Monday, October 17, 2011

The Odds of Slowdown or Recession, United States Hiring Collapse and Financial Turbulence

 

 

The Odds of Slowdown or Recession, United States Hiring Collapse and Financial Turbulence

Carlos M. Pelaez

© Carlos M. Pelaez, 2010, 2011

Executive Summary

I United States Hiring Collapse

II World Financial Turbulence

III Global Inflation

IV World Economic Slowdown

IVA United States

IVB Japan

IVC China

IVD Euro Area

IVE Germany

IVF France

IVG Italy

IVH United Kingdom

V Valuation of Risk Financial Assets

VI Economic Indicators

VII Interest Rates

VII Conclusion

References

Appendix I The Great Inflation

Executive Summary

Short-term indicators of economies accounting for some three-quarters of world output are followed in this blog. The purchasing managers’ indexes are more current and integrated providing the best available world view. There are five conclusions based on the overall information.

1. Recession. The R (recession) word is similarly forbidden as the L (lose) word in positions in trading desks. There appears to be improvement in output data globally in Jul and Aug. There is growing consensus that the world economy may not fall in recession but with higher doubts on Europe that manages a sovereign risk crisis with tough political restrictions. Naturally, slower growth bring economies closer to contraction

2. Inflation. There is evidence of moderation of inflation in recent monthly data. Concern with 12 months is because of wage increases. In a return of risk appetite with zero interest rates, commodity prices would soar again, raising world inflation. There is a good characterization that central banks attempt to inflate the economy in a negatively-sloping short-term Phillips curve that may prove yet another academic myth already disproved by the increase in interest rates by the Fed in 1981

3. Labor Markets. Advanced economies continue to be plagued by fractured labor markets without improving perspectives

4. Output Growth. The world economy and especially advanced economies are struggling with low rates of growth. Advanced economies have accumulated substantial imbalances that may restrict future growth but at some point expectations of inevitable consolidation by taxation and increases in interest rates to end unparalleled accommodation may reduce growth rates

5. Financial Turbulence. There will continue to be sharp fluctuations in valuations of risk financial assets. In recent weeks, volumes have thinned in various financial markets with the possibility of sharper fluctuations by professionals accustomed to reversing exposures to realize profits. This is an essential function of price discovery. European sovereign risks and increasingly the legislative agenda in the US will continue causing turbulence in financial markets

Hiring in the nonfarm sector (HNF) has declined from 64.9 million in 2006 to 47.2 million in 2010 or by 17.7 million while hiring in the private sector (HP) has declined from 60.4 million in 2006 to 43.3 million in 2010 or by 17.1 million. An important characteristic of the current fractured labor market of the US is the closing of the avenue for exiting unemployment and underemployment normally available through dynamic hiring. Another avenue that is closed is the opportunity for advancement in moving to new jobs that pay better salaries and benefits again because of the collapse of hiring in the United States. Those who are unemployed or underemployed cannot find a new job even accepting lower wages and no benefits. The employed cannot escape declining inflation-adjusted earnings because there is no hiring. Several charts anticipated here from the text illustrate the socio-economic disaster of about 30 million in the United States who are unemployed, underemployed in part-time jobs or at the point of giving up in finding a job.

Chart 6 anticipated here from the text provides total nonfarm hiring on a monthly basis from 2001 to 2011. Hiring rebounded in early 2010 but then fell and stabilized at a lower level than the early peak in 2010. 

clip_image001

Chart 6, US, Total Nonfarm Hiring (HNF), 2001-2011 Month SA

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm

There is only milder improvement in total private hiring shown in Chart 8 also anticipated here from the text. HP rose in 2011 but appears to have become stationary again in recent months.

clip_image002

Chart 8, US, Total Private Hiring Month SA 2011-2011

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm

Chart 10 also anticipated from the text shows monthly job openings rising from the trough in 2009 to a high in the beginning of 2010. Job openings then stabilized into 2011. 

clip_image003

Chart 10, US Job Openings, Thousands NSA

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm

Chart 16 also anticipated from the text provides U6 on a monthly basis from 2001 to 2011. There was a steep climb from 2007 into 2009 and then this measure of unemployment and underemployment stabilized at that high level.

