while considering different regulatory and monetary regimes. The revealing conclusion of Bordo and Haubrich (2012DR, 2) is that:
“Our analysis of the data shows that steep expansions tend to follow deep contractions, though this depends heavily on when the recovery is measured. In contrast to much conventional wisdom, the stylized fact that deep contractions breed strong recoveries is particularly true when there is a financial crisis. In fact, on average, it is cycles without a financial crisis that show the weakest relation between contraction depth and recovery strength. For many configurations, the evidence for a robust bounce-back is stronger for cycles with financial crises than those without.”
The average rate of growth of real GDP in expansions after recessions with financial crises was 8 percent but only 6.9 percent on average for recessions without financial crises (Bordo 2012Sep27). Real GDP declined 12 percent in the Panic of 1907 and increased 13 percent in the recovery, consistent with the plucking model of Friedman (Bordo 2012Sep27). Bordo (2012Sep27) finds two probable explanations for the weak recovery during the current economic cycle: (1) collapse of United States housing; and (2) uncertainty originating in fiscal policy, regulation and structural changes. There are serious doubts if monetary policy is adequate to recover the economy under these conditions.
Lucas (2011May) estimates US economic growth in the long-term at 3 percent per year and about 2 percent per year in per capita terms. There are displacements from this trend caused by events such as wars and recessions but the economy grows much faster during the expansion, compensating for the contraction and maintaining trend growth over the entire cycle. Historical US GDP data exhibit remarkable growth: Lucas (2011May) estimates an increase of US real income per person by a factor of 12 in the period from 1870 to 2010. The explanation by Lucas (2011May) of this remarkable growth experience is that government provided stability and education while elements of “free-market capitalism” were an important driver of long-term growth and prosperity. Lucas sharpens this analysis by comparison with the long-term growth experience of G7 countries (US, UK, France, Germany, Canada, Italy and Japan) and Spain from 1870 to 2010. Countries benefitted from “common civilization” and “technology” to “catch up” with the early growth leaders of the US and UK, eventually growing at a faster rate. Significant part of this catch up occurred after World War II. Lucas (2011May) finds that the catch up stalled in the 1970s. The analysis of Lucas (2011May) is that the 20-40 percent gap that developed originated in differences in relative taxation and regulation that discouraged savings and work incentives in comparison with the US. A larger welfare and regulatory state, according to Lucas (2011May), could be the cause of the 20-40 percent gap. Cobet and Wilson (2002) provide estimates of output per hour and unit labor costs in national currency and US dollars for the US, Japan and Germany from 1950 to 2000 (see Pelaez and Pelaez, The Global Recession Risk (2007), 137-44). The average yearly rate of productivity change from 1950 to 2000 was 2.9 percent in the US, 6.3 percent for Japan and 4.7 percent for Germany while unit labor costs in USD increased at 2.6 percent in the US, 4.7 percent in Japan and 4.3 percent in Germany. From 1995 to 2000, output per hour increased at the average yearly rate of 4.6 percent in the US, 3.9 percent in Japan and 2.6 percent in Germany while unit labor costs in USD fell at minus 0.7 percent in the US, 4.3 percent in Japan and 7.5 percent in Germany. There was increase in productivity growth in Japan and France within the G7 in the second half of the 1990s but significantly lower than the acceleration of 1.3 percentage points per year in the US. The key indicator of growth of real income per capita, which is what a person earns after inflation, measures long-term economic growth and prosperity. A refined concept would include real disposable income per capita, which is what a person earns after inflation and taxes.
Table IB-1 provides the data required for broader comparison of long-term and cyclical performance of the United States economy. Revisions and enhancements of United States GDP and personal income accounts by the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) (https://bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm) provide valuable information on long-term growth and cyclical behavior. First, Long-term performance. Using annual data, US GDP grew at the average rate of 3.2 percent per year from 1929 to 2019 and at 3.2 percent per year from 1947 to 2019. Real disposable income grew at the average yearly rate of 3.2 percent from 1929 to 2019 and at 3.7 percent from 1947 to 1999. Real disposable income per capita grew at the average yearly rate of 2.0 percent from 1929 to 2019 and at 2.3 percent from 1947 to 1999. US economic growth was much faster during expansions, compensating contractions in maintaining trend growth for whole cycles. Using annual data, US real disposable income grew at the average yearly rate of 3.5 percent from 1980 to 1989 and real disposable income per capita at 2.6 percent. The US economy has lost its dynamism in the current cycle: real disposable income grew at the yearly average rate of 2.2 percent from 2006 to 2019 and real disposable income per capita at 1.5 percent. Real disposable income grew at the average rate of 2.2 percent from 2007 to 2019 and real disposable income per capita at 1.5 percent. Table IB-1 illustrates the contradiction of long-term growth with the proposition of secular stagnation (Hansen 1938, 1938, 1941 with early critique by Simons (1942). Secular stagnation would occur over long periods. Table IB-1 also provides the corresponding rates of population growth that is only marginally lower at 0.8 to 0.9 percent recently from 1.1 percent over the long-term. GDP growth fell abruptly from 2.6 percent on average from 2000 to 2006 to 1.7 percent from 2006 to 2019 and 1.7 percent from 2007 to 2019 and real disposable income growth fell from 2.9 percent on average from 2000 to 2006 to 2.2 percent from 2006 to 2019 and 2.2 percent from 2007 to 2019. The decline of growth of real per capita disposable income is even sharper from average 1.9 percent from 2000 to 2006 to 1.5 percent from 2006 to 2019 and 1.5 percent from 2007 to 2019 while population growth was 0.8 percent on average. Lazear and Spletzer (2012JHJul122) provide theory and measurements showing that cyclic factors explain currently depressed labor markets. This is also the case of the overall economy. Second, first four quarters of expansion. Growth in the first four quarters of expansion is critical in recovering loss of output and employment occurring during the contraction. In the first four quarters of expansion from IQ1983 to IVQ1983: GDP increased 7.9 percent, real disposable personal income 5.5 percent and real disposable income per capita 4.5 percent. In the first four quarters of expansion from IIIQ2009 to IIQ2010: GDP increased 2.8 percent, real disposable personal income 1.0 percent and real disposable income per capita 0.2 percent. Third, first 43 quarters of expansion. In the expansion from IQ1983 to IIIQ1993: GDP grew 46.4 percent at the annual equivalent rate of 3.6 percent; real disposable income grew 40.6 percent at the annual equivalent rate of 3.2 percent; and real disposable income per capita grew 25.7 percent at the annual equivalent rate of 2.2 percent. The National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) dates a contraction of the US from IQ1990 (Jul) to IQ1991 (Mar) (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html). The expansion lasted until another contraction beginning in IQ2001 (Mar). US GDP contracted 1.3 percent from the pre-recession peak of $8983.9 billion of chained 2009 dollars in IIIQ1990 to the trough of $8865.6 billion in IQ1991 (https://bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm).
In the expansion from IIIQ2009 to IQ2020: GDP grew 25.5 percent at the annual equivalent rate of 2.1 percent; real disposable income grew 29.1 percent at the annual equivalent rate of 2.4 percent; and real disposable personal income per capita grew 20.2 percent at the annual equivalent rate of 1.7 percent. Fourth, entire quarterly cycle. In the entire cycle combining contraction and expansion from IQ1980 to IIIQ1993: GDP grew 46.1 percent at the annual equivalent rate of 2.7 percent; real disposable personal income grew 49.0 percent at the annual equivalent rate of 2.9 percent; and real disposable personal income per capita 29.3 percent at the annual equivalent rate of 1.9 percent. The National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) dates a contraction of the US from IQ1990 (Jul) to IQ1991 (Mar) (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html). The expansion lasted until another contraction beginning in IQ2001 (Mar). US GDP contracted 1.3 percent from the pre-recession peak of $8983.9 billion of chained 2009 dollars in IIIQ1990 to the trough of $8865.6 billion in IQ1991 (https://bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm). In the entire cycle combining contraction and expansion from IVQ2007 to IQ2020: GDP grew 20.5 percent at the annual equivalent rate of 1.5 percent; real disposable personal income increased 31.0 percent at the annual equivalent rate of 2.2 percent; and real disposable personal income per capita grew 20.4 percent at the annual equivalent rate of 1.5 percent. The United States grew during its history at high rates of per capita income that made its economy the largest in the world. That dynamism is disappearing. Bordo (2012 Sep27) and Bordo and Haubrich (2012DR) provide convincing evidence that recoveries have been faster after deeper recessions and recessions with financial crises, casting serious doubts on the conventional explanation of weak growth during the current expansion allegedly because of the depth of the contraction of 4.0 percent from IVQ2007 to IIQ2009 and the financial crisis. There was sharp contraction of US GDP at the SAAR of 4.8 percent in IQ2020 in the probable global recession of the lockdown of economic activity of the COVID-19 event (https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/05/mediocre-cyclical-united-states.html). The proposition of secular stagnation should explain a long-term process of decay and not the actual abrupt collapse of the economy and labor markets currently.
Table IB-1, US, GDP, Real Disposable Personal Income, Real Disposable Income per Capita and Population Long-term and in 1983-92 and 2007-2019, %
Long-term Average ∆% per Year | GDP | Population | |
1929-2019 | 3.2 | 1.1 | |
1947-2019 | 3.2 | 1.2 | |
1947-1999 | 3.6 | 1.3 | |
1980-1989 | 3.5 | 0.9 | |
2000-2019 | 2.0 | 0.8 | |
2000-2006 | 2.6 | 0.9 | |
2006-2019 | 1.7 | 0.7 | |
2007-2019 | 1.7 | 0.7 | |
Long-term Average ∆% per Year | Real Disposable Income | Real Disposable Income per Capita | Population |
1929-2019 | 3.2 | 2.0 | 1.1 |
1947-1999 | 3.7 | 2.3 | 1.3 |
2000-2019 | 2.4 | 1.6 | 0.8 |
2000-2006 | 2.9 | 1.9 | 0.9 |
2006-2019 | 2.2 | 1.5 | 0.7 |
2007-2019 | 2.2 | 1.5 | 0.7 |
Whole Cycles Average ∆% per Year | |||
1980-1989 | 3.5 | 2.6 | 0.9 |
2006-2019 | 2.2 | 1.5 | 0.7 |
2007-2019 | 2.2 | 1.5 | 0.7 |
Comparison of Cycles | # Quarters | ∆% | ∆% Annual Equivalent |
GDP | |||
I83 to IV83 I83 to IQ87 I83 to II87 I83 to III87 I83 to IV87 I83 to I88 I83 to II88 I83 to III88 I83 to IV88 I83 to I89 I83 to II89 I83 to III89 I83 to IV89 I83 to I90 I83 to II90 I83 to III90 I83 to IV90 I83 to I91 I83 to II91 I83 to III91 I83 to IV91 I83 to I92 I83 to II92 I83 to III92 I83 to IV92 I83 to I93 I83 to II93 I83 to III93 | 4 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 | 7.9 23.0 24.4 25.4 27.6 28.3 29.9 30.7 32.5 33.8 34.8 35.8 36.1 37.6 38.1 38.2 36.9 36.3 37.3 38.0 38.5 40.2 41.7 43.1 44.6 44.8 45.7 46.4 | 7.9 5.0 5.0 4.9 5.0 4.9 4.9 4.8 4.8 4.8 4.7 4.6 4.5 4.5 4.4 4.3 4.0 3.8 3.8 3.8 3.7 3.7 3.7 3.7 3.8 3.7 3.6 3.6 |
RDPI | |||
I83 to IV83 I83 to I87 I83 to III87 I83 to IV87 I83 to I88 I83 to II88 I83 to III88 I83 to IV88 I83 to I89 I83 to II89 I83 to III89 I83 to IV89 I83 to I90 I83 to II90 I83 to III90 I83 to IV90 I83 to I91 I83 to II91 I83 to III91 I83 to IV91 I83 to I92 I83 to II92 I83 to III92 I83 to IV92 I83 to I93 I83 to II93 I83 to III93 | 4 17 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 | 5.5 19.4 20.4 22.1 23.9 25.1 26.3 27.5 29.0 28.6 29.5 30.5 31.5 32.5 32.4 31.2 31.6 32.6 33.1 34.2 36.9 38.3 38.9 39.6 40.1 40.5 40.6 | 5.5 4.3 4.0 4.1 4.2 4.2 4.1 4.1 4.2 3.9 3.9 3.9 3.9 3.8 3.7 3.5 3.4 3.4 3.3 3.3 3.5 3.5 3.4 3.4 3.3 3.3 3.2 |
RDPI Per Capita | |||
I83 to IV83 I83 to I87 I83 to III87 I83 to IV87 I83 to I88 I83 to II88 I83 to III88 I83 to IV88 I83 to I89 I83 to II89 I83 to III89 I83 to IV89 I83 to I90 I83 to II90 I83 to III90 I83 to IV90 I83 to I91 I83 to II91 I83 to III91 I83 to IV91 I83 to I92 I83 to II92 I83 to III92 I83 to IV92 I83 to I93 I83 to II93 I83 to III93 | 4 17 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 | 4.5 15.0 15.5 16.7 18.2 19.2 20.0 20.8 22.0 21.3 21.8 22.5 23.2 23.6 23.2 21.7 21.6 22.1 22.2 22.8 24.9 25.7 25.8 25.9 26.0 26.0 25.7 | 4.5 3.3 3.1 3.1 3.2 3.2 3.2 3.2 3.2 3.0 3.0 2.9 2.9 2.9 2.7 2.5 2.4 2.4 2.3 2.3 2.4 2.4 2.4 2.3 2.3 2.2 2.2 |
Whole Cycle IQ1980 to IIIQ1993 | |||
GDP | 56 | 46.1 | 2.7 |
RDPI | 56 | 49.0 | 2.9 |
RDPI per Capita | 56 | 29.3 | 1.9 |
Population | 56 | 15.3 | 1.0 |
GDP | |||
III09 to II10 III09 to I20 | 4 43 | 2.8 25.5 | 2.8 2.1 |
RDPI | |||
III09 to II10 III09 to IQ20 | 4 43 | 1.0 29.1 | 1.0 2.4 |
RDPI per Capita | |||
III09 to II10 III09 to IQ20 | 4 43 | 0.2 20.2 | 0.2 1.7 |
Population | |||
III09 to II10 III09 to IQ20 | 4 43 | 0.8 7.4 | 0.8 0.7 |
IVQ2007 to IQ2020 | 49 | ||
GDP | 49 | 20.5 | 1.5 |
RDPI | 49 | 31.0 | 2.2 |
RDPI per Capita | 49 | 20.4 | 1.5 |
Population | 49 | 8.8 | 0.7 |
RDPI: Real Disposable Personal Income
Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis https://apps.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm
There are seven basic facts illustrating the current economic disaster of the United States:
- GDP maintained trend growth in the entire business cycle from IQ1980 to IQ1993, including contractions and expansions. The National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) dates a contraction of the US from IQ1990 (Jul) to IQ1991 (Mar) (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html). The expansion lasted until another contraction beginning in IQ2001 (Mar). US GDP contracted 1.3 percent from the pre-recession peak of $8983.9 billion of chained 2009 dollars in IIIQ1990 to the trough of $8865.6 billion in IQ1991 (https://bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm). GDP is well below trend in the entire business cycle from IVQ2007 to IQ2020, including contractions and expansions. GDP contracted the SAAR of 4.8 percent in IQ2020 in the probable global recession in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event (https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/05/mediocre-cyclical-united-states.html).
- Per capita real disposable income exceeded trend growth in the 1980s but is substantially below trend in IQ2020
- Level of employed persons increased in the 1980s but declined/stagnated cyclically into IQ2020 with recent recovery and sharp contraction in the probable global recession in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event.
- Level of full-time employed persons increased in the 1980s but declined/stagnated cyclically into IQ2020 with recent recovery and sharp contraction in the probable global recession in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event.
- Level unemployed, unemployment rate and employed part-time for economic reasons fell in the recovery from the recessions in the 1980s but not substantially in relative cyclical terms in the recovery since IIQ209 with recent recovery frustrated by the probable global recession in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event.
- Wealth of households and nonprofit organizations soared in the 1980s but stagnated in historically relative real terms into IVQ2019
- Gross private domestic investment increased sharply from IQ1980 to IIQ1993, but gross private domestic investment stagnated, and private fixed investment stagnated in relative cyclical terms from IVQ2007 into IQ2020 with recent recovery frustrated by the probable global recession in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event.