clip_image004

Chart 16, US, U6, total unemployed, plus all marginally attached workers, plus total employed part time for economic reasons % LF plus all marginally attached workers as % of Labor Force, Month, SA,

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/cps/data.htm

One of the dramas of the current job market of the US consists of millions of people working part-time for economic reasons, or the failure to find full-time employment. Chart 17 also anticipated from the text shows the jump of numbers of people working part-time for economic reasons from 2007 and subsequent stabilization at a very high level.

clip_image005

Chart 17, US, Working Part-time for Economic Reasons

Thousands, Month SA 2001-2011

Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/cps/data.htm

The New York State Comptroller Thomas P. DiNapoli explains vividly the worrisome state of the securities industry (http://www.osc.state.ny.us/press/releases/oct11/101111.htm):

“The securities industry had a strong start to 2011, but its prospects have cooled considerably for the second half of this year,’ DiNapoli said. ‘It now seems likely that profits will fall sharply, job losses will continue, and bonuses will be smaller than last year. These developments will have a rippling effect through the economy and adversely impact State and City tax collections. As we know, when Wall Street slows, New York City and New York State’s budgets feel the impact and that is a concern.”

The report of the New York State Comptroller elaborates the impact of the loss of employment to New York City and New York State (http://www.osc.state.ny.us/press/releases/oct11/101111.htm):

“The economies and budgets of New York City and New York State are very dependent on the securities industry. According to the Office of the State Comptroller, last year securities-related activities accounted for 14 percent of New York State’s tax revenues and almost 7 percent of New York City’s. In addition, one in 8 jobs in New York City and 1 in 13 jobs in New York State are linked to the securities industry. Given the current weakness, tax collections are likely to fall short of City and State targets in their current fiscal years and may decline by more the following year.

DiNapoli’s analysis also found that:

  • The member firms of the New York Stock Exchange earned $9.3 billion in the first quarter of 2011 (almost half of the City’s $20 billion target for the entire year), but profits declined sharply in the second quarter. The Office of the State Comptroller forecasts that profits are unlikely to reach $18 billion for all of 2011, which is one-third less than in 2010.
  • After adding 9,900 jobs between January 2010 and April 2011, the securities industry has lost 4,100 jobs through August 2011. Job losses are likely to continue given declines in profitability and recent layoff announcements. OSC estimates that the securities industry could lose nearly 10,000 additional jobs by the end of 2012, which would bring total industry job losses to 32,000 since January 2008.
  • Cash bonuses are likely to be smaller in 2011, the second year in a row in which they have declined.
  • The average salary in the securities industry in 2010 grew by 16.1 percent to $361,330, 5.5 times higher than the average salary in the private sector of $66,120. The disparity between average salaries in the securities industry and the rest of the private sector narrowed in 2008 and 2009, but widened in 2010.
  • In 2010, the securities industry accounted for 23.5 percent of all wages paid in the private sector despite accounting for only 5.3 percent of all private sector jobs.
  • The State Comptroller’s Office estimates that each job gained (or lost) in the securities industry leads to the creation (or loss) of almost two additional jobs in other industries in the New York City and another job elsewhere in New York State.“

This may be the beginning of the loss of jobs and business to the US because of the erosion of the country’s competitiveness. Erosion of the competitiveness of the US in capital markets had even begun earlier (see Pelaez and Pelaez, Globalization and the State, Vol. II (2009b), 168-179).

I United States Hiring Collapse. An important characteristic of the current fractured labor market of the US is the closing of the avenue for exiting unemployment and underemployment normally available through dynamic hiring. Another avenue that is closed is the opportunity for advancement in moving to new jobs that pay better salaries and benefits again because of the collapse of hiring in the United States. Those who are unemployed or underemployed cannot find a new job even accepting lower wages and no benefits. The employed cannot escape declining inflation-adjusted earnings because there is no hiring. The objective of this section is to analyze hiring and labor underutilization in the United States.

An appropriate measure of job stress is considered by Blanchard and Katz (1997, 53):

“The right measure of the state of the labor market is the exit rate from unemployment, defined as the number of hires divided by the number unemployed, rather than the unemployment rate itself. What matters to the unemployed is not how many of them there are, but how many of them there are in relation to the number of hires by firms.”

The natural rate of unemployment and the similar NAIRU are quite difficult to estimate in practice (Ibid; see Ball and Mankiw 2002).

The Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) created the Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey (JOLTS) with the purpose that (http://www.bls.gov/jlt/jltover.htm#purpose):

“These data serve as demand-side indicators of labor shortages at the national level. Prior to JOLTS, there was no economic indicator of the unmet demand for labor with which to assess the presence or extent of labor shortages in the United States. The availability of unfilled jobs—the jobs opening rate—is an important measure of tightness of job markets, parallel to existing measures of unemployment.”

The BLS collects data from about 16,000 US business establishments in nonagricultural industries through the 50 states and DC. The data are released monthly and constitute an important complement to other data provided by the BLS.

Hiring in the nonfarm sector (HNF) has declined from 64.9 million in 2006 to 47.2 million in 2010 or by 17.7 million while hiring in the private sector (HP) has declined from 60.4 million in 2006 to 43.3 million in 2010 or by 17.1 million, as shown in Table 1. The ratio of nonfarm hiring to unemployment (RNF) has fallen from 47.7 in 2006 to 36.4 in 2010 and in the private sector (RHP) from 52.9 in 2006 to 40.3 in 2010 (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/03/slow-growth-inflation-unemployment-and.html).

Table 1, US, Annual Total Nonfarm Hiring (HNF) and Total Private Hiring (HP) in the US and Percentage of Total Employment

 

HNF

Rate RNF

HP

Rate HP

2001

63,766

48.4

59,374

53.6

2002

59,797

45.9

55,665

51.1

2003

57,787

44.5

54,082

49.9

2004

61,624

46.9

57,534

52.4

2005

64,498

48.2

60,444

54.0

2006

64,870

47.7

60,419

52.9

2007

63,326

46.0

58,760

50.9

2008

53,986

39.5

50,286

44.0

2009

45,372

34.7

41,966

38.8

2010

47,234

36.4

43,299

40.3

Source: http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm

Chart 1 provides the yearly levels of total nonfarm hiring (NFH) in Table 1. The fall of hiring during the contraction of 2007 to 2009 was much stronger than in the shallow contraction of 2001 with GDP contraction of only 0.4 percent from Mar 2001 (IQ2001) to Dec 2011 (IVQ 2001) compared with 5.1 percent contraction in the much longer recession of Dec 2007 (IVQ2007) to Jun 2009 (IIQ2009) (http://www.nber.org/cycles.html).

clip_image007

Chart 1,  US, Total Nonfarm Hiring (HNF), Yearly, 2001-2010

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm

Chart 2 shows the ratio or rate of nonfarm hiring to unemployment (RNF) that also fell much more in the recession of 2007 to 2009 than in the shallow recession of 2001. 

clip_image009

Chart 2,  US, Rate Total Nonfarm Hiring (HNF), Yearly, 2001-2010

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm

Total nonfarm hiring (HNF) yearly percentage changes are provided in Table 2. There were much milder declines in 2002 of 6.2 percent and 3.4 percent in 2003 followed by strong rebounds of 6.6 percent in 2004 and 4.7 percent in 2005. In contrast, the contractions of nonfarm hiring in the recession after 2007 were much sharper in percentage points: 2.4 in 2007, 14.7 in 2008 and 16 percent in 2009. On a yearly basis, nonfarm hiring grew 4.1 percent in 2010 relative to 2009.

Table 2, US, Annual Total Nonfarm Hiring (HNF), Yearly Percentage Change, 2001-2010

Year

Annual

2002

-6.2

2003

-3.4

2004

6.6

2005

4.7

2006

0.6

2007

-2.4

2008

-14.7

2009

-16.0

2010

4.1

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm

Chart 3 plots yearly percentage changes of nonfarm hiring. Percentage declines after 2007 were quite sharp.

clip_image011

Chart 3, US, Annual Total Nonfarm Hiring (HNF), Yearly Percentage Change, 2001-2010

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm

Total private hiring (HP) yearly data are provided in Chart 4. There has been sharp contraction of total private hiring in the US and only mild recovery in 2010.       

clip_image013

Chart 4, US, Total Private Hiring, Yearly, 2001-2011

Source:

US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm

Chart 5 plots the rate of total private hiring relative to unemployment (RHP). The rate collapsed during the global recession after 2007.