There are references to adverse periods as “lost decades.” There is a more prolonged and adverse period in Table V-3A: the lost economic cycle of the Global Recession with economic growth underperforming below trend worldwide. Economic contractions were relatively high but not comparable to the decline of GDP during the Great Depression. In fact, during the Great Depression in the four years of 1930 to 1933, US GDP in constant dollars fell 26.3 percent cumulatively and fell 45.3 percent in current dollars (Pelaez and Pelaez, Financial Regulation after the Global Recession (2009a), 150-2, Pelaez and Pelaez, Globalization and the State, Vol. II (2009b), 205-7 and revisions in http://bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm). Data are available for the 1930s only on a yearly basis. The contraction of GDP in the current cycle of the Global Recession was much lower, 4.0 percent (https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/06/mediocre-cyclical-united-states.html and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/05/mediocre-cyclical-united-states_31.html). Contractions were deeper in Japan, 8.6 percent, the euro area (19 members), 5.7 percent, Germany 6.9 percent and the UK 6.0 percent. The contraction in France was 3.9 percent. There is adversity in low rates of growth during the expansion that did not compensate for the contraction such that for the whole cycle performance is disappointingly low. As a result, GDP is substantially below what it would have been in trend growth in all countries and regions in the world. Long-term economic performance in the United States consisted of trend growth of GDP at 3 percent per year and of per capita GDP at 2 percent per year as measured for 1870 to 2010 by Robert E Lucas (2011May). The economy returned to trend growth after adverse events such as wars and recessions. The key characteristic of adversities such as recessions was much higher rates of growth in expansion periods that permitted the economy to recover output, income and employment losses that occurred during the contractions. Over the business cycle, the economy compensated the losses of contractions with higher growth in expansions to maintain trend growth of GDP of 3 percent and of GDP per capita of 2 percent. The US maintained growth at 3.0 percent on average over entire cycles with expansions at higher rates compensating for contractions. US economic growth has been at only 2.1 percent on average in the cyclical expansion in the 43 quarters from IIIQ2009 to IQ2020 and in the global recession with output in the US reaching a high in Feb 2020 (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html), in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event. Boskin (2010Sep) measures that the US economy grew at 6.2 percent in the first four quarters and 4.5 percent in the first 12 quarters after the trough in the second quarter of 1975; and at 7.7 percent in the first four quarters and 5.8 percent in the first 12 quarters after the trough in the first quarter of 1983 (Professor Michael J. Boskin, Summer of Discontent, Wall Street Journal, Sep 2, 2010 http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052748703882304575465462926649950.html). There are new calculations using the revision of US GDP and personal income data since 1929 by the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) (http://bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm) and the third estimate of GDP for IQ2020 (https://www.bea.gov/sites/default/files/2020-06/gdp1q20_3rd.pdf). The average of 7.7 percent in the first four quarters of major cyclical expansions is in contrast with the rate of growth in the first four quarters of the expansion from IIIQ2009 to IIQ2010 of only 2.8 percent obtained by dividing GDP of $15,557.3 billion in IIQ2010 by GDP of $15,134.1 billion in IIQ2009 {[($15,557.3/$15,134.1) -1]100 = 2.8%], or accumulating the quarter on quarter growth rates (https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/06/mediocre-cyclical-united-states.html and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/05/mediocre-cyclical-united-states_31.html). The expansion from IQ1983 to IQ1986 was at the average annual growth rate of 5.7 percent, 5.3 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1986, 5.1 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1986, 5.0 percent from IQ1983 to IQ1987, 5.0 percent from IQ1983 to IIQ1987, 4.9 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1987, 5.0 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1987, 4.9 percent from IQ1983 to IIQ1988, 4.8 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1988, 4.8 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1988, 4.8 percent from IQ1983 to IQ1989, 4.7 percent from IQ1983 to IIQ1989, 4.6 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1989, 4.5 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1989. 4.5 percent from IQ1983 to IQ1990, 4.4 percent from IQ1983 to IIQ1990, 4.3 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1990, 4.0 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1990, 3.8 percent from IQ1983 to IQ1991, 3.8 percent from IQ1983 to IIQ1991, 3.8 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1991, 3.7 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1991, 3.7 percent from IQ1983 to IQ1992, 3.7 percent from IQ1983 to IIQ1992, 3.7 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ2019, 3.8 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1992, 3.7 percent from IQ1983 to IQ1993, 3.6 percent from IQ1983 to IIQ1993, 3.6 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1993 and at 7.9 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1983 (https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/06/mediocre-cyclical-united-states.html and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/05/mediocre-cyclical-united-states_31.html). The National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) dates a contraction of the US from IQ1990 (Jul) to IQ1991 (Mar) (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html). The expansion lasted until another contraction beginning in IQ2001 (Mar). US GDP contracted 1.3 percent from the pre-recession peak of $8983.9 billion of chained 2009 dollars in IIIQ1990 to the trough of $8865.6 billion in IQ1991 (https://apps.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm). The US maintained growth at 3.0 percent on average over entire cycles with expansions at higher rates compensating for contractions. Growth at trend in the entire cycle from IVQ2007 to IQ2020 and in the global recession with output in the US reaching a high in Feb 2020 (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html), in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event would have accumulated to 43.6 percent. GDP in IQ2020 would be $22,634.2 billion (in constant dollars of 2012) if the US had grown at trend, which is higher by $3656.8 billion than actual $18,977.4 billion. There are more than three trillion dollars of GDP less than at trend, explaining the 41.3 million unemployed or underemployed equivalent to actual unemployment/underemployment of 23.9 percent of the effective labor force with the largest part originating in the global recession with output in the US reaching a high in Feb 2020 (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html), in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event (Section I and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/06/creation-of-three-million-private.html). Unemployment is decreasing while employment is increasing in initial adjustment of the lockdown of economic activity in the global recession resulting from the COVID-19 event (https://www.bls.gov/cps/employment-situation-covid19-faq-june-2020.pdf). US GDP in IQ2020 is 16.2 percent lower than at trend. US GDP grew from $15,762.0 billion in IVQ2007 in constant dollars to $18,977.4 billion in IQ2020 or 20.4 percent at the average annual equivalent rate of 1.5 percent. Professor John H. Cochrane (2014Jul2) estimates US GDP at more than 10 percent below trend. Cochrane (2016May02) measures GDP growth in the US at average 3.5 percent per year from 1950 to 2000 and only at 1.76 percent per year from 2000 to 2015 with only at 2.0 percent annual equivalent in the current expansion. Cochrane (2016May02) proposes drastic changes in regulation and legal obstacles to private economic activity. The US missed the opportunity to grow at higher rates during the expansion and it is difficult to catch up because growth rates in the final periods of expansions tend to decline. The US missed the opportunity for recovery of output and employment always afforded in the first four quarters of expansion from recessions. Zero interest rates and quantitative easing were not required or present in successful cyclical expansions and in secular economic growth at 3.0 percent per year and 2.0 percent per capita as measured by Lucas (2011May). There is cyclical uncommonly slow growth in the US instead of allegations of secular stagnation. There is similar behavior in manufacturing. There is classic research on analyzing deviations of output from trend (see for example Schumpeter 1939, Hicks 1950, Lucas 1975, Sargent and Sims 1977). The long-term trend is growth of manufacturing at average 2.9 percent per year from May 1919 to May 2020. Growth at 2.9 percent per year would raise the NSA index of manufacturing output (SIC, Standard Industrial Classification) from 108.2987 in Dec 2007 to 154.4475 in May 2020. The actual index NSA in May 2020 is 87.3585 which is 43.4 percent below trend. The underperformance of manufacturing in May 2020 originates partly in the earlier global recession augmented by the current global recession with output in the US reaching a high in Feb 2020 (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html), in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19. Manufacturing grew at the average annual rate of 3.3 percent between Dec 1986 and Dec 2006. Growth at 3.3 percent per year would raise the NSA index of manufacturing output (SIC, Standard Industrial Classification) from 108.2987 in Dec 2007 to 162.0699 in May 2020. The actual index NSA in May 2020 is 87.3585, which is 46.1 percent below trend. Manufacturing output grew at average 1.4 percent between Dec 1986 and May 2020. Using trend growth of 1.4 percent per year, the index would increase to 128.7047 in May 2020. The output of manufacturing at 87.3585 in May 2020 is 32.1 percent below trend under this alternative calculation. Using the NAICS (North American Industry Classification System), manufacturing output fell from the high of 110.5147 in Jun 2007 to the low of 86.3800 in Apr 2009 or 21.8 percent. The NAICS manufacturing index increased from 86.3800 in Apr 2009 to 88.2710 in May 2020 or 2.2 percent. The NAICS manufacturing index increased at the annual equivalent rate of 3.5 percent from Dec 1986 to Dec 2006. Growth at 3.5 percent would increase the NAICS manufacturing output index from 106.6777 in Dec 2007 to 163.5246 in May 2020. The NAICS index at 88.2710 in May 2020 is 46.0 below trend. The NAICS manufacturing output index grew at 1.7 percent annual equivalent from Dec 1999 to Dec 2006. Growth at 1.7 percent would raise the NAICS manufacturing output index from 106.6777 in Dec 2007 to 131.5151 in May 2020. The NAICS index at 88.2710 in May 2020 is 32.9 percent below trend under this alternative calculation.
Table V-3A, Cycle 2007-2020, Percentage Contraction, Average Growth Rate in Expansion, Average Growth Rate in Whole Cycle and GDP Percent Below Trend
Contraction ∆% | Expansion Average ∆% | Whole Cycle Average ∆% | Below Trend Percent | |
USA | 4.0 | 2.1 | 1.5 | 16.2 |
Japan | 8.6 | 1.2 | 0.3 | NA |
Euro Area 19 | 5.7 | 1.0 | 0.4 | 20.2 |
France | 3.9 | 0.8 | 0.4 | 15.4 |
Germany | 7.0 | 1.7 | 0.9 | NA |
UK | 6.0 | 1.6 | 0.9 | 20.1 |
Note: AV: Average. Expansion and Whole Cycle AV ∆% calculated with quarterly growth, seasonally adjusted and quarterly adjusted when applicable, rates and converted into annual equivalent. Combines the Global Recession after 2007 and the COVID-19 Global Recession after IQ2020.
Data reported periodically in this blog.
Source: Country Statistical Agencies https://www.bls.gov/bls/other.htm https://www.census.gov/programs-surveys/international-programs/about/related-sites.html
There is a critical issue of the United States economy will be able in the future to attain again the level of activity and prosperity of projected trend growth. Growth at trend during the entire business cycles built the largest economy in the world but there may be an adverse, permanent weakness in United States economic performance and prosperity. Table IB-2 provides data for analysis of these seven basic facts. The seven blocks of Table IB-2 are separated initially after individual discussion of each one followed by the full Table IB-2.
1. Trend Growth.
i. As shown in Table IB-2, actual GDP grew cumulatively 45.6 percent from IQ1980 to IIIQ1993, which is relatively close to what trend growth would have been at 51.3 percent. Real GDP grew 44.5 percent from IVQ1979 to IIQ1993. Rapid growth at the average annual rate of 3.6 percent per quarter during the expansion from IQ1983 to IIIQ1993 erased the loss of GDP of 4.7 percent during the contractions and maintained relatively close trend growth at 2.7 percent for GDP and 2.9 percent for real disposable personal income over the entire cycle. The National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) dates a contraction of the US from IQ1990 (Jul) to IQ1991 (Mar) (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html). The expansion lasted until another contraction beginning in IQ2001 (Mar). US GDP contracted 1.3 percent from the pre-recession peak of $8983.9 billion of chained 2009 dollars in IIIQ1990 to the trough of $8865.6 billion in IQ1991 (https://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm).
ii. In contrast, cumulative growth from IVQ2007 to IQ2020 was 20.5 percent while trend growth would have been 43.6 percent. The US maintained growth at 3.0 percent on average over entire cycles with expansions at higher rates compensating for contractions. Growth at trend in the entire cycle from IVQ2007 to IQ2020 and the lockdown of economic activity in COVID-19 would have accumulated to 43.6 percent. GDP in IQ2020 would be $22,634.2 billion (in constant dollars of 2012) if the US had grown at trend, which is higher by $3646.3 billion than actual $18,987.9 billion. There are more than three trillion dollars of GDP less than at trend, explaining the 51.6 million unemployed or underemployed equivalent to actual unemployment/underemployment of 30.0 percent of the effective labor force with the largest part originating in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event (https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/05/fifty-two-million-unemployed-or.html and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/04/lockdown-of-economic-activity-in.html). Unemployment is increasing sharply while employment is declining rapidly because of the lockdown of economic activity in the probable global recession resulting from the COVID-19 event (https://www.bls.gov/cps/employment-situation-covid19-faq-april-2020.pdf). US GDP in IQ2020 is 16.1 percent lower than at trend. US GDP grew from $15,762.0 billion in IVQ2007 in constant dollars to $18,987.9 billion in IQ2020 or 20.5 percent at the average annual equivalent rate of 1.5 percent. Professor John H. Cochrane (2014Jul2) estimates US GDP at more than 10 percent below trend. Cochrane (2016May02) measures GDP growth in the US at average 3.5 percent per year from 1950 to 2000 and only at 1.76 percent per year from 2000 to 2015 with only at 2.0 percent annual equivalent in the current expansion. Cochrane (2016May02) proposes drastic changes in regulation and legal obstacles to private economic activity. The US missed the opportunity to grow at higher rates during the expansion and it is difficult to catch up because growth rates in the final periods of expansions tend to decline. The US missed the opportunity for recovery of output and employment always afforded in the first four quarters of expansion from recessions. Zero interest rates and quantitative easing were not required or present in successful cyclical expansions and in secular economic growth at 3.0 percent per year and 2.0 percent per capita as measured by Lucas (2011May). There is cyclical uncommonly slow growth in the US instead of allegations of secular stagnation. There is similar behavior in manufacturing. There is classic research on analyzing deviations of output from trend (see for example Schumpeter 1939, Hicks 1950, Lucas 1975, Sargent and Sims 1977). The long-term trend is growth of manufacturing at average 2.9 percent per year from Apr 1919 to Apr 2020. Growth at 2.9 percent per year would raise the NSA index of manufacturing output (SIC, Standard Industrial Classification) from 108.2987 in Dec 2007 to 154.0798 in Apr 2020. The actual index NSA in Apr 2020 is 84.8550 which is 44.9 percent below trend. The deterioration of manufacturing in Apr 2020 originates in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event. Manufacturing grew at the average annual rate of 3.3 percent between Dec 1986 and Dec 2006. Growth at 3.3 percent per year would raise the NSA index of manufacturing output (SIC, Standard Industrial Classification) from 108.2987 in Dec 2007 to 161.6318 in Apr 2020. The actual index NSA in Apr 2020 is 84.8550, which is 47.5 percent below trend. Manufacturing output grew at average 1.3 percent between Dec 1986 and Apr 2020. Using trend growth of 1.3 percent per year, the index would increase to 127.0007 in Apr 2020. The output of manufacturing at 84.8550 in Apr 2020 is 33.2 percent below trend under this alternative calculation. Using the NAICS (North American Industry Classification System), manufacturing output fell from the high of 110.5147 in Jun 2007 to the low of 86.3800 in Apr 2009 or 21.8 percent. The NAICS manufacturing index decreased from 86.3800 in Apr 2009 to 85.8317 in Apr 2020 or minus 0.6 percent. The NAICS manufacturing index increased at the annual equivalent rate of 3.5 percent from Dec 1986 to Dec 2006. Growth at 3.5 percent would increase the NAICS manufacturing output index from 106.6777 in Dec 2007 to 163.0563 in Apr 2020. The NAICS index at 85.8317 in Apr 2020 is 47.4 below trend. The NAICS manufacturing output index grew at 1.7 percent annual equivalent from Dec 1999 to Dec 2006. Growth at 1.7 percent would raise the NAICS manufacturing output index from 106.6777 in Dec 2007 to 131.3304 in Apr 2020. The NAICS index at 85.8317 in Apr 2020 is 34.6 percent below trend under this alternative calculation.
Period IQ1980 to IIIQ1993 | |
GDP SAAR USD Billions | |
IQ1980 | 6,837.6 |
IIIQ1993 | 9,955.6 |
∆% IQ1980 to IIIQ1993 (46.1 percent from IVQ1979 $6816.2 billion) | 45.6 |
∆% Trend Growth IQ1980 to IIIQ1993 | 51.3 |
Period IVQ2007 to IQ2020 | |
GDP SAAR USD Billions | |
IVQ2007 | 15,762.0 |
IQ2020 | 18,987.9 |
∆% IVQ2007 to IQ2020 | 20.5 |
∆% IVQ2007 to IQ2020 Trend Growth | 43.6 |
2. Real Disposable Income
i. In the entire business cycle from IQ1980 to IIIQ1993, as shown in Table IB-2, per capita real disposable income, or what is left per person after inflation and taxes, grew cumulatively 29.2 percent, which is close to what would have been trend growth of 31.9 percent. The National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) dates a contraction of the US from IQ1990 (Jul) to IQ1991 (Mar) (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html). The expansion lasted until another contraction beginning in IQ2001 (Mar). US GDP contracted 1.3 percent from the pre-recession peak of $8983.9 billion of chained 2009 dollars in IIIQ1990 to the trough of $8865.6 billion in IQ1991 (https://bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm).
ii. In contrast, in the entire business cycle from IVQ2007 to IQ2020, per capita real disposable income increased 20.4 percent while trend growth would have been 27.5 percent. Income available after inflation and taxes is cyclically lower relative to the level before the contraction after 43 consecutive quarters of GDP growth at mediocre rates relative to those prevailing during historical cyclical expansions. Growth of personal income during the expansion has been tepid even with the new revisions. In IVQ2014, personal income grew at 5.3 percent in nominal terms while nominal disposable income grew at 4.9 percent in nominal terms and at 5.4 percent in real terms (Table 14 at https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2019-07/pi0619.pdf). In IQ2015, nominal personal income grew at 4.3 percent while nominal disposable income grew at 2.8 percent and at 4.6 percent in real terms (Table 14 at https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2019-07/pi0619.pdf). In IIQ2015, nominal personal income grew at 5.4 percent while nominal disposable income grew at 5.1 percent and real disposable income grew at 3.0 percent (Table 14 at https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2019-07/pi0619.pdf). In IIIQ2015, nominal personal income grew at 3.8 percent while nominal disposable income grew at 4.1 percent and real disposable income grew at 3.0 percent (Table 14 at https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2019-07/pi0619.pdf). In IVQ2015, nominal personal income grew at 1.2 percent while nominal disposable income grew at 0.9 percent and real disposable income at 1.3 percent (Table 14 at https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2019-07/pi0619.pdf). In IQ2016, personal income grew at 1.6 percent and fell at 2.1 percent excluding transfer receipts while nominal disposable income grew at 2.9 percent and real disposable income grew at 2.7 percent (Table 14 at https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2019-07/pi0619.pdf). In IIQ2016, personal income grew at 2.3 percent and at 2.2 percent excluding transfer receipts while nominal disposable income grew at 2.0 percent and real disposable income fell at 0.4 percent (Table 14 at https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2019-07/pi0619.pdf). In IIIQ2016, personal income grew at 3.7 percent and at 1.3 percent excluding transfer receipts while nominal disposable income grew at 3.5 percent and real disposable income grew at 1.8 percent (Table 14 at https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2019-07/pi0619.pdf). In IVQ2016, nominal personal income grew at 4.2 percent, decreasing at 2.6 percent excluding current transfers while disposable income grew at 4.3 percent and real disposable income increased at 2.4 percent (Table 14 at https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2019-07/pi0619.pdf). In IQ2017, nominal personal income grew at 6.6 percent and 4.7 percent excluding transfer receipts while nominal disposable income grew at 7.1 percent and real disposable income at 4.9 percent (Table 14 at https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2019-07/pi0619.pdf). In IIQ2017, nominal personal income grew at 3.6 percent and 2.4 percent excluding transfer receipts while nominal disposable income grew at 3.6 percent and real disposable income at 2.7 percent (Table 14 at https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2019-07/pi0619.pdf). In IIIQ2017, nominal personal income grew at 4.4 percent and at 2.5 percent excluding transfer receipts while nominal disposable income grew at 4.1 percent and real disposable personal income grew at 2.3 percent (Table 14 at https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2019-07/pi0619.pdf). In IVQ2017, nominal personal income grew at 7.3 percent and at 2.9 percent real excluding transfer receipts while nominal disposable income grew at 6.5 percent and real disposable personal income grew at 3.7 percent (Table 14 at https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2019-07/pi0619.pdf). In IQ2018, nominal personal income grew at 7.4 percent and at 4.6 percent real excluding transfer receipts while nominal disposable income grew at 9.6 percent and real disposable income grew at 6.9 percent (Table 6 at https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2019-09/pi0819.pdf). In IIQ2018, nominal personal income grew at 4.3 percent and at 2.1 percent real excluding transfer receipts while nominal disposable income grew at 4.9 percent and real disposable income grew at 2.7 percent (Table 6 at https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2019-12/pi1119.pdf). In IIIQ2018, nominal personal income grew at 4.7 percent and at 3.4 percent real excluding transfer receipts while nominal disposable income grew at 4.9 percent and real disposable income grew at 3.3 percent (Table 6 at https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2020-03/pi0220_1.pdf). In IVQ2018, nominal personal income grew at 3.5 percent and at 2.3 percent real excluding transfer receipts while nominal disposable income grew at 4.2 percent and real disposable income grew at 2.8 percent (Table 6 at https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2020-03/pi0220_1.pdf). In IQ2019, nominal personal income grew at 6.2 percent and at 4.0 real percent excluding transfer receipts while nominal disposable income grew at 4.9 percent and real disposable income grew at 4.5 percent (Table 6 at https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2020-03/pi0220_1.pdf). In IIQ2019, nominal personal income grew at 4.4 percent and at 1.7 real percent excluding transfer receipts while nominal disposable income grew at 3.9 percent and real disposable income grew at 1.5 percent (Table 6 at https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2020-03/pi0220_1.pdf). In IIIQ2019, nominal personal income grew at 2.6 percent and at 0.7 real percent excluding transfer receipts while nominal disposable income grew at 3.6 percent and real disposable income grew at 2.1 percent (Table 6 at https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2020-03/pi0220_1.pdf). In IVQ2019, nominal personal income grew at 3.1 percent and at 1.7 percent real excluding current transfers while nominal disposable income grew at 3.0 percent and real disposable income grew at 1.6 percent (Table 6 at https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2020-03/pi0220_1.pdf).