clip_image015

Chart 5, US, Rate Total Private Hiring, Yearly, 2001-2011

Source:

US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm

Total nonfarm hiring (HNF), total private hiring (HP) and their respective rates are provided for the month of Aug in the years from 2001 to 2011 in Table 3. There is some recovery in HNF from 4121 in Aug 2009 to 4317 in Aug 2010 and 4462 in Aug 2011 for cumulative gain of 8.3 percent. HP rose from 3675 in Aug 2009 to 4026 in Aug 2011 for cumulative gain of 9.6 percent. HNF has fallen from 6014 in Aug 2005 to 4462 in Aug 2011 or by 25.8 percent. HP has fallen from 5487 in Aug 2005 to 4026 in Aug 2011 or by 26.2 percent. The labor market continues to be fractured, failing to provide an opportunity to exit from unemployment/underemployment or to find an opportunity for advancement away from declining inflation-adjusted earnings.

Table 3, US, Total Nonfarm Hiring (HNF) and Total Private Hiring (HP) in the US in Thousands and in Percentage of Total Employment Not Seasonally Adjusted

 

HNF

Rate RNF

HP

Rate HP

2001 Aug

5503

4.2

4927

4.4

2002 Aug

5306

4.1

4757

4.3

2003 Aug

5062

3.9

4690

4.3

2004 Aug

5606

4.3

5110

4.6

2005 Aug

6014

4.5

5487

4.8

2006 Aug

5874

4.3

5249

4.6

2007 Aug

5746

4.2

5068

4.4

2008 Aug

4982

3.6

4445

3.9

2009 Aug

4121

3.2

3675

3.4

2010 Aug

4317

3.3

3890

3.6

2011 Aug

4462

3.4

4026

3.7

Source:  US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm

Chart 6 provides total nonfarm hiring on a monthly basis from 2001 to 2011. Hiring rebounded in early 2010 but then fell and stabilized at a lower level than the early peak in 2010. 

clip_image017

Chart 6, US, Total Nonfarm Hiring (HNF), 2001-2011 Month SA

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm

Similar behavior occurs in the rate of nonfarm hiring plot in Chart 7. Recovery in early 2010 was followed by decline and stabilization at the lower level.

clip_image019

Chart 7, US, Rate Total Nonfarm Hiring, Monthly 2001-2011 Month SA

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm

There is only milder improvement in total private hiring shown in Chart 8. HP rose in 2011 but appears to have become stationary again in recent months.

clip_image021

Chart 8, US, Total Private Hiring Month SA 2011-2011

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm

Chart 9 shows similar behavior in the rate of private hiring. The rate appears to have stabilized at a low level.

clip_image023

Chart 9, US, Rate Total Private Hiring Month SA 2011-2011

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm

The JOLTS report of the Bureau of Labor Statistics also provide total nonfarm job openings (TNF JOB), TNF JOB rate and TNF LO (layoffs and discharges) shown in Table 4 for the month of Aug from 2001 to 2011. The final column provides TNF LO for the years from 2001 to 2011. Nonfarm job openings fell from a peak of 4701 in Aug 2007 to 3158 in Aug 2011 or by 32.8 percent while the rate dropped from 3.3 to 2.2. Nonfarm layoffs and discharges (TNF LO) rose from 1748 in Aug 2006 to 2238 in Aug 2008 or by 28 percent. The yearly data show layoffs and discharges rising from 21.5 million in 2006 to 26.3 million in 2009 or by 22.3 percent. 

Table 4, US, Job Openings and Total Separations, Thousands NSA

 

TNF JOB

TNF JOB
Rate

TNF LO

TNF LO
Year

Aug 2001

4331

3.2

1857

24351

Aug 2002

3518

2.6

1870

23325

Aug 2003

3229

2.4

2072

23959

Aug 2004

3761

2.8

2080

23389

Aug 2005

4152

3.0

1976

22774

Aug 2006

4634

3.3

1748

21468

Aug 2007

4701

3.3

1951

22577

Aug 2008

3651

2.6

2238

23737

Aug 2009

2287

1.7

2208

26318

Aug 2010

2954

2.2

1947

21243

Aug 2011

3158

2.4

1744

 

Notes: TNF JOB: Total Nonfarm Job Openings; LO: Layoffs and Discharges

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm

Chart 10 shows monthly job openings rising from the trough in 2009 to a high in the beginning of 2010. Job openings then stabilized into 2011. 

clip_image025

Chart 10, US Job Openings, Thousands NSA

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm

The rate of job openings in Chart 11 shows similar behavior. The rate rises from 2009 into the initial part of 2010 and then stabilizes into 2011.

clip_image027

Chart 11, US, Rate of Job Openings, Thousands NSA

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm

Chart 12 shows total separations in the JOLTS report on a monthly basis. Total separations collapsed during the global recession and then stabilized.

clip_image029

Chart 12, US, Total Separations, Month SA 2001-2011

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm

Yearly total separations are shown in Chart 13. Separations are some 20 million lower in 2010 than before the global recession.

clip_image031

Chart 13, US, Total Separations, Yearly 2001-2010

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm

Monthly data of layoffs and discharges reach a peak in early 2009, as shown in Chart 14. Layoffs and discharges dropped sharply with the recovery of the economy in 2010 and 2011.

clip_image033

Chart 14, US, Layoffs and Discharges, Monthly 2011-2011

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm

Layoffs and discharges in Chart 15 rose sharply to a peak in 2009. There was pronounced drop into 2010.

clip_image035

Chart 15, US, Layoffs and Discharges, Yearly 2011-2011

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm

The Bureau of Labor Statistics also provides alternative measures of labor underutilization shown in Table 5. The most comprehensive measure is U6 that consists of total unemployed plus total employed part time for economic reasons plus all marginally attached workers as percent of the labor force. U6 not seasonally annualized has risen from 5.6 percent in 2006 to 15.7 in Sep 2011. 

Table 5, US, Alternative Measures of Labor Underutilization %

 

U1

U2

U3

U4

U5

U6

Sep 2011
NSA

5.2

5.0

8.8

9.4

10.2

15.7

Sep 2010 NSA

5.3

5.6

9.2

9.9

10.7

16.2

Aug 2011 NSA

5.2

5.1

9.1

9.6

10.6

16.7

Aug 2010
NSA

5.3

5.7

9.5

10.2

10.9

16.4

Jul 2011 NSA

5.2

5.2

9.3

10.0

10.9

16.3

Jul 2010 NSA

5.5

5.8

9.7

10.4

11.2

16.8

2010

5.7

6.0

9.6

10.3

11.1

16.7

2009

4.7

5.9

9.3

9.7

10.5

16.2

2008

2.1

3.1

5.8

6.1

6.8

10.5

2007

1.5

2.3

4.6

4.9

5.5

8.3

2006

1.5

2.2

4.6

4.9

5.5

5.6

Note: LF: labor force; U1, persons unemployed 15 weeks % LF; U2, job losers and persons who completed temporary jobs %LF; U3, total unemployed % LF; U4, total unemployed plus discouraged workers, plus all other marginally attached workers; % LF plus discouraged workers; U5, total unemployed, plus discouraged workers, plus all other marginally attached workers % LF plus all marginally attached workers; U6, total unemployed, plus all marginally attached workers, plus total employed part time for economic reasons % LF plus all marginally attached workers

Source: http://www.bls.gov/news.release/pdf/empsit.pdf

Monthly seasonally adjusted measures of labor underutilization are provided in Table 6. U6 has been climbing from 15.9 percent in Apr 2011 to 16.5 percent in Sep 2011. Unemployment is an inaccurate measure of the stress in US job markets. A different calculation in this blog is provided by using the participation rate in the labor force before the global recession. This calculation shows 29.4 million in job stress of unemployment/underemployment in Sep 2011, not seasonally adjusted, corresponding to 18.5 percent of the labor force (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/10/twenty-nine-million-unemployedunderempl.html). 