Period IQ1980 to IIIQ1993 | |
Real Disposable Personal Income per Capita IQ1980 Chained 2012 USD | 21,579 |
Real Disposable Personal Income per Capita IIIQ1993 Chained 2012 USD | 27,875 |
∆% IQ1980 to IIIQ1993 (29.3 percent from IVQ1979 $21,565) | 29.2 |
∆% Trend Growth | 31.9 |
Period IVQ2007 to IQ2020 | |
Real Disposable Personal Income per Capita IVQ2007 Chained 2012 USD | 38,037 |
Real Disposable Personal Income per Capita IQ2020 Chained 2012 USD | 45,800 |
∆% IVQ2007 to IQ2020 | 20.4 |
∆% Trend Growth | 27.5 |
3. Number of Employed Persons
i. As shown in Table IB-2, the number of employed persons increased over the entire business cycle from 98.527 million not seasonally adjusted (NSA) in IQ1980 to 120.673 million NSA in IIIQ1993 or by 22.5 percent. The National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) dates a contraction of the US from IQ1990 (Jul) to IQ1991 (Mar) (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html). The expansion lasted until another contraction beginning in IQ2001 (Mar). US GDP contracted 1.3 percent from the pre-recession peak of $8983.9 billion of chained 2009 dollars in IIIQ1990 to the trough of $8865.6 billion in IQ1991 (https://bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm).
ii. In contrast, during the entire business cycle the number employed nearly stagnated from 146.334 million in IVQ2007 to 155.167 million in IQI2020 or by 6.0 percent higher. There are 51.2 million unemployed or underemployed equivalent to actual unemployment/underemployment of 30.0 percent of the effective labor force (https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/05/fifty-two-million-unemployed-or.html and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/04/lockdown-of-economic-activity-in.html) caused by the lockdown of economic activity in the probable global recession in the COVID-19 event. The number employed in Apr 2020 was 133.326 million (NSA) or 13,989 million fewer people with jobs relative to the peak of 147.315 million in Aug 2007 while the civilian noninstitutional population of ages 16 years and over increased from 231.958 million in Jul 2007 to 259.896 million in Apr 2020 or by 27.938 million. The number employed decreased 9.5 percent from Jul 2007 to Apr 2020 while the noninstitutional civilian population of ages of 16 years and over, or those available for work, increased 12.0 percent. The ratio of employment to population in Jul 2007 was 63.5 percent (147.315 million employed as percent of population of 231.958 million). The same ratio in Apr 2020 would result in 165.034 million jobs (0.635 multiplied by noninstitutional civilian population of 259,896 million). There are effectively 31.708 million fewer jobs in Apr 2020 than in Jul 2007, or 165.034 million minus 133.326 million. There is actually not sufficient job creation in merely absorbing new entrants in the labor force because of those dropping from job searches, worsening the stock of unemployed or underemployed in involuntary part-time jobs.
Period IQ1980 to IIIQ1993 | |
Employed Millions IQ1980 NSA End of Quarter | 98.527 |
Employed Millions IIIQ1993 NSA End of Quarter | 120.673 |
∆% Employed IQ1980 to IIIQ1993 | 22.5 |
Period IVQ2007 to IQ2020 | |
Employed Millions IVQ2007 NSA End of Quarter | 146.334 |
Employed Millions IQ2020 NSA End of Quarter | 155.167 |
∆% Employed IVQ2007 to IQ2020 | 6.0 |
4. Number of Full-Time Employed Persons
i. As shown in Table IB-2, during the entire business cycle in the 1980s, including contractions and expansion, the number of employed full-time rose from 81.280 million NSA in IQ1980 to 99.599 million NSA in IIIQ1993 or 22.5 percent. The National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) dates a contraction of the US from IQ1990 (Jul) to IQ1991 (Mar) (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html). The expansion lasted until another contraction beginning in IQ2001 (Mar). US GDP contracted 1.3 percent from the pre-recession peak of $8983.9 billion of chained 2009 dollars in IIIQ1990 to the trough of $8865.6 billion in IQ1991 (https://bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm).
ii. In contrast, during the entire current business cycle, including contraction and expansion, the number of persons employed full-time increased from 121.042 million in IVQ2007 to 117.981 million in IQ2020 or 8.3 percent. The magnitude of the stress in US labor markets is magnified by the increase in the civilian noninstitutional population of the United States from 231.958 million in Jul 2007 to 259.896 million in Apr 2020 or by 27.938 million (https://www.bls.gov/data/). The number with full-time jobs in Apr 2020 is 113.656 million, in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event, which is lower by 9.563 million relative to the peak of 123.219 million in Jul 2007. The ratio of full-time jobs of 123.219 million in Jul 2007 to civilian noninstitutional population of 231.958 million was 53.1 percent. If that ratio had remained the same, there would be 138.005 million full-time jobs with population of 259.986 million in Apr 2020 (0.531 x 259.896) or 24.349 million fewer full-time jobs relative to actual 113.656 million. There appear to be around 20 million fewer full-time jobs in the US than before the global recession while population increased around 20 million. Mediocre GDP growth is the main culprit of the fractured US labor market augmented by the lockdown in economic activity in the COVID-19 event.
Period IQ1980 to IIIQ1993 | |
Employed Full-time Millions IQ1980 NSA End of Quarter | 81.280 |
Employed Full-time Millions IIIQ1993 NSA End of Quarter | 99.599 |
∆% Full-time Employed IQ1980 to IIIQ1993 | 22.5 |
Period IVQ2007 to IQ2020 | |
Employed Full-time Millions IVQ2007 NSA End of Quarter | 121.042 |
Employed Full-time Millions IQ2020 NSA End of Quarter | 127.981 |
∆% Full-time Employed IVQ2007 to IQ2020 | 5.7 |
5. Unemployed, Unemployment Rate and Employed Part-time for Economic Reasons.
i. As shown in Table IB-2 and in the following block, in the cycle from IQ1980 to IIIQ1993: (a) The rate of unemployment was lower at 6.4 percent in IIIQ1993 relative to 6.6 percent in IQ1980. (b) The number unemployed increased from 6.983 million in IQ1980 to 8.302 million in IIIQ1993 or 18.9 percent. (c) The number employed part-time for economic reasons increased 70.0 percent from 3.624 million in IQ1980 to 6.159 million in IIIQ1993. The National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) dates a contraction of the US from IQ1990 (Jul) to IQ1991 (Mar) (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html). The expansion lasted until another contraction beginning in IQ2001 (Mar). US GDP contracted 1.3 percent from the pre-recession peak of $8983.9 billion of chained 2009 dollars in IIIQ1990 to the trough of $8865.6 billion in IQ1991 (https://bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm).
ii. In contrast, in the economic cycle from IVQ2007 to IQ2020: (a) The rate of unemployment decreased from 4.8 percent in IVQ2007 to 4.5 percent in IQ2020. (b) The number unemployed changed 0.0 percent from 7.371 million in IVQ2007 to 7.370 million in IQ2020. (c) The number employed part-time for economic reasons because they could not find any other job increased 23.8 percent from 4.750 million in IVQ2007 to 5.879 million in IQ2020. (d) U6 Total Unemployed plus all marginally attached workers plus total employed part time for economic reasons as percent of all civilian labor force plus all marginally attached workers NSA increased from 8.7 percent in IVQ2007 to 8.9 percent in IQ2020. The probable global recession originating in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event is deteriorating sharply labor markets.
Period IQ1980 to IIIQ1993 | |
Unemployment Rate IQ1980 NSA End of Quarter | 6.6 |
Unemployment Rate IIIQ1993 NSA End of Quarter | 6.4 |
Unemployed IQ1980 Millions NSA End of Quarter | 6.983 |
Unemployed IIIQ1993 Millions NSA End of Quarter | 8.302 |
∆% | 18.9 |
Employed Part-time Economic Reasons IQ1980 Millions NSA End of Quarter | 3.624 |
Employed Part-time Economic Reasons Millions IIIQ1993 NSA End of Quarter | 6.159 |
∆% | 70.0 |
Period IVQ2007 to IQ2020 | |
Unemployment Rate IVQ2007 NSA End of Quarter | 4.8 |
Unemployment Rate IQ2020 NSA End of Quarter | 4.5 |
Unemployed IVQ2007 Millions NSA End of Quarter | 7.371 |
Unemployed IQ2020 Millions NSA End of Quarter | 7.370 |
∆% | 0.0 |
Employed Part-time Economic Reasons IVQ2007 Millions NSA End of Quarter | 4.750 |
Employed Part-time Economic Reasons Millions IQ2020 NSA End of Quarter | 5.879 |
∆% | 23.8 |
U6 Total Unemployed plus all marginally attached workers plus total employed part time for economic reasons as percent of all civilian labor force plus all marginally attached workers NSA | |
IVQ2007 | 8.7 |
IQ2020 | 8.9 |
6. Wealth of Households and Nonprofit Organizations.
The comparison of net worth of households and nonprofit organizations in the entire economic cycle from IQ1980 (and from IVQ1979) to IIQ1993 and from IVQ2007 to IVQ2019 is in Table IIA-5. The data reveal the following facts for the cycles in the 1980s:
- IVQ1979 to IIQ1993. Net worth increased 183.6 percent from IVQ1979 to IIQ1993, the all items CPI index increased 88.3 percent from 76.7 in Dec 1979 to 144.4 in Jun 1993 and real net worth increased 50.6 percent.
- IQ1980 to IVQ1985. Net worth increased 66.5 percent, the all items CPI index increased 36.5 percent from 80.1 in Mar 1980 to 109.3 in Dec 1985 and real net worth increased 22.0 percent.
- IVQ1979 to IVQ1985. Net worth increased 70.1 percent, the all items CPI index increased 42.5 percent from 76.7 in Dec 1979 to 109.3 in Dec 1985 and real net worth increased 19.3 percent.
- IQ1980 to IQ1989. Net worth increased 121.5 percent, the all items CPI index increased 52.7 percent from 80.1 in Mar 1980 to 122.3 in Mar 1989 and real net worth increased 45.1 percent.
- IQ1980 to IIQ1989. Net worth increased 126.1 percent, the all items CPI index increased 54.9 percent from 80.1 in Mar 1980 to 124.1 in Jun 1989 and real net worth increased 45.9 percent.
- IQ1980 to IIIQ1989. Net worth increased 131.9 percent, the all items CPI index increased 56.1 percent from 80.1 in Mar 1980 to 125.0 in Sep 1989 and real net worth increased 48.6 percent.
- IQ1980 to IVQ1989. Net worth increased 136.2 percent, the all items CPI index increased 57.4 from 80.1 in Mar 1980 to 126.1 in Dec 1989 and real net worth increased 50.1 percent.
- IQ1980 to IQ1990. Net worth increased 137.6 percent, the all items CPI index increased 60.7 percent from 80.1 in Mar 1980 to 128.7 in Mar 1990 and real net worth increased 47.9 percent.
- IQ1980 to IIQ1990. Net worth increased 140.2 percent, the all items CPI index increased 62.2 percent from 80.1 in Mar 1980 to 129.9 in Jun 1990 and real net worth increased 48.1 percent
- IQ1980 to IIIQ1990. Net worth increased 138.4 percent, the all items CPI index increased 65.7 percent from 80.1 in Mar 1980 to 132.7 in Jun 1990 and real net worth increased 43.9 percent.
- IQ1980 to IVQ1990. Net worth increased 143.1 percent, the all items CPI index increased 67.0 percent from 80.1 in Mar 1980 to 133.8 in Dec 1990 and real net worth increased 45.5 percent. The National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) dates a contraction of the US from IQ1990 (Jul) to IQ1991 (Mar) (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html). The expansion lasted until another contraction beginning in IQ2001 (Mar). US GDP contracted 1.3 percent from the pre-recession peak of $8983.9 billion of chained 2009 dollars in IIIQ1990 to the trough of $8865.6 billion in IQ1991 (https://apps.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm). This new cyclical contraction explains the contraction of net worth in IIIQ1990
- IQ1980 to IQ1991. Net worth increased 149.3 percent, the all items CPI index increased 68.5 percent from 80.1 in Mar 1980 to 135.0 in Mar 1991 and real net worth increased 47.9 percent.
- IQ1980 to IIQ1991. Net worth increased 149.9 percent, the all items CPI index increased 69.8 percent from 80.1 in Mar 1980 to 136.0 in Jun 1991 and real net worth increased 47.2 percent.
- IQ1980 to IIIQ1991. Net worth increased 152.9 percent, the all items CPI index increased 71.3 percent from 80.1 in Mar 1980 to 137.2 in Sep 1991 and real net worth increased 47.6 percent.
- IQ1980 to IVQ1991. Net worth increased 159.2 percent, the all items CPI index increased 72.2 percent from 80.1 in Mar 1980 to 137.9 in Dec 1991 and real net worth increased 50.6 percent.
- IQ1980 to IQ1992. Net worth increased 160.2 percent, the all items CPI index increased 73.9 percent from 80.1 in Mar 1980 to 139.3 in Mar 1992 and real net worth increased 49.6 percent.
- IQ1980 to IIQ1992. Net worth increased 161.1 percent, the all items CPI index increased 75.0 percent from 80.1 in Mar 1980 to 140.2 in Jun 1992 and real net worth increased 49.2 percent.
- IQ1980 to IIIQ1992. Net worth increased 164.9 percent, the all items CPI index increased 76.4 percent from 80.1 in Mar 1980 to 141.3 in Sep 1992 and real net worth increased 50.1 percent.
- IQ1980 to IVQ1992. Net worth increased 171.3, the all items CPI index increased 77.2 percent from 80.1 in Mar 1980 to 141.9 in Dec 1992 and real net worth increased 53.2 percent.
- IQ1980 to IQ1993. Net worth increased 174.9 percent, the all items CPI increased 79.3 percent from 80.1 in Mar 1980 to 143.6 in Mar 1993 and real net worth increased 53.3 percent.
- IQ1980 to IIQ1993. Net worth increased 177.7 percent, the all items CPI increased 80.3 percent from 80.1 in Jun 1980 to 144.4 in Jun 1993 and real net worth increased 54.0 percent.
There is comparatively weaker performance in the current economic cycle:
- IVQ2007 to IVQ2019. Net worth increased 67.6 percent, the all items CPI increased 22.3 percent from 210.036 in Dec 2007 to 256.974 in Dec 2019 and real or inflation adjusted net worth increased 37.0 percent. Real estate assets adjusted for inflation increased 4.5 percent. Growth of real net worth at the long-term average of 3.2 percent per year from IVQ1945 to IVQ2019 would have accumulated to 45.9 percent in the entire cycle from IVQ2007 to IVQ2019, much higher than actual 37.0 percent.
The explanation is partly in the sharp decline of wealth of households and nonprofit organizations and partly in the mediocre growth rates of the cyclical expansion beginning in IIIQ2009. Long-term economic performance in the United States consisted of trend growth of GDP at 3 percent per year and of per capita GDP at 2 percent per year as measured for 1870 to 2010 by Robert E Lucas (2011May). The economy returned to trend growth after adverse events such as wars and recessions. The key characteristic of adversities such as recessions was much higher rates of growth in expansion periods that permitted the economy to recover output, income and employment losses that occurred during the contractions. Over the business cycle, the economy compensated the losses of contractions with higher growth in expansions to maintain trend growth of GDP of 3 percent and of GDP per capita of 2 percent. The US maintained growth at 3.0 percent on average over entire cycles with expansions at higher rates compensating for contractions. US economic growth has been at only 2.1 percent on average in the cyclical expansion in the 43 quarters from IIIQ2009 to IQ2020. Boskin (2010Sep) measures that the US economy grew at 6.2 percent in the first four quarters and 4.5 percent in the first 12 quarters after the trough in the second quarter of 1975; and at 7.7 percent in the first four quarters and 5.8 percent in the first 12 quarters after the trough in the first quarter of 1983 (Professor Michael J. Boskin, Summer of Discontent, Wall Street Journal, Sep 2, 2010 http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052748703882304575465462926649950.html). There are new calculations using the revision of US GDP and personal income data since 1929 by the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) (http://bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm) and the first estimate of GDP for IQ2020 (https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2020-04/gdp1q20_adv.pdf). The average of 7.7 percent in the first four quarters of major cyclical expansions is in contrast with the rate of growth in the first four quarters of the expansion from IIIQ2009 to IIQ2010 of only 2.8 percent obtained by dividing GDP of $15,557.3 billion in IIQ2010 by GDP of $15,134.1 billion in IIQ2009 {[($15,557.3/$15,134.1) -1]100 = 2.8%], or accumulating the quarter on quarter growth rates (https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/05/mediocre-cyclical-united-states.html and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/03/weekly-rise-of-valuations-of-risk.html). The expansion from IQ1983 to IQ1986 was at the average annual growth rate of 5.7 percent, 5.3 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1986, 5.1 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1986, 5.0 percent from IQ1983 to IQ1987, 5.0 percent from IQ1983 to IIQ1987, 4.9 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1987, 5.0 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1987, 4.9 percent from IQ1983 to IIQ1988, 4.8 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1988, 4.8 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1988, 4.8 percent from IQ1983 to IQ1989, 4.7 percent from IQ1983 to IIQ1989, 4.6 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1989, 4.5 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1989. 4.5 percent from IQ1983 to IQ1990, 4.4 percent from IQ1983 to IIQ1990, 4.3 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1990, 4.0 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1990, 3.8 percent from IQ1983 to IQ1991, 3.8 percent from IQ1983 to IIQ1991, 3.8 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1991, 3.7 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1991, 3.7 percent from IQ1983 to IQ1992, 3.7 percent from IQ1983 to IIQ1992, 3.7 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ2019, 3.8 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1992, 3.7 percent from IQ1983 to IQ1993, 3.6 percent from IQ1983 to IIQ1993, 3.6 percent from IQ1983 to IIIQ1993 and at 7.9 percent from IQ1983 to IVQ1983 (https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/05/mediocre-cyclical-united-states.html and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/03/weekly-rise-of-valuations-of-risk.html). The National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) dates a contraction of the US from IQ1990 (Jul) to IQ1991 (Mar) (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html). The expansion lasted until another contraction beginning in IQ2001 (Mar). US GDP contracted 1.3 percent from the pre-recession peak of $8983.9 billion of chained 2009 dollars in IIIQ1990 to the trough of $8865.6 billion in IQ1991 (https://apps.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm). The US maintained growth at 3.0 percent on average over entire cycles with expansions at higher rates compensating for contractions. Growth at trend in the entire cycle from IVQ2007 to IQ2020 and the lockdown of economic activity in COVID-19 would have accumulated to 43.6 percent. GDP in IQ2020 would be $22,634.2 billion (in constant dollars of 2012) if the US had grown at trend, which is higher by $3646.3 billion than actual $18,987.9 billion. There are more than three trillion dollars of GDP less than at trend, explaining the 51.6 million unemployed or underemployed equivalent to actual unemployment/underemployment of 30.0 percent of the effective labor force with the largest part originating in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event (https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/05/fifty-two-million-unemployed-or.html and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/04/lockdown-of-economic-activity-in.html). Unemployment is increasing sharply while employment is declining rapidly because of the lockdown of economic activity in the probable global recession resulting from the COVID-19 event (https://www.bls.gov/cps/employment-situation-covid19-faq-april-2020.pdf). US GDP in IQ2020 is 16.1 percent lower than at trend. US GDP grew from $15,762.0 billion in IVQ2007 in constant dollars to $18,987.9 billion in IQ2020 or 20.5 percent at the average annual equivalent rate of 1.5 percent. Professor John H. Cochrane (2014Jul2) estimates US GDP at more than 10 percent below trend. Cochrane (2016May02) measures GDP growth in the US at average 3.5 percent per year from 1950 to 2000 and only at 1.76 percent per year from 2000 to 2015 with only at 2.0 percent annual equivalent in the current expansion. Cochrane (2016May02) proposes drastic changes in regulation and legal obstacles to private economic activity. The US missed the opportunity to grow at higher rates during the expansion and it is difficult to catch up because growth rates in the final periods of expansions tend to decline. The US missed the opportunity for recovery of output and employment always afforded in the first four quarters of expansion from recessions. Zero interest rates and quantitative easing were not required or present in successful cyclical expansions and in secular economic growth at 3.0 percent per year and 2.0 percent per capita as measured by Lucas (2011May). There is cyclical uncommonly slow growth in the US instead of allegations of secular stagnation. There is similar behavior in manufacturing. There is classic research on analyzing deviations of output from trend (see for example Schumpeter 1939, Hicks 1950, Lucas 1975, Sargent and Sims 1977). The long-term trend is growth of manufacturing at average 2.9 percent per year from Apr 1919 to Apr 2020. Growth at 2.9 percent per year would raise the NSA index of manufacturing output (SIC, Standard Industrial Classification) from 108.2987 in Dec 2007 to 154.0798 in Apr 2020. The actual index NSA in Apr 2020 is 84.8550 which is 44.9 percent below trend. The deterioration of manufacturing in Apr 2020 originates in the lockdown of economic activity in the COVID-19 event. Manufacturing grew at the average annual rate of 3.3 percent between Dec 1986 and Dec 2006. Growth at 3.3 percent per year would raise the NSA index of manufacturing output (SIC, Standard Industrial Classification) from 108.2987 in Dec 2007 to 161.6318 in Apr 2020. The actual index NSA in Apr 2020 is 84.8550, which is 47.5 percent below trend. Manufacturing output grew at average 1.3 percent between Dec 1986 and Apr 2020. Using trend growth of 1.3 percent per year, the index would increase to 127.0007 in Apr 2020. The output of manufacturing at 84.8550 in Apr 2020 is 33.2 percent below trend under this alternative calculation. Using the NAICS (North American Industry Classification System), manufacturing output fell from the high of 110.5147 in Jun 2007 to the low of 86.3800 in Apr 2009 or 21.8 percent. The NAICS manufacturing index decreased from 86.3800 in Apr 2009 to 85.8317 in Apr 2020 or minus 0.6 percent. The NAICS manufacturing index increased at the annual equivalent rate of 3.5 percent from Dec 1986 to Dec 2006. Growth at 3.5 percent would increase the NAICS manufacturing output index from 106.6777 in Dec 2007 to 163.0563 in Apr 2020. The NAICS index at 85.8317 in Apr 2020 is 47.4 below trend. The NAICS manufacturing output index grew at 1.7 percent annual equivalent from Dec 1999 to Dec 2006. Growth at 1.7 percent would raise the NAICS manufacturing output index from 106.6777 in Dec 2007 to 131.3304 in Apr 2020. The NAICS index at 85.8317 in Apr 2020 is 34.6 percent below trend under this alternative calculation.
Table IIA-5, Net Worth of Households and Nonprofit Organizations in Billions of Dollars, IVQ1979 to IIQ1993 and IVQ2007 to IVQ2019
Period IQ1980 to IIQ1993 | |
Net Worth of Households and Nonprofit Organizations USD Millions | |
IVQ1979 IQ1980 | 9,097.9 9,290.5 |
IVQ1985 IIIQ1986 IVQ1986 IQ1987 IIQ1987 IIIQ1987 IVQ1987 IQ1988 IIQ1988 IIIQ1988 IVQ1988 IQ1989 IIQ1989 IIIQ1989 IVQ1989 IQ1990 IIQ1990 | 15,471.3 16,526.5 17,096.6 17,720.6 18,012.4 18,424.3 18,369.6 18,879.0 19,317.2 19,638.8 20,146.9 20,579.8 21,002.2 21,544.8 21,947.4 22,076.3 22,314.7 |
III1990 | 22,146.8 |
IV1990 | 22,581.0 |
I1991 | 23,165.8 |
IIQ1991 | 23,214.1 |
IIIQ1991 | 23,493.8 |
IVQ1991 | 24,080.6 |
IQ1992 | 24,170.9 |
IIQ1992 | 24,256.5 |
IIIQ1992 | 24,607.2 |
IVQ1992 | 25,206.6 |
IQ1993 | 25,536.0 |
IIQ1993 | 25,798.5 |
∆ USD IVQ1979 to IVQ1985 IVQ1979 to IIQ1993 IQ1980-IVQ1985 IQ1980-IIIQ1986 IQ1980-IVQ1986 IQ1980-IQ1987 IQ1980-IIQ1987 IQ1980-IIIQ1987 IQ1980-IVQ1987 IQ1980-IQ1988 IQ1980-IIQ1988 IQ1980-IIIQ1988 IQ1980-IVQ1988 IQ1980-IQ1989 IQ1980-IIQ1989 IQ1980-IIIQ1989 IQ1980-IVQ1989 IQ1980-IQ1990 IQ1980-IIQ1990 | +6,373.4 ∆%70.1 R∆19.3 +16,700.6 ∆%183.6R∆%50.6 +6,180.8∆%66.5 R∆%22.0 +7,236.0 ∆%77.9 R∆%29.3 +7,806.1 ∆%84.0 R∆%33.4 +8,430.1 ∆%90.7 R∆%36.3 +8,721.9 ∆%93.9 R∆%36.8 +9,133.8 ∆%98.3 R∆%38.1 +9079.1 ∆%97.7 R∆%37.2 +9588.5 ∆%103.2 R∆%39.7 10,0026.7 ∆%107.9 R∆%41.1 +10,348.3 ∆%111.4 R∆%41.3 +10,856.4 ∆%116.9 R∆%44.2 +11289.3 ∆%121.5 R∆%45.1 +11,711.7 ∆%126.1 R∆% 45.9 +12,254.3 ∆%131.9 R∆% 48.6 +12,656.9 ∆%136.2 R∆%50.1 +12,785.8 ∆%137.6 R∆%47.9 +13,024.2 ∆%140.2 R∆%48.1 |
IQ1980-IIIQ1990 | +12,586.3∆%138.4 R∆%43.9 |
IQ1980-IVQ1990 | +13,290.5 ∆%143.1 R∆%45.5 |
IQ1980-IQ1991 | +13,875.3 ∆%149.3 R∆%47.9 |
IQ1980-IIQ1991 | +13,923.6 ∆%149.9 R∆%47.2 |
IQ1980-IIIQ1991 | +14,203.3 ∆%152.9 R∆%47.6 |
IQ1980-IVQ1991 | +14,790.1 ∆%159.2 R∆%50.6 |
IQ1980-IQ1992 | +14,880.4 ∆%160.2 R∆%49.6 |
IQ1980-IIQ1992 | +14,966.0 ∆%161.1 R∆%49.2 |
IQ1980-IIIQ1992 | +15,316.7 ∆%164.9 R∆%50.1 |
IQ1980-IVQ1992 | +15,916.1 ∆%171.3 R∆%53.2 |
IQ1980-IQ1993 | +16,245.5 ∆%174.9 R∆%53.3 |
IQ1980-IIQ1993 | +16,508.0 ∆%177.7 R∆% 54.0 |
Period IVQ2007 to IVQ2019 | |
Net Worth of Households and Nonprofit Organizations USD Millions | |
IVQ2007 | 70,642.3 |
IVQ2019 | 118,368.2 |
∆ USD Billions | +47,725.9 ∆%67.6 R∆%37.0 |
Net Worth = Assets – Liabilities. R∆% real percentage change or adjusted for CPI percentage change.
Notes: Deposits: Total Time and Savings Deposits FL15303005; Net Worth = Assets – Liabilities
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 2020. Flow of funds, balance sheets and integrated macroeconomic accounts: fourth quarter 2019. Washington, DC, Federal Reserve System, Mar 12. https://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/z1/current/default.htm
7. Gross Private Domestic Investment.
i. The comparison of gross private domestic investment in the entire economic cycles from IQ1980 to IIIQ1993 and from IVQ2007 to IQ2020 is in the following block and in Table IB-2. Gross private domestic investment increased from $933.1 billion in IQ1980 to $1,303.6 billion in IIIQ1993 or by 39.7 percent. The National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) dates a contraction of the US from IQ1990 (Jul) to IQ1991 (Mar) (https://www.nber.org/cycles.html). The expansion lasted until another contraction beginning in IQ2001 (Mar). US GDP contracted 1.3 percent from the pre-recession peak of $8983.9 billion of chained 2009 dollars in IIIQ1990 to the trough of $8865.6 billion in IQ1991 (https://bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm).
ii In the current cycle, gross private domestic investment increased from $2,653.1 billion in IVQ2007 to $3,314.9 billion in IQ2020, or 24.9 percent. Private fixed investment edged from $2,630.0 billion in IVQ2007 to $3,304.4 billion in IQ2020 or increase by 25.6 percent. Private fixed investment contracted at the SAAR of minus 2.6 percent in IQ2020 in the probable global recession in the lockdown of economic activity of the COVID-19 event.
Period IQ1980-IIIQ1993 | |
Gross Private Domestic Investment USD 2009 Billions | |
IQ1980 | 933.1 |
IIIQ1993 | 1303.6 |
∆% | 39.7 |
Period IVQ2007 to IQ2020 | |
Gross Private Domestic Investment USD 2012 Billions | |
IVQ2007 | 2,653.1 |
IQ2020 | 3,314.9 |
∆% | 24.9 |
Private Fixed Investment USD 2012 Billions | |
IVQ2007 | 2,630.0 |
IQ2020 | 3,304.4 |
∆% | 25.6 |
Table IB-2, US, GDP and Real Disposable Personal Income Per capita Actual and Trend Growth and Employment, 1980-1992 and 2007-2019, SAAR USD Billions, Millions of Persons and ∆%
Period IQ1980 to IIIQ1993 | |
GDP SAAR USD Billions | |
IQ1980 | 6,837.6 |
IIIQ1993 | 9,955.6 |
∆% IQ1980 to IIIQ1993 (46.1 percent from IVQ1979 $6816.2 billion) | 45.6 |
∆% Trend Growth IQ1980 to IIIQ1993 | 51.3 |
Real Disposable Personal Income per Capita IQ1980 Chained 2012 USD | 21,579 |
Real Disposable Personal Income per Capita IIIQ1993 Chained 2012 USD | 27,875 |
∆% IQ1980 to IIIQ1993 (29.3 percent from IVQ1979 $21,565 billion) | 29.2 |
∆% Trend Growth | 31.9 |
Employed Millions IQ1980 NSA End of Quarter | 98.527 |
Employed Millions IIIQ1993 NSA End of Quarter | 120.673 |
∆% Employed IQ1980 to IIIQ1993 | 22.5 |
Employed Full-time Millions IQ1980 NSA End of Quarter | 81.280 |
Employed Full-time Millions IIIQ1993 NSA End of Quarter | 99.599 |
∆% Full-time Employed IQ1980 to IIIQ1993 | 22.5 |
Unemployment Rate IQ1980 NSA End of Quarter | 6.6 |
Unemployment Rate IIIQ1993 NSA End of Quarter | 6.4 |
Unemployed IQ1980 Millions NSA End of Quarter | 6.983 |
Unemployed IIIQ993 Millions NSA End of Quarter | 8.302 |
∆% | 18.9 |
Employed Part-time Economic Reasons IQ1980 Millions NSA End of Quarter | 3.624 |
Employed Part-time Economic Reasons Millions IIIQ1993 NSA End of Quarter | 6.159 |
∆% | 70.0 |
Net Worth of Households and Nonprofit Organizations USD Billions | |
IVQ1979 | 9,097.9 |
IIQ1993 | 25,798.5 |
∆ USD Billions | +16,700.6 |
∆% CPI Adjusted | 50.6 |
Gross Private Domestic Investment USD 2012 Billions | |
IQ1980 | 933.1 |
IIIQ1993 | 1303.6 |
∆% | 39.7 |
Period IVQ2007 to IQ2020 | |
GDP SAAR USD Billions | |
IVQ2007 | 15,762.0 |
IQ2020 | 18,987.9 |
∆% IVQ2007 to IQ2020 | 20.5 |
∆% IVQ2007 to IQ2020 Trend Growth | 43.6 |
Real Disposable Personal Income per Capita IVQ2007 Chained 2012 USD | 38,037 |
Real Disposable Personal Income per Capita IQ2020 Chained 2012 USD | 45,800 |
∆% IVQ2007 to IQ2020 | 20.4 |
∆% Trend Growth | 27.5 |
Employed Millions IVQ2007 NSA End of Quarter | 146.334 |
Employed Millions IQ2020 NSA End of Quarter | 155.167 |
∆% Employed IVQ2007 to IQ2020 | 6.0 |
Employed Full-time Millions IVQ2007 NSA End of Quarter | 121.042 |
Employed Full-time Millions IQ2020 NSA End of Quarter | 127.981 |
∆% Full-time Employed IVQ2007 to IQ2020 | 5.7 |
Unemployment Rate IVQ2007 NSA End of Quarter | 4.8 |
Unemployment Rate IQ2020 NSA End of Quarter | 4.5 |
Unemployed IVQ2007 Millions NSA End of Quarter | 7.371 |
Unemployed IQ2020 Millions NSA End of Quarter | 7.370 |
∆% | 0.0 |
Employed Part-time Economic Reasons IVQ2007 Millions NSA End of Quarter | 4.750 |
Employed Part-time Economic Reasons Millions IQ2020 NSA End of Quarter | 5.879 |
∆% | 23.8 |
U6 Total Unemployed plus all marginally attached workers plus total employed part time for economic reasons as percent of all civilian labor force plus all marginally attached workers NSA | |
IVQ2007 | 8.7 |
IQ2020 | 8.9 |
Net Worth of Households and Nonprofit Organizations USD Billions | |
IVQ2007 | 70,642.3 |
IVQ2019 | 118,368.2 |
∆ USD Billions | +47,725.9 ∆%67.6 R∆%37.0 |
Gross Private Domestic Investment USD Billions | |
IVQ2007 | 2,653.1 |
IQ2020 | 3,314.9 |
∆% | 24.9 |
Private Fixed Investment USD 2009 Billions | |
IQ2007 | 2,630.0 |
IQ2020 | 3,304.4 |
∆% | 25.6 |
Note: GDP trend growth used is 3.0 percent per year and GDP per capita is 2.0 percent per year as estimated by Lucas (2011May) on data from 1870 to 2010.
Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis https://apps.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm Source:
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 2019. Flow of funds, balance sheets and integrated macroeconomic accounts: third quarter 2019. Washington, DC, Federal Reserve System, Dec 2019. https://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/z1/current/default.htm
The Congressional Budget Office estimates potential GDP, potential labor force and potential labor productivity provided in Table IB-3. The CBO estimates average rate of growth of potential GDP from 1950 to 2017 at 3.2 percent per year. The projected path is significantly lower at 1.4 percent per year from 2018 to 2028. The legacy of the economic cycle expansion from IIIQ2009 to IQ2020 at 2.1 percent on average is in contrast with 3.6 percent on average in the expansion from IQ1983 to IIIQ1993 (https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/05/mediocre-cyclical-united-states.html and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/03/weekly-rise-of-valuations-of-risk.html). Subpar economic growth may perpetuate unemployment and underemployment estimated at 51.6 million or 30.0 percent of the effective labor force in Apr 2020 (https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/05/fifty-two-million-unemployed-or.html and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/04/lockdown-of-economic-activity-in.html) with much lower hiring than in the period before the current cycle (Section I and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/04/united-states-imbalances-of-internal.html).
Table IB-3, US, Congressional Budget Office History and Projections of Potential GDP of US Overall Economy, ∆%
Potential GDP | Potential Labor Force | Potential Labor Productivity* | |
Average Annual ∆% | |||
1950-1973 | 4.0 | 1.6 | 2.4 |
1974-1981 | 3.2 | 2.5 | 0.7 |
1982-1990 | 3.4 | 1.7 | 1.7 |
1991-2001 | 3.2 | 1.2 | 2.0 |
2002-2007 | 2.5 | 1.0 | 1.5 |
2008-2017 | 1.5 | 0.5 | 0.9 |
Total 1950-2017 | 3.2 | 1.4 | 1.7 |
Projected Average Annual ∆% | |||
2018-2022 | 2.0 | 0.6 | 1.4 |
2023-2028 | 1.8 | 0.4 | 1.4 |
2018-2028 | 1.9 | 0.5 | 1.4 |
*Ratio of potential GDP to potential labor force
Source: CBO, The budget and economic outlook: 2018-2028. Washington, DC, Apr 9, 2018 https://www.cbo.gov/publication/53651 CBO (2014BEOFeb4), CBO, Key assumptions in projecting potential GDP—February 2014 baseline. Washington, DC, Congressional Budget Office, Feb 4, 2014. CBO, The budget and economic outlook: 2015 to 2025. Washington, DC, Congressional Budget Office, Jan 26, 2015. Aug 2016
Chart IB1-BEO2818 of the Congressional Budget Office provides historical and projected annual growth of United States potential GDP. The projection is of faster growth of real potential GDP.
Chart IB1-BEO2818, CBO Economic Forecast
Source: CBO, The budget and economic outlook: 2018-2028. Washington, DC, Apr 9, 2018 https://www.cbo.gov/publication/53651 CBO (2014BEOFeb4).
Chart IB1-A1 of the Congressional Budget Office provides historical and projected annual growth of United States potential GDP. There is sharp decline of growth of United States potential GDP.
Chart IB-1A1, Congressional Budget Office, Projections of Annual Growth of United States Potential GDP
Source: CBO, The budget and economic outlook: 2017-2027. Washington, DC, Jan 24, 2017 https://www.cbo.gov/publication/52370
https://www.cbo.gov/about/products/budget-economic-data#6
Chart IB-1A of the Congressional Budget Office provides historical and projected potential and actual US GDP. The gap between actual and potential output closes by 2017. Potential output expands at a lower rate than historically. Growth is even weaker relative to trend.
Chart IB-1A, Congressional Budget Office, Estimate of Potential GDP and Gap
Source: Congressional Budget Office
https://www.cbo.gov/publication/49890
Chart IB-1 of the Congressional Budget Office (CBO 2013BEOFeb5) provides actual and potential GDP of the United States from 2000 to 2011 and projected to 2024. Lucas (2011May) estimates trend of United States real GDP of 3.0 percent from 1870 to 2010 and 2.2 percent for per capita GDP. The United States successfully returned to trend growth of GDP by higher rates of growth during cyclical expansion as analyzed by Bordo (2012Sep27, 2012Oct21) and Bordo and Haubrich (2012DR). Growth in expansions following deeper contractions and financial crises was much higher in agreement with the plucking model of Friedman (1964, 1988). The Congressional Budget Office estimates potential GDP, potential labor force and potential labor productivity provided in Table IB-3. The CBO estimates average rate of growth of potential GDP from 1950 to 2017 at 3.2 percent per year. The projected path is significantly lower at 1.4 percent per year from 2018 to 2028. The legacy of the economic cycle expansion from IIIQ2009 to IQ2020 at 2.1 percent on average is in contrast with 3.6 percent on average in the expansion from IQ1983 to IIIQ1993 (https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/05/mediocre-cyclical-united-states.html and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/03/weekly-rise-of-valuations-of-risk.html). Subpar economic growth may perpetuate unemployment and underemployment estimated at 51.6 million or 30.0 percent of the effective labor force in Apr 2020 (https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/05/fifty-two-million-unemployed-or.html and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/04/lockdown-of-economic-activity-in.html) with much lower hiring than in the period before the current cycle (Section I and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2020/04/united-states-imbalances-of-internal.html). The US economy and labor markets collapsed without recovery. Abrupt collapse of economic conditions can be explained only with cyclic factors (Lazear and Spletzer 2012Jul22) and not by secular stagnation (Hansen 1938, 1939, 1941 with early dissent by Simons 1942).
Chart IB-1, US, Congressional Budget Office, Actual and Projections of Potential GDP, 2000-2024, Trillions of Dollars
Source: Congressional Budget Office, CBO (2013BEOFeb5). The last year in common in both projections is 2017. The revision lowers potential output in 2017 by 7.3 percent relative to the projection in 2007.
Chart IB-2 provides differences in the projections of potential output by the CBO in 2007 and more recently on Feb 4, 2014, which the CBO explains in CBO (2014Feb28).
Chart IB-2, Congressional Budget Office, Revisions of Potential GDP
Source: Congressional Budget Office, 2014Feb 28. Revisions to CBO’s Projection of Potential Output since 2007. Washington, DC, CBO, Feb 28, 2014.