Table 6, US, Alternative Measures of Labor Underutilization SA %

 

Sep 2011

Aug  2011

Jul 2011

Jun 2011

May 2011

Apr 2011

U1

5.4

5.4

5.3

5.3

5.3

5.1

U2

5.3

5.3

5.4

5.4

5.4

5.3

U3

9.1

9.1

9.1

9.2

9.1

9.0

U4

9.7

9.7

9.8

9.8

9.5

9.5

U5

10.5

10.6

10.7

10.7

10.3

10.4

U6

16.5

16.2

16.1

16.2

15.8

15.9

Note: LF: labor force; U1, persons unemployed 15 weeks % LF; U2, job losers and persons who completed temporary jobs %LF; U3, total unemployed % LF; U4, total unemployed plus discouraged workers, plus all other marginally attached workers; % LF plus discouraged workers; U5, total unemployed, plus discouraged workers, plus all other marginally attached workers % LF plus all marginally attached workers; U6, total unemployed, plus all marginally attached workers, plus total employed part time for economic reasons % LF plus all marginally attached workers

Source: http://www.bls.gov/news.release/pdf/empsit.pdf

Chart 16 provides U6 on a monthly basis from 2001 to 2011. There was a steep climb from 2007 into 2009 and then this measure of unemployment and underemployment stabilized at that high level.

clip_image037

Chart 16, US, U6, total unemployed, plus all marginally attached workers, plus total employed part time for economic reasons % LF plus all marginally attached workers as % of Labor Force, Month, SA,

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/cps/data.htm

One of the dramas of the current job market of the US consists of millions of people working part-time for economic reasons, or the failure to find full-time employment. Chart 17 shows the jump of numbers of people working part-time for economic reasons from 2007 and subsequent stabilization at a very high level.

clip_image039

Chart 17, US, Working Part-time for Economic Reasons

Thousands, Month SA 2001-2011

Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/cps/data.htm

People lose their marketable job skills after prolonged unemployment and find increasing difficulty in finding another job. Chart 18 shows the sharp rise in unemployed over 27 weeks and stabilization at an extremely high level.

clip_image041

Chart 18, US, Number Unemployed for 27 Weeks or Over, Thousands SA Month 2001-2011

Sources: http://www.bls.gov/cps/data.htm

Another segment of U6 consists of people marginally attached to the labor force who continue to seek employment but less frequently. Chart 19 shows the sharp rise in people marginally attached to the labor force after 2007 and subsequent stabilization.

clip_image043

Chart 19, US, Marginally Attached to the Labor Force, SA Month 2001-2011

Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/cps/data.htm

II World Financial Turbulence. The past three months have been characterized by financial turbulence, attaining unusual magnitude in the past month. Table 7, updated with every comment in this blog, provides beginning values on Oct 10 and daily values throughout the week ending on Fr Oct 14 of several financial assets. Section V Valuation of Risk Financial Assets provides a set of more complete values. All data are for New York time at 5 PM. The first column provides the value on Fri Oct 7 and the percentage change in that prior week below the label of the financial risk asset. The first five asset rows provide five key exchange rates versus the dollar and the percentage cumulative appreciation (positive change or no sign) or depreciation (negative change or negative sign). Positive changes constitute appreciation of the relevant exchange rate and negative changes depreciation. Financial turbulence has been dominated by reactions to the new program for Greece (see section IB in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/07/debt-and-financial-risk-aversion-and.html), doubts on the larger countries in the euro zone with sovereign risks such as Spain and Italy, the growth standstill recession and long-term unsustainable government debt in the US, worldwide deceleration of economic growth and continuing inflation. The dollar/euro rate is quoted as number of US dollars USD per one euro EUR, USD 1.338/EUR in the first row, first column in the block for currencies in Table 7 for Fri Oct 7, depreciating to USD 1.3652/EUR on Mon Oct 10, or by 2.0 percent. Table 7 defines a country’s exchange rate as number of units of domestic currency per unit of foreign currency. USD/EUR would be the definition of the exchange rate of the US and the inverse [1/(USD/EUR)] is the definition in this convention of the rate of exchange of the euro zone, EUR/USD. A convention is required to maintain consistency in characterizing movements of the exchange rate in Table 7 as appreciation and depreciation. The first row for each of the currencies shows the exchange rate at 5 PM New York time, such as USD 1.3652/EUR on Oct 10; the second row provides the cumulative percentage appreciation or depreciation of the exchange rate from the rate on the last business day of the prior week, in this case Fri Oct 7, to the last business day of the current week, in this case Fri Oct 14, such as depreciation of 3.7 percent for the dollar to USD 1.387/EUR by Oct 14; and the third row provides the percentage change from the prior business day to the current business day. For example, the USD depreciated (negative sign) by 3.7 percent from the rate of USD 1.338/EUR on Fri Oct 7 to the rate of USD 1.387/EUR on Fri Oct 14 {[(1.387/1.338) – 1]100 = 3.7%} and depreciated by 0.6 percent from the rate of USD 1.3786 on Thu Oct 13 to USD 1.387/EUR on Fri Oct 14 {[(1.387/1.3786) -1]100 = 0.6%}. The dollar depreciated during the week because more dollars, $1.387, were required to buy one euro on Fri Oct 14 than $1.338 required to buy one euro on Fri Oct 7. The depreciation of the dollar in the week was caused by diminishing risk aversion with purchases of risk financial investments by reduction of dollar-denominated assets.