Chart IB-3 provides actual and projected potential GDP from 2000 to 2024. The gap between actual and potential GDP disappears at the end of 2017 (CBO2014Feb4). GDP increases in the projection at 2.5 percent per year.
Chart IB-3, Congressional Budget Office, GDP and Potential GDP
Source: CBO (2013BEOFeb5), CBO, Key assumptions in projecting potential GDP—February 2014 baseline. Washington, DC, Congressional Budget Office, Feb 4, 2014.
References
Abraham, Katharine G., John C. Haltiwanger, Kristin Sandusky and James Spletzer. 2009. Exploring differences in employment between household and establishment data. Cambridge, MA, National Bureau of Economic Research, Sep 2009.
Abraham, Katharine G., John C. Haltiwanger, Kristin Sandusky and James Spletzer. 2016. The consequences of long-term unemployment: evidence from linked survey and administrative data. Cambridge, MA, National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 22665, Sep.
Adrian, Tobias, Arturo Estrella, Hyun Song Shin. 2018. Risk-taking channel of monetary policy. Center for Economic Policy Research, Discussion Paper DP12677, Feb https://cepr.org/active/publications/discussion_papers/dp.php?dpno=12677
Allen, William R. 1993. Irving Fisher and the 100 percent reserve proposal. Journal of Law and Economics 36 (2, Oct): 703-17.
Andrés, Javier, J. David López-Salido and Edward Nelson. 2004. Tobin’s imperfect asset substitution in optimizing equilibrium. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 36 (4, Aug): 665-90.
Asso, Pier Francesco, George A. Kahn and Robert Leeson. 2007. The Taylor Rule and the transformation of monetary policy. Kansas City: Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City RWP 07-II, Dec.
Asso, Pier Francesco, George A. Kahn and Robert Leeson. 2010. The Taylor Rule and the practice of central banking. Kansas City: Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, RWP 10-05, Feb.
Atkeson, Andrew and Patrick J. Kehoe. 1998. Paths of development for early- and late-bloomers in a dynamic Heckscher-Ohlin world. Minneapolis, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Staff Report No. 256, Oct.
Atkeson, Andrew and Patrick J. Kehoe. 2004. Deflation and depression: is there an empirical link. American Economic Review 94 (2, May): 99-103.
Bagehot, Walter. 1873. Lombard Street, 14th edn. London: Kegan, Paul & Co, 1917.
Balassa, Bela. 1964. The purchasing power parity doctrine: a reappraisal. Journal of Political Economy 72 (6, Dec): 584.596.
Ball, Laurence and N. Gregory Mankiw. 2002. The NAIRU in theory and practice. Journal of Economic Perspectives 16 (4, Autumn): 115-36.
Bank of Japan. 2012Feb14APP. Amendment to “Principal Terms and Conditions for the Asset Purchase Program.” Tokyo, Bank of Japan, Feb 14 http://www.boj.or.jp/en/announcements/release_2012/rel120214a.pdf
Bank of Japan. 2012Feb14PSG. The price stability goal in the medium to long term. Tokyo, Bank of Japan, Feb 14 http://www.boj.or.jp/en/announcements/release_2012/k120214b.pdf
Bank of Japan. 2012Feb14EME. Enhancement of monetary easing. Tokyo, Bank of Japan, Feb 14 http://www.boj.or.jp/en/announcements/release_2012/k120214a.pdf
Barbosa, Fernando de Holanda. 1987. Domestic and international sources of Brazilian inflation: 1947-80. In Luigi L. Pasinetti and P.J. Lloyd, eds. Structural change, economic interdependence and world development. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Barnett, Jessica C. and Marina S. Vornovitsky. 2016. Health Insurance coverage in the United States: 2015. Washington, DC, US Census Bureau, Sep 2016 http://www.census.gov/content/dam/Census/library/publications/2016/demo/p60-257.pdf
Barro, Robert J. and David B. Gordon. 1983a. Rules, discretion and reputation in a model of monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 12 (1): 101-121.
Barro, Robert J. and David B. Gordon. 1983b. A positive theory of monetary policy in a natural rate model. Journal of Political Economy 91 (4, Aug): 589-610.
Barro, Robert J. 2016. The reasons behind the Obama non-recovery,” Wall Street Journal, Sep 20 http://www.wsj.com/articles/the-reasons-behind-the-obama-non-recovery-1474412963
Barro, Robert J. and Tao Jin. 2016. Rate events and long-run risks. Cambridge, MA, National Bureau of Economic Research, NBER Working Paper No. 21871, Jan, http://www.nber.org/papers/w21871
Barsky, Robert B. and Lutz Kilian. 2004. Oil and the macroeconomy since the 1970s. Journal of Economic Perspectives 18 (4, Autumn): 115-34.
Barth, James R., Gerard Caprio, Jr. and Ross Levine. 2006. Rethinking bank regulation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. 2011Jun. Basel II: a global regulatory framework for more resilient banks and banking systems. Basel, Switzerland: BIS, Jun 2011 http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs189.pdf
Batini, Nicoletta and Edward Nelson. 2002. The lag from monetary policy actions to inflation: Friedman revisited. London, Bank of England, External MPC Unit Discussion Paper No. 6, Jan.
Beim, David O. 2011Oct9. Can the euro be saved? New York City, Columbia University, Oct 9 http://www1.gsb.columbia.edu/mygsb/faculty/research/pubfiles/5573/Can%20the%20Euro%20be%20Saved.pdf
Benhabib, Jess and Mark M. Spiegel. 2009. Moderate inflation and the deflation-depression link. 2009. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 41 (4, Jun): 787-798.
Benston, George J. and George G. Kaufman. 1997. The FDICA after five years. Journal of Economic Perspectives 11 (3, Summer, 1997): 139-58.
Bernanke, Ben S. 2002. Deflation: making sure “it” doesn’t happen here. Washington, DC, National Economists Club, Nov 21 http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2002/20021121/default.htm
Bernanke, Ben S. 2000. Japanese monetary policy: a case of self-induced paralysis? In Ryoichi Mikitani and Adam S. Posen, Japan’s financial crisis and its parallels to US experience. Washington, DC, Institute for International Economics, Special Report 13, Sep 2000.
Bernanke, Ben S. 2002. Deflation: making sure “it” doesn’t happen here. Washington, DC, Before the National Economists Club, Nov 21 http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2002/20021121/default.htm
Bernanke, Ben S. 2003. A perspective on inflation targeting. Business Economics 38 (3, Jul): 7–15.
Bernanke, Ben S. 2003JPY. Some thoughts on monetary policy in Japan. Tokyo, Before the Japan Society of Monetary Economics, May 31 http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2003/20030531/default.htm
Bernanke, Ben S. 2009SL. The crisis and the policy response. London, London School of Economics, Stamp Lecture, Jan 13 http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20090113a.htm
Bernanke, Ben S. 2010WP. What the Fed did and why: supporting the recovery and sustaining price stability. Washington Post, Nov 4. http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/article/2010/11/03/AR2010110307372_pf.html
Bernanke, Ben S. 2011Oct4JEC. Statement. Washington, DC, Joint Economic Committee, US Congress, Oct 4 http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/bernanke20111004a.pdf
Bernanke, Ben S. 2012Apr25. Transcript of Chairman Bernanke’s press conference April 25, 2012. Washington, DC, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Apr 25 http://www.federalreserve.gov/mediacenter/files/FOMCpresconf20120425.pdf
Bernanke, Ben S. 2012Aug22. Letter to The Honorable Darrell E. Issa. Washington, DC, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Aug 22 http://online.wsj.com/public/resources/documents/Bernankeletter0812.pdf
Bernanke, Ben S. 2012Oct14IMF. US monetary policy and international implications. Tokyo, Japan, Challenges of the Global Financial System: Risks and Governance under Evolving Globalization, High-level Seminar sponsored by Bank of Japan-International Monetary Fund, Oct 14 http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20121014a.htm
Bernanke, Ben S. 2012JHAug31. Monetary policy since the onset of the crisis. Jackson Hole, WY, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Symposium, Aug 31 http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20120831a.htm
Bernanke, Ben S. 2012Nov20. The economic recovery and economic policy. New York City, NY, Economic Club, Nov 20 http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20121120a.htm
Bernanke, Ben S. 2013Mar25. Monetary policy and the global economy. London, Bank of England and London School of Economics, Mar 25 http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20130325a.htm
Bernanke, Ben S. 2013Jul17. Statement on semiannual monetary policy report to the Congress. Washington, DC, Jul 17, US House of Representatives, Jul 18, US Senate http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/bernanke20130717a.htm
Bernanke, Ben S. and Frederic S. Mishkin. 1997. Inflation targeting: a new framework for monetary policy? Journal of Economic Perspectives 11 (2, Spring): 97–116.
Bernanke, Ben S. and Vincent R. Reinhart. 2004. Conducting monetary policy at very low short-term interest rates. American Economic Review 94 (2): 85-90.
Black, Fischer and Myron Scholes. 1973. The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. Journal of Political Economy 81 (May/June): 637-54.
Blanchard, Olivier. 2011WEOSep. Foreword to IMF 2011WEOSep: XIII-XIV.
Blanchard, Olivier. 2012WEOApr. Foreword to IMF 2012WEOApr: XIII-XIV
Blanchard, Olivier and Lawrence F. Katz. 1997. What we know and do not know about the natural rate of unemployment. Journal of Economic Perspectives 11 (1, Winter): 51-72.
Blinder, Alan S. 2000. Monetary policy at the zero lower bound: balancing the risks. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 32 (4, Nov): 1093-1099.
Blinder, Alan S. and Mark Zandi. 2010Jul27. How the Great Recession was brought to an end. Princeton, NJ, http://www.princeton.edu/~blinder/End-of-Great-Recession.pdf
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 2012Dec6. Flow of funds accounts of the United States. Washington, DC, Federal Reserve System, Dec 6 http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/z1/default.htm
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 2017Jul17. Monetary policy report. Washington, DC, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve, Jul 17 http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/mpr_default.htm
Bordo, Michael D. 2012Sep27. Financial recessions don’t lead to weak recoveries. Wall Street Journal, Sep 27 http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10000872396390444506004577613122591922992.html
Bordo, Michael D. 2012Oct21. Why this US recovery is weaker. Bloomberg View, Oct 21 http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2012-10-21/why-this-u-s-recovery-is-weaker.html
Bordo, Michael D. 2012Nov20. Expansionary monetary policy can create asset price booms. Washington, DC, Shadow Open Market Committee, Nov 20 http://shadowfed.org/wp-content/uploads/2012/11/Bordo-SOMC-Nov2012.pdf
Bordo, Michael D. and Hugh Rockoff. 2011. The influence of Irving Fisher on Milton Friedman’s monetary economics. Denver, CO, AEA Session on Irving Fisher and Modern Economics: 100 years after the Purchasing Power of Money, Jan 8 www.aeaweb.org/aea/2011conference/program/retrieve.php?pdfid
Bordo, Michael D, Ehsan Choudhri and Anna J. Schwartz. 1995. Could stable money have averted the Great Contraction. Economic Inquiry 33 (3, Jul): 484-505.
Bordo, Michael D. and Harold James. 2001. The Adam Klug Memorial Lecture: Haberler versus Nurkse: the case for floating exchange rates as an alternative to Bretton Woods? Cambridge, MA: NBER, WP 8545, Oct.
Bordo, Michael D. and Jopseh G. Haubrich. 2012DR. Deep recessions, fast recoveries, and financial crises: evidence from the American record. Cleveland, OH, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, WP 12/14 http://www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/2012/wp1214.pdf
Bordo, Michael D. and John Landon-Lane. 2013. Does expansionary monetary policy cause asset price booms; some historical and empirical evidence. Cambridge, MA, National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 19585, Oct 2013 http://www.nber.org/papers/w19585
Bordo, Michael D. and Peter Rousseau. 2006. Legal political factors and the historical evolution of the finance-growth link. NBER Working Paper No. 12035. Cambridge, MA, National Bureau of Economic Research, Feb. Earlier presented at CPRN/ONB Workshop on International Financial Integration: The Role of Intermediaries, Vienna, 30 Sep-1Oct 2005.
Boskin, Michael J. 2010Sep. Summer of economic discontent. Wall Street Journal, Sep 2 http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052748703882304575465462926649950.html?KEYWORDS=michael+boskin
Bricker, Jesse, Arthur B. Kennickell, Kevin B. Moore and John Sabelhaus. 2012. Changes in US family finances from 2007 to 2010: evidence from the Survey of Consumer Finances. Federal Reserve Bulletin 98 (2, Jun): 2-80 http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/bulletin/2012/PDF/scf12.pdf
Brunner, Karl and Allan H. Meltzer. 1973. Mr. Hicks and the “monetarists.” Economica NS 40 (157, Feb): 44-59.
Brunnermeier, Markus K. and Lasse Hege Pedersen. 2009. Market liquidity and funding liquidity. Review of Financial Studies 22 (6): 2201-38.
Buiter, Willem. 2011Oct31. EFSF needs bigger bazooka to maximize its firepower. Financial Times, Oct 31 http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/c4886f7a-03d3-11e1-bbc5-00144feabdc0.html#axzz1cMoq63R5
Buiter, Willem. 2012Oct15. Only big debt restructuring can save euro. Financial Times, Oct 15 http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/edd92eee-12de-11e2-aa9c-00144feabdc0.html#axzz29OP0k8cX
Buiter, Willem. 2014Feb4. The Fed’s bad manners risk offending foreigners. Financial Times, Feb 4 http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/fbb09572-8d8d-11e3-9dbb-00144feab7de.html#axzz2suwrwkFs
Brunner, Karl and Allan H. Meltzer. 1973. Mr. Hicks and the “monetarists.” Economica NS 40 (157, Feb): 44-59.
Burdekin, Richard C. 2005. US pressure on China’s currency: Milton Friedman and the silver episode revisited. Claremont McKenna College, Nov 2005 http://www.claremontmckenna.edu/rdschool/papers/2005-07.pdf
Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2011Feb11. Overview of seasonal adjustment of the current employment statistics program. Washington, Feb 11, 2011 http://www.bls.gov/ces/cessa_oview.pdf
Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2012Feb3. Seasonal adjustment files and documentation. Washington, BLD, Feb 3 http://www.bls.gov/web/empsit/cesseasadj.htm
Caballero, Ricardo and Francsco Giavazzi. 2012Jan15. Parity may be euro’s last chance. Bloomberg, Jan 15 http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2012-01-16/dollar-parity-may-be-euro-salvation-commentary-by-caballero-and-giavazzi.html
Cagan, Phillip. 1965. Determinants and effects of changes in the stock of money, 1875-1960. New York: Columbia University Press.
Calomiris, Charles C. and Gary B. Gorton. 1991. The origins of banking panics: models, facts and bank regulation. In R. Glenn Hubbard, ed. Financial markets and financial crises. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Calomiris, Charles W. and Stephen H. Haber. 2014. Fragile by design: the political origins of banking crises and scarce credit. Princeton: Princeton University Press http://press.princeton.edu/titles/10177.html
Calomiris, Charles W. 2017Apr. Why Trump might win with China. Wall Street Journal, Apr 17 https://www.wsj.com/articles/why-trump-might-win-with-china-1492469922
Cameron, Rondo E. 1961. France and the economic development of Europe 1800-1914: conquests of peace and seeds of war. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Cameron, Rondo E. 1967. Banking in the early stages of industrialization. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Cameron, Rondo E. 1972. Banking and economic development. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Cameron, Rondo E. 1989. A concise economic history of the world: from Paleolithic times to the present. New York and Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Cameron, Rondo E., V.I. Bovkyn, Richard Sylla, Mira Wilkins, Boris Anan’ich, and A. A. Fursenko, eds. 1992. International Banking 1870-1914. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
CBO. 2011JunLTBO. CBO’s long-term budget outlook. Washington, DC, Congressional Budget Office, Jun http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/122xx/doc12212/06-21-Long-Term_Budget_Outlook.pdf
CBO. 2012JanBEO. The budget and economic outlook: fiscal years 2012 to 2022. Washington, DC: Congressional Budget Office, Jan http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/126xx/doc12699/01-31-2012_Outlook.pdf
CBO. 2012Jan31. Historical budget data. Washington, DC, Jan 31.
CBO. 2012MarBEO. Updated budget projections: fiscal years 2012 to 2022. Washington, DC: Congressional Budget Office, Mar http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/attachments/March2012Baseline.pdf
CBO. 2012LTBO. The 2012 long-term budget outlook. Washington, DC: Congressional Budget Office, Jun http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/attachments/06-05-Long-Term_Budget_Outlook.pdf
CBO. 2012AugBEO. An update to the budget and economic outlook: fiscal years 2012 to 2022. Washington, DC, Congressional Budget Office, Aug http://www.cbo.gov/publication/43539
CBO. 2012NovMBR. Monthly budget review fiscal year 2012. Washington, DC, Congressional Budget Office, Nov 7 http://www.cbo.gov/publication/43698
CBO. 2012NovCDR. Choices for deficit reduction. Washington, DC, Congressional Budget Office http://www.cbo.gov/publication/43692
CBO. 2012NovEEP. Economic effects of policies contributing to fiscal tightening in 2013. Washington, DC, Congressional Budget Office, Nov http://www.cbo.gov/publication/43694
CBO. 2013BEOFeb5. The budget and economic outlook: fiscal years 2013 to 2023. Washington, DC, Congressional Budget Office http://www.cbo.gov/publication/43907
CBO. 2013HBDFeb5. Historical budget data—February 2013 baseline projections. Washington, DC, Congressional Budget Office http://www.cbo.gov/publication/43904
CBO. 2013MEFeb5. Macroeconomic effects of alternative budget paths. Washington, DC, Congressional Budget Office, Feb 5 http://www.cbo.gov/publication/43769
CBO (2013Aug12). 2013AugHBD. Historical budget data—August 2013. Washington, DC, Congressional Budget Office, Aug 12 http://www.cbo.gov/publication/44507
CBO (2013Aug12Av). Kim Kowaleski and Amber Marcellino. Updated historical budget data. CBO, Aug 12 http://www.cbo.gov/publication/44508
CBO (2013Sep11). 2013Sep11. CBO’s baseline budget projections updated. Washington, DC, Congressional Budget Office, Sep 11 http://www.cbo.gov/publication/44574
CBO (2013Sep17). The 2013 long-term budget outlook. Washington, DC, Congressional Budget Office, Sep 17 http://www.cbo.gov/publication/44521
Chung, Hess, Jean-Philippe Laforte, David Reifschneider and John C. Williams. 2011. Have we underestimated the likelihood and severity of zero lower bound events? San Francisco, FRBSF, WP 2011-01 http://www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/papers/2011/wp11-01bk.pdf
Clark, Colin. 1957. The conditions of economic progress. London: Macmillan.
Cline, William. 2001. The role of the private sector in resolving financial crises in emerging markets. Cambridge, MA, NBER, Jun.
Cline, William. 2002. Private sector involvement: definition, measurement and implementation. London, Bank of England Conference, Jul-23-4.
Coastworth, John H. 1981. Growth against development: the economic impact of railroads in Portfirian Mexico. DeKalb, Ill: Northern Illinois University Press.
Coastworth, John H. 2006. Counterfactual Mexicos. History Compass 4(1), 176-80.
Cobet, Aaron E. and Gregory A. Wilson. 2002. Comparing 50 years of labor productivity in US and foreign manufacturing. Monthly Labor Review (Jun): 51-65.
Cochrane, John A. 2010A. The government debt valuation equation. An appendix to “Understanding policy.” http://faculty.chicagobooth.edu/john.cochrane/research/Papers/
Cochrane, John H. 2011Jan. Understanding policy in the great recession: some unpleasant fiscal arithmetic. European Economic Review 55 (1, Jan): 2-30.
Cochrane, John H. 2012Aug31. The Federal Reserve: from central bank to central planner. Wall Street Journal, Aug 31 http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10000872396390444812704577609384030304936.html?mod=WSJ_hps_sections_opinion
Cochrane, John H. 2014Jul2. The failure of macroeconomics. Wall Street Journal, Jul 2. http://online.wsj.com/articles/john-cochrane-new-keynesian-macroeconomic-models-dont-support-more-stimulus-spending-1404342631?KEYWORDS=john+h+cochrane
Cochrane, John H. 2016May02. Ending America’s slow-growth tailspin. Wall Street Journal, May 2. http://www.wsj.com/articles/ending-americas-slow-growth-tailspin-1462230818#:kf42ZuSoKO6LcA
Cochrane, John H. and Luigi Zingales. 2009. Lehman and the financial crisis. Wall Street Journal, Sep 15.
Cohen, Morris Raphael and Ernest Nagel. 1934. An introduction to logic and scientific method. New York: Harcourt, Brace and Company.
Cole, Harold L. and Lee E. Ohanian. 1999. The Great Depression in the United States from a neoclassical perspective. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 23 (1, Winter): 2-24.
Cole, Harold L. and Narayana Kocherlakota. 1998. Zero nominal interest rates: why they are good and how to get them. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 22 (2, Spring): 2-10.
Cooley, Thomas F. and Lee E. Ohanian. 2010. FDR and the lessons of the Depression. Wall Street Journal, Aug 27 http://online.wsj.com/news/articles/SB10001424052748703461504575443402028756986?KEYWORDS=Thomas+Cooley
Contador, Cláudio R. and Haddad, Cláudio L. 1975. Produto real, moeda e preços. Revista Brasileira de Estatística 36(143, jul/set): 407-40.
Cox, John C., Jonathan E. Ingersoll, Jr. and Stephen A. Ross. 1981. A re-examination of traditional hypotheses about the term structure of interest rates. Journal of Finance 36 (4, Sep): 769-99.
Cox, John C., Jonathan E. Ingersoll, Jr. and Stephen A. Ross. 1985. A theory of the term structure of interest rates. Econometrica 53 (2, Mar): 385-407.
Culbertson, John M. 1957. The term structure of interest rates. Quarterly Journal of Economics 71 (4, Nov): 485-517.
Culbertson, J. M. 1960. Friedman on the lag in effect of monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy 68 (6, Dec): 617-21.
Culbertson, J. M. 1961. The lag in effect of monetary policy: reply. Journal of Political Economy 69 (5, Oct): 467-77.
Culbertson, John M. 1963. The term structure of interest rates: reply. Quarterly Journal of Economics 77 (4, Nov): 691-6.
D’Amico Stefania and Thomas B. King. 2010. Flow and stock effects of large-sale Treasury purchases. Washington, DC, Federal Reserve board, Sep.
Darby, Michael R. Darby. 1974. The permanent income theory of consumption—a restatement. Quarterly Journal of Economics (88, 2): 228-50.
Deane, Phyllis. 1968. New estimates of gross national product for the United Kingdom 1830-1914. Review of Income and Wealth 14 (2, Jun): 95-112.
Delfim Netto, Antonio. 1959. O problema do café no Brasil. São Paulo: Faculdade de Economia e Administração da Universidade de São Paulo. Partly reprinted in Pelaez (1973).
De Long, J. Bradford. 1997. America’s peacetime inflation: the 1970s. In Christina D. Romer and David H. Romer, eds. Reducing inflation: motivation and strategy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1997.
DeLong, J. Bradford and Barry Eichengreen. 2001Jul. Between meltdown and moral hazard: the international monetary and financial policies of the Clinton Administration. Cambridge, MA, Conference on the Economic Policies of the Clinton Administration, Kennedy School of Government, Jun 26-29 http://eml.berkeley.edu/~eichengr/research/clintonfinancialpolicies9.pdf
DeNavas-Walt, Carmen, Bernadette D. Proctor and Jessica C. Smith. 2012Sep. Income, poverty and health insurance coverage in the United States: 2011. Washington, DC, US Census Bureau http://www.census.gov/prod/2012pubs/p60-243.pdf
DeNavas-Walt, Carmen, Bernadette D. Proctor and Jessica C. Smith. 2013. Income, poverty, and health insurance coverage in the United States: 2012. Washington, DC: US Census Bureau, Current Population Reports, P60-245, US Government Printing Office http://www.census.gov/prod/2013pubs/p60-245.pdf
DeNavas-Walt, Carmen and Bernadette D. Proctor. 2014. Income and poverty in the United States: 2013. Washington, DC: US Census Bureau, Current Population Reports P60-249, US Government Printing Office, Sep 18.
DeNavas-Walt, Carmen and Bernadette D. Proctor. 2015. Income and poverty in the United States: 2014. Washington, DC: US Census Bureau, Current Population Reports P60-252, US Government Printing Office, Sep.
Doh, Taeyoung. 2010. The efficacy of large-scale asset purchases at the zero lower bound. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review Second Quarter 2010: 5-34 http://www.kansascityfed.org/Publicat/EconRev/PDF/10q2Doh.pdf
Dorrance, G. S. 1948. The income terms of trade. Review of Economic Studies 16 (1, 1948-1949): 50-6.
Draghi, Mario. 2011Dec1. Introductory statement by Mario Draghi, President of the ECB. Brussels, Hearing before the Plenary of the European Parliament, Dec 1 http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2011/html/sp111201.en.html
Draghi, Mario. 2011Dec8. Introductory statement to the press conference. Frankfurt am Main, ECB, Dec 8 http://www.ecb.int/press/pressconf/2011/html/is111208.en.html
Draghi, Mario. 2012May26. Speech by Mario Draghi, President of the European Central Bank. London, Global Investment Conference, Jul 26 http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2012/html/sp120726.en.html
Draghi, Mario. 2012Aug29. The future of the euro: stability through change. Frankfurt am Main, ECB, published in Die Zeit, 29 Aug 2012 http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2012/html/sp120829.en.html
Duffie, Darell and Kenneth J. Singleton. 2003. Credit risk: pricing, measurement and management. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Eggertsson, Gauti B. and Paul Krugman. 2010. Debt, deleveraging and the liquidity trap: A Fisher-Minsky-Koo approach. Princeton, Princeton University, Nov 16 http://www.princeton.edu/~pkrugman/debt_deleveraging_ge_pk.pdf
European Council. 2011Dec9. Statements by the euro area heads of state or government. Brussels, European Union, Dec 9 http://www.consilium.europa.eu/uedocs/cms_Data/docs/pressdata/en/ec/126658.pdf
European Council. 2012Oct19. Conclusions. Brussels, European Union, Oct 19 http://www.consilium.europa.eu/uedocs/cms_data/docs/pressdata/en/ec/133004.pdf
DeNavas-Walt, Carmen, Bernadette D. Proctor and Jessica C. Smith. 2012Sep. Income, poverty and health insurance coverage in the United States: 2011. Washington, DC, US Census Bureau, US Government Printing Office, Sep http://www.census.gov/prod/2012pubs/p60-243.pdf
Diamond, DouglasW. 1984. Financial intermediation and delegated monitoring. Review of Economic Studies 51: 393-414.
Diamond, Douglas W. 1996. Financial intermediation as delegated monitoring: a simple example. Economic Quarterly Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond 82 (3): 51-66.
Diamond, Douglas W. and Philip H. Dybvig. 1983. Bank runs, deposit insurance and liquidity. Journal of Political Economy 91 (3, Jun): 401-49.
Diamond, Douglas W. and Philip H. Dybvig. 1986. Banking theory, deposit insurance and bank regulation. Journal of Business 59 (1, Jan): 55-68.
Diamond, Douglas W. and Raghuram G. Rajan. 2000. A theory of bank capital. Journal of Finance 55 (6, Dec): 2431-65.
Diamond, Douglas W. and Raghuram G. Rajan. 2001a. Banks and liquidity. American Economic Review 91 (2, May): 422-5.
Diamond, Douglas W. and Raghuram G. Rajan. 2001b. Liquidity Risk, liquidity creation and financial fragility: a theory of banking. Journal of Political Economy 109 (2, Apr): 287-327.
Dornbusch, Rudiger. 1976. Expectations and exchange rate dynamics. Journal of Political Economy 84 (6, Dec): 1161-76.
Draghi, Mario. 2011Dec15. The euro, monetary stability and the design of a fiscal compact. Berlin, Dec 15 http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2011/html/sp111215.en.html
Draghi, Mario. 2012May3. Introductory statement to the press conference. Barcelona, May 3 http://www.ecb.int/press/pressconf/2012/html/is120503.en.html
Draghi, Mario. 2012Jun15. President’s address at the 14th ECB and its Watchers Conference. Frankfurt am Main, European Central Bank, Jun 15 http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2012/html/sp120615.en.html
Economides, Nicholas, Yannis Ioannides, Emmanuel Petrakis, Christopher Pissarides and Thanasis Stengos. 2012. What’s at stake in the Greek vote. Wall Street Journal, Jun 14 http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052702303822204577466541312448940.html?mod=WSJ_hps_sections_opinion
Eichengreen, Barry and Jeffrey Sachs. 1985. Exchange rates and economic recovery in the 1930s. Journal of Economic History 45 (4, Dec): 925-46.
Eggertson, Gauti B. and Michael Woodford. 2003. The zero bound on interest rates and optimal monetary policy. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity I (2003): 139-211.
European Central Bank. 2011MBDec. Editorial. Monthly Bulletin December 2011, 5-9 http://www.ecb.int/pub/pdf/mobu/mb201112en.pdf
European Commission. 2011Oct26SS. Euro summit statement. Brussels, European Commission, Oct 26 http://ec.europa.eu/news/economy/111027_en.htm
European Commission. 2011Oct26MRES. Main results of Euro Summit. Brussels, European Commission, Oct 26 http://www.consilium.europa.eu/uedocs/cms_Data/docs/pressdata/en/ec/125645.pdf
European Council. 2011Dec9. Statements by the euro area heads of state or government. Brussels, European Union, Dec 9 http://www.consilium.europa.eu/uedocs/cms_Data/docs/pressdata/en/ec/126658.pdf
Evans, Charles. 2010. Monetary policy in a low-inflation environment: developing a state-contingent price-level target. Boston, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston’s 55th Economic Conference, Oct 16 http://chicagofed.org/webpages/publications/speeches/2010/10_16_boston_speech.cfm#_ftn1
Evans, Charles. 2012Aug27. Some thoughts on global risks and monetary policy. Hong Kong, China, Market News International Seminar, Aug 27 http://www.chicagofed.org/webpages/publications/speeches/2012/08_27_12_hongkong.cfm
Evans, Charles. 2012Nov27. Monetary policy in challenging times. Toronto, Canada, Howe Institute, Nov 27
http://www.chicagofed.org/webpages/publications/speeches/2012/11_27_12_cdhowe.cfm
Fabozi, Frank J., Gerald W. Buestow, Jr., and Robert R. Johnson. Measuring interest rate risk. In Frank J. Fabozzi, ed. The handbook of fixed income securities, 7th Edition. New York, McGraw, 2006.
Fama, Eugene F. 1970. Efficient capital markets: a review of theory and empirical work. Journal of Finance 25 (2): 383-417.
Fama, Eugene F. and Robert R. Bliss. 1987. The information in long-maturity forward rates. American Economic Review 77 (4, Sep): 680-92.
Feldstein, Martin. 2016. A Federal Reserve oblivious to its effect on financial markets. Wall Street Journal, Jan 13 http://www.wsj.com/articles/a-federal-reserve-oblivious-to-its-effect-on-financial-markets-1452729166
Fisher, Irving. 1930. The theory of interest. New York: The Macmillan Company http://www.econlib.org/library/YPDBooks/Fisher/fshToI19.html
Fisher, Irving. 1933. The debt-deflation theory of great depressions. Econometrica 1(4): 337-57.
Fisher, Irving. 100% Money. 1936. New York: Adelphi Company.
Fishlow, Albert. 1965. American railroads and the transformation of the ante-bellum economy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Feldstein, Martin. 2012Mar19. Obama’s tax hikes threaten a new US recession. Financial Times, Mar 19 http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/0d0e7acc-6f7d-11e1-9c57-00144feab49a.html#axzz1pexRlsiQ
Fleming, J. Marcus. 1962. Domestic financial policies under fixed and under floating exchange rates. IMF Staff Papers 9: 369-79.
Fogel, Robert W. 1964. Railroads and American economic growth: essays in econometric history. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Fogel, Robert W. and Stanley Engerman. 1974. Time on the cross. Boston: Little Brown.
Forbes, Kristin J. 2012JHAug9. The big “C”: identifying and mitigating contagion. Jackson Hole, WY, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Symposium, Aug 31 http://www.kansascityfed.org/publicat/sympos/2012/kf.pdf
Friedman, Milton. 1953. The effects of a full-employment policy on economic stability: a formal analysis. In Milton Friedman, Essays on positive economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Friedman, Milton. 1953b. The case for flexible exchange rates. In Milton Friedman, Essays on positive economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press: 157-203.
Friedman, Milton. 1957. A Theory of the Consumption Function. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Friedman, Milton. 1961. The lag in effect of monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy 69 (5, Oct): 447-66.
Friedman, Milton. 1964. The monetary studies of the National Bureau. In The National Bureau enters its forty-fifth year. New York, NY: National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc., Forty-Fourth Annual Report: 7-25 http://www.nber.org/chapters/c4453.pdf
Friedman, Milton. 1968. The role of monetary policy. American Economic Review 58 (1, Mar): 1-17.
Friedman, Milton. 1969. The optimum quantity of money. In Milton Friedman, The optimum quantity of money and other essays. Chicago: Aldine, 1969.
Friedman, Milton. 1970. Controls on interest rates paid by banks. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 2 (1, Feb): 15-32.
Friedman, Milton. 1982. Monetary policy: theory and practice. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 14 (1, Feb): 98-118.
Friedman, Milton. 1988. The “plucking model” of business fluctuations revisited. Palo Alto, CA, The Hoover Institution, Stanford University, Working Papers in Economics E-88-48, Dec 1988.
Friedman, Milton. 1989. Bimetalism revisited. Palo Alto, CA, The Hoover Institution, Stanford University, Working Papers in Economics E-89-24. Aug 1989.
Friedman, Milton. Franklin D. Roosevelt, Silver and China. Journal of Political Economy 100 (1, Feb): 62-83.
Friedman, Milton and Anna Jacobson Schwartz. 1963. A monetary history of the United States, 1867-1960. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Friedman, Milton and Anna Jacobson Schwartz. 1963a. Money and business cycles. Review of Economics and Statistics 45, Supplement (Feb): 32-64.
Friedman, Milton and Anna Jacobson Schwartz. 1970. Monetary statistics of the United States: estimates, sources, and methods. New York: Columbia University Press.
Friedman, Milton and Anna Jacobson Schwartz. 1987. Money and business cycles. In Anna Jacobson Schwartz, ed. Money in historical perspective. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Friedman, Milton and Gary S. Becker. 1957. A statistical illusion in judging Keynesian models. Journal of Political Economy 65 (1, Feb): 64-75.
FOMC. 2006Dec12. Meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee December 12, 2006. Washington, DC, Federal Reserve, Dec 12 http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/FOMC20061212meeting.pdf
Gagnon, Joseph, Matthew Raskin, Julie Remache and Brian Sack. 2010. Large-scale asset purchases by the Federal Reserve: did they work. New York, FRBNY Staff Report no. 441, Mar http://data.newyorkfed.org/research/staff_reports/sr441.pdf
Georgescu-Rogen, Nicholas. 1960. Economic theory and agrarian economics. Oxford Economic Papers New Series 12 (1, Feb): 1-40.
Gorton, Gary. 2009EFM. The subprime panic. European Financial Management 15 (1): 10-46.
Graham, Frank D. 1936. Partial reserve money and the 100 per cent proposal. American Economic Review (26, 3): 428-40.
Gorton, Gary and Andrew Metrick. 2010H. Haircuts. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 92 (6, Nov/Dec): 507-19 http://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/review/10/11/Gorton.pdf
Gorton, Gary and Andrew Metrick. 2010SB. Securitized banking and the run on repo. New Haven, Yale University, 2010, Nov.
Greenspan, Alan. 1996. The challenge of central banking in a democratic society. Washingotn, DC, American Enterprise Institute, Dec 5 http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/1996/19961205.htm
Greenspan, Alan. 2004. Risk and uncertainty in monetary policy. American Economic Review 94 (2, May): 33-40. Also available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2004/20040103/default.htm
Gürkaynak, Refet S., Brian Sack and Eric T. Swanson. 2005. Do actions speak louder than words? The response of asset prices to monetary policy actions and statements. International Journal of Central Banking 1 (May): 55-93.
Haber, Stephen. 2011. Differential paths of financial development: evidence from new world economies. In Dora L. Costa and Naomi R. Lamoreaux, eds. Understanding long-run economic growth: geography, institutions and the knowledge economy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2011, 89-120.
Haberler, Gottfried. 1937. Prosperity and depression. Lake Success, New York: United Nations. http://mises.org/document/4617/
Haddad, Cláudio L. 1974. Growth of Brazilian real output. Chicago, Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Chicago, Jun.
Hallerbach, Winfried G. 2001. Duration and Dimension. Tinbergen Institute Working Paper No. TI 99-047/2, Erasmus University, Amsterdam, the Netherlands http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/cf_dev/AbsByAuth.cfm?per_id=89567
Hamilton, Alexander. 1780. The national Bank. In Henry Cabot Lodge, ed. The works of Alexander Hamilton. New York and London: G. P. Putnam & Sons, 1904: 319-45. http://oll.libertyfund.org/?option=com_staticxt&staticfile=show.php%3Ftitle=1380&chapter=64319&layout=html#a_1594266
Hamilton, James D. and Jing Wu. 2010. The effectiveness of alternative monetary policy tools in a zero lower bound environment. San Diego, University of California San Diego, Nov 3 http://dss.ucsd.edu/~jhamilto/zlb.pdf
Hansen, Alvin H. 1938. Full recovery of stagnation? New York: W. W. Norton & Co., 1938.
Hansen, Alvin H. 1939. Economic progress and declining population growth. American Economic Review 29, 1 (Mar, 1939): 1-15.
Hansen, Alvin H. 1941. Fiscal policy and business cycles. New York: W. W. Norton & Co., 1941.
Harberger, Arnold C. 1971. Three basic postulates for applied welfare economics: an interpretive essay. Journal of Economic Literature 9 (3): 785-97.
Harberger, Arnold C. 1997. New frontiers in project evaluation? World Bank Research Observer 12 (1): 73-9.
Harris, Jennifer M. 2011BA. Benchmark article. Washington, DC, Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/ces/cesbmart.pdf
Herkenhoff, Kyle F., Lee E. Ohanian and Edward C. Prescott. 2017. Tarnishing the Golden and Empire States: Land-Use Restrictions and the U.S. Economic Slowdown. NBER Working Paper No. 23790, Apr 2017 https://sites.google.com/site/kyleherkenhoff/research
Harrod, Roy F. 1939. International economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1939.
Hetzel, Robert L. and Ralph F. Leach. 2001. The Treasury-Fed accord: a new narrative account. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 87 (1, Winter): 33-55.
Hicks, John R. 1935. A suggestion for simplifying the theory of money. Economica NS 2 (5, Feb): 1-19.
Hicks, John R. 1937. Mr. Keynes and the “classics”: a suggested interpretation. Econometrica 5 (2, Apr): 147-59.
Hicks, John R. 1950. A contribution to the theory of the trade cycle. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1950.
Hicks, John R. 1962. Liquidity. Economic Journal 72 (288, Dec): 787-802.
Hicks, John R. 1975. The scope and status of welfare economics. Oxford Economic Papers 27 (3): 307-26.
Hill, Jonathan B. 2007. Efficient tests of long-run causality in trivariate VAR processes with a rolling window study of the money-income relationship. Journal of Applied Econometrics 22 (2007): 747-765. Published online in Wiley InterScience www.interscience.wiley.com http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1002/jae.925/full
Imlah, Albert H. 1958. Economic elements in the Pax Britannica. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1958.
Ho, Tai-kuang and Cheng-chung Lai. 2012. Silver fetters? The rise and fall of Chinese price level under fluctuating world silver price, 1928-34. Hsinchu, Taiwan, National Tsiang Hua University, Nov http://apebh2013.files.wordpress.com/2013/02/ho-lai-textrv.pdf
Hobbs, Frank and Nicole Stoops. 2002. Demographic trends in the 20th century. Washington, DC, US Government Printing Office http://www.census.gov/prod/2002pubs/censr-4.pdf
Hoover, Ethel D. 1958. Wholesale and retail prices in the nineteenth century. Journal of Economic History 18 (3, Sep): 298-316.
Hoover, Ethel D. 1960. Retail prices after 1850. In Trends in the American economy in the nineteenth century. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1960.
IMF. 2011WEOSep. World economic outlook Sep 11: slowing growth, rising risks. Washington, DC, IMF Sep http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2011/02/pdf/text.pdf
IMF. 2011JSRNov23. Japan sustainability report. Washington, DC, IMF, Nov 23 http://www.imf.org/external/np/country/2011/mapjapanpdf.pdf
IMF. 2012GFSRJan24. Global Financial Stability Report: market update. Washington, DC, IMF, Jan 24 http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fmu/eng/2012/01/index.htm
IMF. 2012FMJan24. Fiscal Monitor Update. Washington, DC, IMF, Jan 24 http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fm/2012/update/01/fmindex.htm
IMF. 2012WEOJan24. World Economic Outlook Update: an update of the key WEO projections. Washington, DC, IMF, Jan 24 http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2012/update/01/index.htm
IMF. 2012WEOApr. World Economic Outlook April 2012: growth resuming, dangers remains. Washington, DC, IMF, 2012, Apr http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2012/01/pdf/text.pdf
IMF. 2012GFSRApr. Global financial stability report: the quest for lasting stability. Washington, DC, IMF 2012, Apr http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/gfsr/2012/01/pdf/text.pdf
IMF. 2012FMApr. Fiscal monitor: balancing fiscal policy risks. Washington, DC, IMF, Apr
http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fm/2012/01/pdf/fm1201.pdf
IMFC. 2012Apr20. Joint Statement of the International Monetary and Financial Committee and the Group of 20 Finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors on IMF Resources. Washington, DC, IMF, Apr 20 http://www.imf.org/external/np/sec/pr/2012/pr12144.htm
IMFC. 2012Apr21. Communiqué of the Twenty-Fifth Meeting of the IMFC. Washington, DC, IMF, Apr 21 http://www.imf.org/external/np/sec/pr/2012/pr12145.htm
IMF. 2012FSAPJun8. Spain: Financial Stability Assessment. Washington, DC, International Monetary Fund, Jun http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/scr/2012/cr12137.pdf
IMF. 2012FMOct. Fiscal Monitor: taking stock a progress report on fiscal adjustment. Washington, DC, International Monetary Fund, Oct http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fm/2012/02/pdf/fm1202.pdf
IMF. 2012GFSROct. Global Financial and Stability Report: restoring confidence and progressing on reforms. Washington, DC, International Monetary Fund, Oct http://www.imf.org/External/Pubs/FT/GFSR/2012/02/pdf/text.pdf
IMF. 2012WEOOct. World Economic Outlook October 2012: coping with high debt and sluggish growth. Washington, DC, International Monetary Fund, Oct http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2012/02/pdf/text.pdf
Ingersoll, Jonathan. 1987. Theory of Financial Decision Making. New Jersey: Rowman.
Ireland, Peter N. 1999. Does the time-consistency problem explain the behavior of inflation in the United States. Journal of Monetary Economics 44 (2): 279-91.
Ireland, Peter N. 2003. Implementing the Friedman rule. Review of Economic Dynamics 6(2003): 120-134.
Issa, Darrell E. 2012Aug1. Letter to the Honorable Ben Bernanke. Washington DC, Committee on Oversight and Government Reform, Congress of the United States, House of Representatives, Aug 1 http://online.wsj.com/public/resources/documents/Bernankeletter0812.pdf
Ito, Takatoshi. Interventions and Japanese economic recovery. YenMacro, Michigan 2004 1 http://www.fordschool.umich.edu/rsie/Conferences/CGP/Oct2004Papers/Ito.pdf
Jensen, Michael C. 1993. The modern industrial revolution, exit and the failure of internal control systems. Journal of Finance 48 (3, Jul): 831-80.
Joint Forum of the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, International Organization of Securities Commissions and the International Association of Supervisors. 2004. Credit risk transfer. BCBS, BIS, Oct. http://www.bis.org/publ/joint10.pdf
Kahil, Raouf. 1973. Inflation and economic development in Brazil. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Kendall, Maurice G. and Alan Stuart. 1968. The advanced theory of statistics, III. New York: Hafner, 1968.
Kim, Chang-Jin and Charles R. Nelson. 1999. Friedman’s plucking model of business fluctuations: tests and estimates of permanent and transitory components. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 31 (3, Part 1, Aug): 317-334.
Kohn, Donald L. 2009Apr18. Monetary policy in the financial crisis. Nashville, TN, Conference in Honor of Dewey Daane, Apr 18 http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/kohn20090418a.htm
Kohn, Donald L. 2009Sep10. Comments on “Interpreting the Unconventional US Monetary policy of 2007-2009.” Washington, Brookings Institution, Sep 10 http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/kohn20090910a.htm
Knight, Frank H. 1964. Risk, uncertainty and profit. New York: Reprints of Economic Classics, August M. Kelley, New York.
Krugman, Paul. 1998. It’s baaack: Japan’s slump and the return of the liquidity trap. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2 (1998): 137-205.
Krugman, Paul. 2011Jun 18. Mr. Keynes and the moderns. Princeton, Princeton University Jun 18. Prepared for Conference on 75th Anniversary of Keynes’ General Theory, Cambridge, Cambridge University, Jun 19-21 http://www.princeton.edu/~pkrugman/keynes_and_the_moderns.pdf
Krugman, Paul. 2012Apr24. Earth to Ben Bernanke: chairman Bernanke should listen to Professor Bernanke. New York Times Magazine, Apr 24 http://www.nytimes.com/2012/04/29/magazine/chairman-bernanke-should-listen-to-professor-bernanke.html?pagewanted=all
Kuznets, Simon. 1971. Modern economic growth: findings and reflections. Lecture to the memory of Alfred Nobel, Dec 11, 1971 http://www.nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economics/laureates/1971/kuznets-lecture.html
Kydland, Finn E. and Edward C. Prescott. 1977. Rules rather than discretion: the inconsistency of optimal plans. Journal of Political Economy 85 (3, Jun): 473-92.
Lazear, Edward P. 2012Jan19. The jobs picture is still far from rosy. Wall Street Journal, Jan 19 http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052970204468004577165292033648810.html
Lazear, Edward P. 2013Jan7. Chinese “currency manipulation” is not the problem. Wall Street Journal, Jan 7 http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424127887323320404578213203581231448.html
Lazear, Edward P. 2017Feb27. How Trump can hit 3% growth—maybe. Wall Street Journal, Feb 27 https://www.wsj.com/articles/how-trump-can-hit-3-growthmaybe-1488239746
Lazear, Edward P. and Spletzer, James R. 2012JHJul22. The United States labor market: status quo or a new normal? Jackson, Hole, WY, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Symposium, Sep 1 http://www.kansascityfed.org/publicat/sympos/2012/el-js.pdf
Lazear, Edward P. and James R. Spletzer. 2012Mar. Hiring, churn and the business cycle. Cambridge, MA, NBER, Mar http://www.nber.org/papers/w17910
Lazear, Edward P. and James R. Spletzer. 2012May. Hiring, churn and the business cycle. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 102 (May, No. 3): 575-579.
Leff, Nathaniel H. 1975. Review of Inflation and Economic Development in Brazil, 1946-1963 by Raouf Kahil. Journal of Economic Literature 12 (2, Jun): 510-11.
Levin, Andrew and John B. Taylor. 2009. Falling behind the curve: a positive analysis of stop-start monetary policies and the Great Inflation. Cambridge, MA, NBER, Dec.
Lintner, John. 1965. The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets. Review of Economics and Statistics 47 (1, Feb): 12-37.
Lucas, Robert E. 1975. An equilibrium model of the business cycle. Journal of Political Economy (83, 6): 1113-1144.
Lucas, Robert E. 1976. Econometric policy evaluation: a critique. Carnegie Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy I (1976): 16-46.
Lucas, Robert E. 2004. The industrial revolution: past and future. In Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis 2003Annual Report, May 1, 2004 http://www.minneapolisfed.org/publications_papers/pub_display.cfm?id=3333
Lucas, Robert E. 2011May. The US recession of 2007-201? Washington, University of Washington, Milliman Lecture, May 19 http://www.econ.washington.edu/news/millimansl.pdf
Macaulay, Frederick R. 1938. Some theoretical problems suggested by the movement of interest rates, bond yields and stock prices in the United States since 1856. New York, National Bureau of Economic Research http://papers.nber.org/books/maca38-1
MacFarlane, Helen and Paul Mortimer-Lee. 1994. Inflation over 300 years. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, May 1994, 156-162.
McGrattan, Ellen R. 2010. Capital taxation during the US Great Depression. Minneapolis, MN, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Working Paper 670, Oct 2010 http://www.minneapolisfed.org/research/wp/wp670.pdf
Mann, Henry B. 1945. Nonparametric tests against trend. Econometrica 13 (3, Jul): 245-259.
Markowitz, Harry. 1952. Portfolio selection. Journal of Finance 7 (1, Mar): 77-91.
McCallum, Bennett. 1999. Issues in the design of monetary policy rules. In John B. Taylor and Michael Woodford, eds. Handbook of Macroeconomics Volume 1A. Amsterdam: Elsevier North Holland.
McKinnon, Ronald I. 1973. Money and Capital in Economic Development. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
McKinnon, Ronald I. 2011Dec18. Oh, for Alexander Hamilton to save Europe! Financial Times, Dec 18 http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/811611d6-273a-11e1-b7ec-00144feabdc0.html#axzz1gzoHXOj6
McKinnon, Ronald I. 2013Oct27. Tapering without tears—how to end QE3. Wall Street Journal, Oct 27.
McKinsey & Co. 2007. Sustaining New York and the US’ global financial services leadership. New York: McKinsey & Co.
Meltzer, Allan H. 2005. Origins of the Great Inflation. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 87 (2, Part 2, Mar/Apr): 145-72.
Meltzer, Allan H. 2004. A history of the federal reserve, Volume 1: 1913-1951. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Meltzer, Allan H. 2010a. A history of the Federal Reserve, Volume 2, Book 1, 1951-1969. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Meltzer, Allan H. 2010b. A history of the Federal Reserve, Volume 2, Book 2, 1970-1986. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Metzler, Lloyd A. The nature and stability of inventory cycles. 1941. Review of Economics and Statistics 23 (3, Aug): 113-29.
Merton, Robert C. 1973. Theory of rational option pricing. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 4 (1, Spring): 141-83.
Merton, Robert C. 1974. On the pricing of corporate debt: the risk structure of interest rates. Journal of Finance 29 (2, May): 449-70.
Merton, Robert C. 1998. Applications of option-pricing theory: twenty-five years later. American Economic Review 88 (3): 323-49.
Meulendyke, Ann-Marie. 1998. U.S. monetary policy and financial markets. New York: Federal Reserve Bank of New York http://www.newyorkfed.org/education/addpub/monpol/
Modigliani, Franco and Richard Sutch. 1966. Innovations in interest rate policy. American Economic Review 56 (1/2, Mar): 178-97.
Modigliani, Franco and Richard Sutch. 1967. Debt management and the term structure of interest rates: an empirical analysis of recent experience. Journal of Political Economy 75 (4, Aug): 569-89.
Mossin, Jan. 1966. 1966. Equilibrium in a capital asset market. Econometrica 34 (4, Oct): 768-83.
Mundell, Robert A. 1963. Capital mobility and stabilization policy under fixed and flexible exchange rates. Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science 29 (4): 475-85.
North, Douglass C. 1994. Economic performance through time. American Economic Review 84 (3): 359-68.
North, Douglass C. and Barry R. Weingast. 1989. Constitutions and commitments: the evolution of institutional governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. Journal of Economic History 49 (4): 803-32.
Nurkse, Ragnar. 1944. International currency experience: lessons of the interwar experience. Geneva, League of Nations.
Nurkse, Ragnar. 1959. Patterns of trade and development. Stockholm: Almquist & Wicksell.
O’Donoghue, Jim and Louise Goulding, 2004. Consumer Price Inflation since 1750. UK Office for National Statistics Economic Trends 604, Mar 2004, 38-46.
Pelaez, Carlos A. 2008. The reform of Alexander Hamilton. Philadelphia, University of Pennsylvania Law School, Unpublished manuscript.
Pelaez, Carlos M. and Carlos A. Pelaez. 2005. International Financial Architecture. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. http://us.macmillan.com/QuickSearchResults.aspx?search=pelaez%2C+carlos&ctl00%24ctl00%24cphContent%24ucAdvSearch%24imgGo.x=26&ctl00%24ctl00%24cphContent%24ucAdvSearch%24imgGo.y=14 http://www.amazon.com/Carlos-Manuel-Pel%C3%A1ez/e/B001HCUT10
Pelaez, Carlos M. and Carlos A. Pelaez. 2007. The Global Recession Risk. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. http://www.amazon.com/Carlos-Manuel-Pel%C3%A1ez/e/B001HCUT10
Pelaez, Carlos M. and Carlos A. Pelaez. 2008a. Globalization and the State: Vol. I. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. http://www.amazon.com/Carlos-Manuel-Pel%C3%A1ez/e/B001HCUT10
Pelaez, Carlos M. and Carlos A. Pelaez. 2008b. Globalization and the State: Vol. II. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Pelaez, Carlos M. and Carlos A. Pelaez. 2008c. Government Intervention in Globalization. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. http://www.amazon.com/Carlos-Manuel-Pel%C3%A1ez/e/B001HCUT10
Pelaez, Carlos M. and Carlos A. Pelaez. 2009a. Financial Regulation after the Global Recession. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. http://www.amazon.com/Carlos-Manuel-Pel%C3%A1ez/e/B001HCUT10
Pelaez, Carlos M. and Carlos A. Pelaez. 2009b. Regulation of Banks and Finance. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.http://www.amazon.com/Carlos-Manuel-Pel%C3%A1ez/e/B001HCUT10
Pelaez, Carlos Manuel. 1968. The State, the Great Depression and the Industrialization of Brazi. New York, PhD Dissertation, Columbia University in the City of New York, Jun.
Pelaez, Carlos Manuel. 1968b. A Balança Comercial, a Grande Depressão e a Industrialização Brasileira. Revista Brasileira de Economia 22 (1, Jan/Mar): 15-47.
Pelaez, Carlos Manuel. 1969. Acerca da política governamental, da Grande Depressão e da Industrialização no Brasil. Revista Brasileira de Economia 23 (3, Jul/Set): 77-88.
Pelaez, Carlos Manuel 1971. Análise econômica do programa brasileiro de sustentação do café—1906-1945. Revista Brasileira de Economia 25 (4, Out/Dez): 5-211.
Pelaez, Carlos Manuel. 1972. História da Industrialização Brasileira. Rio de Janeiro: APEC.
Pelaez, Carlos Manuel, ed. 1973. Essays on Coffee and Economic Development. Rio de Janeiro, IBC, 1973. Portuguese edition: Ensaios sobre Café e Desenvolvimento Econômico. Rio de Janeiro: Instituto Brasileiro do Café, 1973.
Pelaez, Carlos Manuel. 1974. Long-run Monetary Behavior and Institutions in an Underdeveloped Economy, 1800-1971. Copenhaguen, Paper Presented at the VI International Congress on Economic History, Session on Monetary Inflation in Historical Perspective, International Economic History Association, Aug 22.
Pelaez, Carlos Manuel. 1975. The Establishment of Banking Institutions in a Backward Economy: Brazil, 1800-1851. Business History Review 49 (4, Winter): 446-472.
Pelaez, Carlos Manuel. 1976a. The Theory and Reality of Imperialism in the Coffee Economy of Nineteenth-Century Brazil. Economic History Review 29, Second Series (May): 276-294.
Pelaez, Carlos Manuel. 1976b. A Comparison of Long-term Monetary Behavior and Institutions in Brazil, Europe and the United States. Journal of European Economic History 5 (2, Fall): 439-450.
Pelaez, Carlos Manuel. 1977. World War I and the Economy of Brazil: Some Evidence from Monetary Statistics. Journal of Interdisciplinary History (7, Apr): 683-680.
Pelaez, Carlos Manuel. 1979. História Econômica do Brasil: Um Elo entre a Teoria e a Realidade Econômica. São Paulo: Editora Atlas.
Pelaez, Carlos Manuel. 1986. O Cruzado e o Austral: Análise das Reformas Monetárias do Brasil e da Argentina. São Paulo: Editora Atlas.
Pelaez, Carlos Manuel. 1987. Economia Brasileira Contemporânea: Origens e Conjuntura Atual. São Paulo: Editora Atlas.
Pelaez, Carlos Manuel and Wilson Suzigan. 1978. Economia Monetária: Teoria, Política e Evidência Empírica. São Paulo, Atlas.
Pelaez, Carlos Manuel and Wilson Suzigan. 1981. História Monetária do Brasil Segunda Edição. Coleção Temas Brasileiros. Brasília: Universidade de Brasília.
Phelps, Edmund S. 1968. Money-wage dynamics and labor market equilibrium. Journal of Political Economy 76 (4, 2, Jul-Aug): 678-711.
Phelps, Edmund S. 2018. The fantasy of fiscal stimulus. The Wall Street Journal Oct 29, 2018 https://www.wsj.com/articles/the-fantasy-of-fiscal-stimulus-1540852299?mod=searchresults&page=1&pos=2
Pinto, Edward J. 2008. Statement. Washington, DC, US House of Representatives, Committee on Oversight and Government Reform, Dec 9.
Pozsar, Zoltan, Adrian Tobias, Adam Ashcraft and Hayley Boesky. 2012RFeb. Shadow banking. New York: Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Staff Report No. 458, Revised Feb 2012 http://www.newyorkfed.org/research/staff_reports/sr458.pdf
Prescott, Edward C. and Lee E. Ohanian. 2014Feb. US productivity growth has taken a dive. Wall Street Journal, Feb 4 http://online.wsj.com/news/articles/SB10001424052702303942404579362462611843696?KEYWORDS=Prescott
Prescott, Edward C. and Lee E. Ohanian. 2014Jun. Behind the productivity plunge: fewer startups. Wall Street Journal, Jun 25 http://online.wsj.com/articles/behind-the-productivity-plunge-fewer-startups-1403737197?KEYWORDS=Prescott
Prescott, Edward C. and Lee E. Ohanian. 2017Dec. What in the Sam Hill are Cows Doing on Sand Hill Road? Wall Street Journal, Dec 1 https://www.wsj.com/articles/what-in-the-sam-hill-are-cows-doing-on-sand-hill-road-1512171702
Proctor, Bernadette D., Jessica L. Semega and Melissa A. Kollar. 2016. Income and Poverty in the United States: 2015. Washington, D.C., US Census Bureau, Sep 2016 http://www.census.gov/content/dam/Census/library/publications/2016/demo/p60-256.pdf
Reinhart, Carmen M. and Kenneth Rogoff. 2010GTD. Growth in a time of debt. American Economic Review 100 (2): 1-9.
Rajan, Raghuram G. 2004. Remarks. Sydney, Australia, Australasian Finance and Banking Conference, Dec 15.
Rajan, Raghuram G. 2005. Has financial development made the world riskier? Jackson Hole, WY, Symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City. http://www.kc.frb.org/publicat/sympos/2005/PDF/Rajan2005.pdf
Rajan, Raghuram G. 2012May8. Stop beating up on Ben Bernanke. Financial Times, May 8 http://blogs.ft.com/the-a-list/2012/05/08/stop-beating-up-on-ben-bernanke/
Rajan, Raghuram G. 2012FA. The true lessons of the recession: the West can’t borrow and spend its way to recovery. Foreign Affairs 91 (May/June, 3): 69-79.
Rajan, Raghuram G. 2014Apr10. Competitive monetary easing: is it yesterday once more? Washington DC, Brookings Institution, Apr 10 http://www.brookings.edu/~/media/events/2014/04/10%20global%20monetary%20policy%20hutchins/rajan_remarks_at_brookings.pdf
Rajan, Raghuram G. and Luigi Zingales. 2001. The influence of the financial revolution on the nature of the firm. American Economic Review 91 (2): 206-11.
Robinson, Joan. 1947. Beggar-my-neighbour remedies for unemployment. In Joan Robinson, Essays in the Theory of Employment, Oxford, Basil Blackwell, 1947.
Reinhart, Carmen M. 2010CB. This time is different chartbook: country histories on debt, default and financial crises. Cambridge, MA, NBER WP 15815, Mar http://www.nber.org/papers/w15815
Reinhart, Carmen M. and Vincent R. Reinhart. 2011Feb. Pride goes before a fall: Federal Reserve policy and asset markets. Cambridge, MA, NBER WP 16815, Feb http://www.nber.org/papers/w16815
Reinhart, Carmen M. and Vincent R. Reinhart. 2010AF. After the fall. Cambridge, MA, NBER WP 16634, Sep http://www.nber.org/papers/w16334
Reinhart Carmen M., Kenneth S. Rogoff and Miguel A. Savastano. 2003. Debt intolerance. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1 (2003): 1-74.
Reinhart, Carmen M. and Kenneth S. Rogoff. 2008TDPV. This time is different: a panoramic view of eight centuries of financial crises. Cambridge, MA, WP 13882, Mar http://www.nber.org/papers/w13882
Reinhart, Carmen M. and Kenneth S. Rogoff. 2009AFC. The aftermath of financial crises. Cambridge, MA, WP 14656, Jan http://www.nber.org/papers/w14656
Reinhart, Carmen M. and Kenneth Rogoff. 2009TD. This time is different: eight centuries of financial folly. Princeton: Princeton University Press http://www.amazon.com/This-Time-Different-Centuries-Financial/dp/0691142165/ref=pd_sim_b_6
Reinhart, Carmen M. and Kenneth Rogoff. 2010GTD. Growth in a time of debt. American Economic Review 100 (2): 1-9.
Reinhart, Carmen M. and Kenneth S. Rogoff. 2010FCDC. From financial crash to debt crisis. Cambridge, MA, NBER WP 15795, Mar http://www.nber.org/papers/w15795 forthcoming in American Economic Review http://www.aeaweb.org/forthcoming/output/acceptedAER.php
Reinhart, Carmen M. and Kenneth S. Rogoff. 2011CEPR. A decade of debt. Washington, DC, Center for Economic and Policy Research, Discussion Paper No. 8310, Apr. Cambridge, MA, NBER WP 16827, Feb http://www.nber.org/papers/w16827
Reinhart, Carmen M. and Kenneth S. Rogoff. 2011EJ. The forgotten history of domestic debt. Economic Journal 121 (May): 319-350.
Reinhart, Carmen M. and Kenneth S. Rogoff. 2011Jul14. Debt endangers growth. Bloomberg, Jul14 http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2011-07-14/too-much-debt-means-economy-can-t-grow-commentary-by-reinhart-and-rogoff.html
Reinhart, Carmen M. and M. Belen Sbrancia. 2011LD. The liquidation of government debt. Cambridge, MA, NBER WP 16893, Mar http://www.nber.org/papers/w16893
Reinhart, Carmen M. and Kenneth S. Rogoff. 2012Oct14. This time is different, again? The United States five years after the onset of subprime. Cambridge, MA, Harvard University, Oct 14 http://www.economics.harvard.edu/faculty/rogoff/files/Is_US_Different_RR_3.pdf
Rogoff, Kenneth. 2002MF. Dornbusch’s overshooting model after twenty-five years. Washington, DC, IMF, Mundell-Fleming Lecture http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2001/kr/112901.pdf
Roll, Richard. 1977. A critique of the asset pricing theory’s tests. Part I: on past and potential testability of the theory. Journal of Financial Economics 4 (2, Mar): 129-76.
Romer, Christina D. 1992. What ended the Great Depression? Journal of Economic History 52 (4, Dec): 757-84.
Romer, Christina D. 2009. Lessons from the New Deal. Washington DC, Testimony of Christina D. Romer, Chair, President’s Council of Economic Advisers, Before the Economic Policy Subcommittee, Senate Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs, Mar 31 http://www.whitehouse.gov/assets/documents/Testimony_of_Christina_D.pdf
Romer, Christina D. and David H. Romer. 2004. A new measure of monetary shocks: derivation and implications. American Economic Review 94 (4, Sep): 1055-84.
Rubin, Robert. 2014Jan8. Sound government finances will promote recovery. Financial Times, Jan 8.
Samuelson, Paul A. 1964. Theoretical notes on trade problems. Review of Economics and Statistics 46 (2, May): 145.154.
Samuelson, Paul A. 1965. Proof that properly anticipated stock prices fluctuate randomly. Industrial Management Review 6 (2): 41-9.
Samuelson, Paul A. 1974. Lessons from the current economic expansion. American Economic Review 64 (2, May): 75-7.
Sargent, Thomas J. 1983. The end of four big inflations. In Robert E. Hall, ed. Inflation: causes and effects. Chicago: Chicago University Press.
Sargent, Thomas J. and Christopher A. Sims. 1977. Business cycle modelling without pretending to have too much a priori economic theory. In Christopher A. Sims, ed. New methods in business cycle research. Minneapolis: Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.
Sargent, Thomas J. and Neil Wallace. 1973. The stability of models of money and growth with perfect foresight. Econometrica 41 (6, Nov): 1043-8.
Sargent, Thomas J. and Neil Wallace. 1981. Some unpleasant monetarist arithmetic. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 5 (3, Fall): 1-17.
Sargent, Thomas J. and William L. Silber. 2012Mar20. The challenges of the Fed’s bid for transparency. Financial Times, Mar 20 http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/778eb1ce-7288-11e1-9c23-00144feab49a.html#axzz1pexRlsiQ
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1939. Business cycles: a theoretical, historical and statistical analysis of the capitalist process. New York and London: McCraw Hill Book Company.
Seers, Dudley. 1962. A theory of inflation and growth in under-developed economies based on the experience of Latin America. Oxford Economic Papers New Series 14 (Jun, 2): 173-95.
Seligman, Edwin R. A. 1908. The crisis of 1907 in the light of history. Introduction to The currency problem and the present financial situation. New York: Columbia University Press http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/docs/publications/books/currencyprob/1908currencyproblem_introduction.pdf
Sharpe, William F. 1964. Capital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. Journal of Finance 19 (3, Sep): 425-42.
Shaw, Edward S. 1973. Financial Deepening in Economic Development. New York: Oxford University Press.
Shikida, Claudio Djissey, Ari Francisco de Araujo Jr and Eirk Figueiredo. 2014. Política monetária, produto e preços: contribuições de Peláez e um teste de tri-causalidade para o período 1861-1970. Revista de Economia e Administração, 13 (3, jul/set): 312-27.
Shultz, George P., Michael J. Boskin, John F. Cogan, Allan H. Meltzer and John B. Taylor. 2012. The magnitude of the mess we’re in. Wall Street Journal, Sep 16, 2012 http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052702303561504577497442109193610.html?mod=WSJ_hps_sections_opinion
Simons, Henry C. 1936. Rules versus authorities in monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy 44 (1, Feb): 1-30.
Simons, Henry C. 1942. Hansen on fiscal policy. Journal of Political Economy 50 (2, Apr): 161-96.
Simons, Henry C. 1948. Economic Policy for a free society. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Sims, Christopher A. 1972. Money, income and causality. American Economic Review 62 (4, Sep): 540-52.
Singer, Hans W. 1950. The distribution of gains between investing and borrowing countries. American Economic Review 40 (2, May): 473-485.
Smith, Jessica C. and Carla Medalia. 2014. Health insurance coverage in the United States: 2013. US Current Population Reports, P60-250, US Census Bureau. Washington, DC: US Government Printing Office, Sep 18.
Smith, Jessica C. and Carla Medalia. 2015. Health insurance coverage in the United States: 2014. US Current Population Reports, P60-253, US Census Bureau. Washington, DC: US Government Printing Office, Sep.
Standard & Poor’s Rating Services (S&PRS). 2012Jan13. Standard & Poor’s takes various rating actions on 16 eurozone sovereign governments. Frankfurt, S&P Rating Services, Jan 13 http://www.standardandpoors.com/ratings/articles/en/us/?articleType=HTML&assetID=1245327294763
Standard & Poor’s Rating Services (S&PRS). 2012Jan16. European Financial Stability Facility long-term Ratings Cut to ‘AA+’; short-term ratings affirmed; outlook developing. Frankfurt, S&P Rating Services, Jan 16 http://www.standardandpoors.com/ratings/articles/en/us/?articleType=HTML&assetID=1245327337060
Stein, Stanley J. and Barbara H. Stein. 1970. The colonial heritage of Latin America. New York and London: Oxford University Press.
Summerhill, William R. 1997. Railroads and the Brazilian economy before 1914. Business and Economic History 26 (2, winter), 318-322.
Summerhill, William R. 1998. Market intervention in a backward economy: railway subsidy in Brazil, 1854-1913. Economic History Review LI (3), 542-68.
Summerhill, William R. 2003. Order against progress: government, foreign investment, and railroads in Brazil. 1854-1913. Palo Alto, Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Summerhill, Jr., William R. 2007SC. Sovereign credibility with financial underdevelopment. Palo Alto, CA, Hoover Seminar on Collective Choice, Mar 6.
Summerhill, Jr., William R. 2007IR. Inglorious revolution: political institutions, sovereign debt and financial underdevelopment in Imperial Brazil. Los Angeles, CA, UCLA, Book Manuscript.
Summerhill, William R. 2015. Inglorious revolution: political institutions, sovereign debt, and financial underdevelopment in Brazil. New Haven, CT, Yale University Press https://yalepress.yale.edu/yupbooks/book.asp?isbn=9780300139273
Summers, Lawrence H. 2013Nov8. Presentation. Washington, DC, IMF Fourteenth Annual Research Conference in Honor of Stanley Fischer, IMF, Nov 8 http://larrysummers.com/imf-fourteenth-annual-research-conference-in-honor-of-stanley-fischer/
Svensson, Lars E. 2003. What is wrong with Taylor rules? Using judgment in monetary policy through targeting rules. Journal of Economic Literature 41 (2 Jun): 426–77.
Svensson, Lars E. 2003LT. Escaping from a liquidity trap and deflation: the foolproof way and others. Journal of Economic Perspectives 17 (4, Autumn): 145-66.
Swanson, Eric T. 2011Mar. Let’s twist again: a high-frequency event-study analysis of operation twist and its implication for QE2. Forthcoming in Brookings Papers on Economic Activity http://www.brookings.edu/~/media/Files/Programs/ES/BPEA/2011_spring_bpea_papers/2011_spring_bpea_conference_swanson.pdf
Taylor, Alan M. 2012. The great leveraging. Basel, Switzerland, Bank for International Settlements, Jul http://www.bis.org/events/conf120621/taylor.pdf
Taylor, John B. 1993. Discretion versus policy rules in practice. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 39 (1993): 195-214.
Taylor, John B. 1997. Comment. In Christina Romer and David Romer, eds. Reducing inflation: motivation and strategy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Taylor, John B. 1998LB. Monetary policy and the long boom. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review (Nov-Dec): 3-11.
Taylor, John B. 1999. An historical analysis of monetary policy rules. In John B. Taylor, ed. Monetary policy rules. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Taylor, John B. 2007JH. Housing and monetary policy. Jackson Hole, WY, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Symposium http://www.kansascityfed.org/PUBLICAT/SYMPOS/2007/PDF/Taylor_0415.pdf
Taylor, John B. 2008Nov. The financial crisis and the policy responses: an empirical analysis of what went wrong. Bank of Canada, Nov 2008 http://www.stanford.edu/~johntayl/Onlinepaperscombinedbyyear/2008/The_Financial_Crisis_and_the_Policy_Responses_An_Empirical_Analysis_of_What_Went_Wrong.pdf
Taylor, John B. 2009. Getting off track: how government actions and interventions caused, prolonged, and worsened the financial crisis. Stanford, CA, Hoover Institution Press.
Taylor, John B. 2012FP. First principles: five keys to restoring America’s prosperity. New York: W. W. Norton.
Taylor, John B. 2012Mar27. Testimony before the Joint Economic Committee at the Hearing on “Monetary Policy Going Forward: Why a Sound Dollar Boosts Growth and Employment.” Washington, DC, JEC, Mar 27 http://jec.senate.gov/republicans/public/?a=Files.Serve&File_id=f002b5f0-9fc0-45f9-9d53-e563137c040e
Taylor, John B. 2012Mar28. The dangers of an interventionist Fed. Wall Street Journal, Mar 28 http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052702303816504577307403971824094.html?mod=WSJ_hps_sections_opinion
Taylor, John B. 2012JMCB. Monetary policy rules work and discretion doesn’t: a tale of two eras. Palo Alto, CA, Stanford University, Mar 2012, forthcoming in the Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 2012 http://www.stanford.edu/~johntayl/JMCB%20lecture.pdf
Taylor, John B. 2012Oct25. An unusually weak recovery as usually defined. Economics One, A Blog by John B. Taylor, Oct 25 http://www.johnbtaylorsblog.blogspot.co.uk/2012/10/an-unusually-weak-recovery-as-usually.html
Taylor, John B. 2013Oct28. Economic failure causes political polarization. Wall Street Journal, Oct 28.
Taylor, John B. 2014Jan01. The economic Hokum of “Secular Stagnation.” Wall Street Journal, Jan 1 http://online.wsj.com/news/articles/SB10001424052702304858104579263953449606842?KEYWORDS=john+b+taylor
Taylor, John B. 2014Jan3. The role of policy in the Great Recession and the weak recovery. Palo Alto, Stanford University, prepared for Allied Social Science Associations, Recessions and Recoveries, American Economic Association, Philadelphia, Jan 3 http://www.aeaweb.org/aea/2014conference/program/preliminary.php?search_string=taylor&search_type=last_name&association=&jel_class=&search=Search#search_box
Taylor, Jonn B. 2014Jun26. The Fed needs to return to monetary rules, Wall Street Journal, Jun 26 http://online.wsj.com/articles/john-taylor-the-fed-needs-to-return-to-monetary-rules-1403823464?KEYWORDS=john+b+taylor
Taylor, John B. 2014Jul15. How to spark another ‘Great Moderation,” Wall Street Journal, Jul 15 http://online.wsj.com/articles/john-taylor-how-to-spark-another-great-moderation-1405469227?KEYWORDS=john+b+taylor
Taylor, John B. 2015. Getting back to a rules-based monetary strategy. 2015. New York, Princeton Club, Presented to the Shadow Open Market Committee Conference, Mar 20.
Taylor, John B. 2016Dec7. Unconventional monetary policy, normalization, and reform. Washington D.C., Testimony before the Subcommittee on Monetary Policy and Trade Committee on Financial Services, US House of Representatives, Dec 7.
Taylor, John B. 2016Dec20. The case for a rules-based Fed. Wall Street Journal, Dec 20 http://www.wsj.com/articles/the-case-for-a-rules-based-fed-1482276881
Taylor, John B. 2018Nov19. Government as a cause of the 2008 financial crisis: a reassessment after 10 years. Hoover Institution, Stanford University, Oct 19, 2018 https://www.hoover.org/sites/default/files/research/docs/govt_as_cause_of_crisis-a_reassement_10.pdf
Taylor, John B. and John C. Williams. 2010. Simple and robust rules for monetary policy. In Benjamin Friedman and Michael Woodford, eds. Handbook of monetary economics Volume 3B. Amsterdam: Elsevier North Holland.
Temin, Peter. 1997. Two views of the British industrial revolution. Journal of Economic History 57 (1, Mar): 63-82.
Tobias, Adrian and Adam B. Aschraft. 2012Apr. Shawdow banking regulation. New York, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Staff Report No. 559, Apr http://www.newyorkfed.org/research/staff_reports/sr559.pdf
Tobin, James. 1958. Liquidity preference as behavior toward risk. Review of Economic Studies 26 (Feb): 65-86.
Tobin, James. 1961. Money, capital, and other stores of value. American Economic Review 51 (2, May): 26-37.
Tobin, James. 1969. A general equilibrium approach to monetary theory. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 1 (1, Feb): 15-29.
Tobin, James. 1974. Monetary policy in 1974 and beyond. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1 (1974): 219-32.
Treynor, Jack L. 1962. Toward a theory of market value of risky assets, unpublished manuscript, 1962, provided by Craig W. French, http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=628187
Vayanos, Dimitri and Jean-Luc Vila. 2009. A preferred-habitat model of the term structure of interest rates. New Orleans, AFA Meetings Paper, Nov 1. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=971439
Vilela Luz, Nícia. 1961. A luta pela industrialização do Brasil (1808 a 1930). São Paulo: Difusão Europeia do Livro.
Vilela Luz, Nicia and Carlos Manuel Peláez. 1972. Economia e história: o encontro dos dois campos de conhecimento. Revista Brasileira de Economia 26 (3, Jul/Sep): 273-301.
Villela, Annibal V. and Wilson Suzigan. 1973. Política do governo e crescimento da economia brasileira. Rio de Janeiro: IPEA/INPES.
Viner, Jacob. 1937. Studies in the theory of international trade. New York: Harper and Brothers, 1965. Available at http://oll.libertyfund.org/?option=com_staticxt&staticfile=show.php%3Ftitle=1414
Wallis, W. Allen and Geoffrey H. Moore. 1941. A significance test for time series and other ordered observations. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1941.
Williams, David, C.A. E. Goodhart and D. H. Gowland. 1976. Money, income and causality: the UK experience. American Economic Review 66 (3, Jun): 417-23.
Winston, Clifford. 2006. Government failure versus market failure. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute/Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies, Brookings Institution Press.
Wolf, Martin. 2012Oct23. A slow convalescence under Obama. Financial Times, Oct 23, 2012 http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/791fc13a-1c57-11e2-a63b-00144feabdc0.html#axzz2AotsUk1q
Wriston, Walter B. 1982. Banking against disaster. New York Times, Sep 14.
Yellen, Janet L. 2011AS. The Federal’s Reserve’s asset purchase program. Denver, Colorado, Allied Social Science Association Annual Meeting, Jan 8 http://federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20110108a.pdf
Yellen, Janet L. 2013Nov14. Testimony. Washington, DC. Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs, US Senate, Nov 14 http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/yellen20131114a.htm
Yellen, Janet L. 2014Jul15. Semiannual Monetary Policy Report to Congress. Washington DC, US Senate, Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs, Jul 15 2014 http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/yellen20140715a.htm
Yellen, Janet L. 20014Aug22. Labor market dynamics and monetary policy. Jackson Hole, WY, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Symposium, Aug 22 http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20140822a.htm
Zingales, Luigi. 2000. In search of new foundations. Journal of Finance 55 (4, Aug): 1623-54.
© Carlos M. Pelaez, 2009, 2010, 2011, 2012, 2013, 2014, 2015, 2016, 2017, 2018, 2019, 2020.
No comments:
Post a Comment