Table 7, Weekly Financial Risk Assets Oct 10 to Oct 14, 2011

Oct 7, 2011

M 10

Tu 11

W 12

Th 13

Fr 14

USD/
EUR

1.338

0.1%

1.3652

-2.0%

-2.0%

1.3648

-2.0%

0.0%

1.3784

-3.0%

-0.9%

1.3786

3.0%

0.0%

1.387

-3.7%

-0.6%

JPY/
USD

76.709

0.4%

76.6702

0.0%

0.0%

76.6687

0.0%

0.0%

77.273

-0.8%

-0.8%

76.8705

-0.2%

0.5%

77.21

-0.7%

-0.4%

CHF/
USD

0.915

-0.8%

0.9032

1.3%

1.3%

0.9076

0.8%

-0.5%

0.8953

2.2%

1.4%

0.8975

-1.9%

-0.2%

0.894

2.3%

0.4%

CHF/EUR
1.2420

-2.3%

1.2330

0.7%

0.7%

1.2387

0.3%

-0.5%

1.2341

0.6%

0.4%

1.2374

0.4%

-0.3%

1.2388

0.3%

-0.1%

USD/
AUD

0.977

1.0235

0.9996

1.0004

-2.4%

-2.4%

0.9972

1.0028

-2.6%

-0.2%

1.0153

0.9849

-0.8%

1.8%

1.0198

0.9806

-0.4%

0.4%

1.0338

0.9673

1.0%

1.4%

10 Year
T Note

2.078

2.061

2.153

2.208

2.178

2.251

2 Year T Note
0.292

0.284

0.304

0.281

0.281

0.269

German Bond

2Y 0.60 10Y 2.00

2Y 0.65 10Y 2.08

2Y0.65 10Y 2.09

2Y 0.70 10Y 2.19

2Y 0.62

10Y 2.11

2Y 0.66 10Y 2.20

DJIA

11103.12

1.7%

11433.18

2.9%

2.9%

11416.3

2.8%

-0.2%

11518.85

3.7%

0.9%

11478.13

3.4%

-0.4%

11644.49

4.9%

1.5%

DJ Global

1756.93

1.8%

1803.73

2.7%

2.7%

1809.96

3.0%

0.4%

1838.39

4.7%

1.6%

1825.99

3.9%

-0.7%

1845.80

5.1%

1.1%

DJ Asia Pacific

1160.75

-0.4%

1168.89

0.7%

0.7%

1188.59

2.4%

1.7%

1193.95

2.9%

0.5%

1208.58

4.1%

1.2%

1199.34

3.3%

-0.8%

Nikkei
8605.62

-1.1%

8605.62

0.0%

0.0%

8773.68

1.9%

1.9%

8738.90

1.5%

-0.4%

8823.25

2.5%

0.9%

8747.96

1.7%

-0.9%

Shanghai

2359.22

-3.0%

2344.79

-0.6%

-0.6%

2348.52

-0.5%

0.2%

2420.00

2.6%

3.0%

2438.79

3.4%

0.8%

2431.37

3.1%

-0.3%

DAX
5675.70

3.2%

5847.29

3.0%

3.0%

5865.01

3.3%

0.3%

5994.47

5.6%

2.2%

5914.84

4.2%

-1.3%

5967.20

5.1%

0.9%

BOVESPA
51243.62

-2.1

53273.11

3.9%

53838.47

1.1%

53838.47

1.1%

54601.07

6.6%

1.4%

55030.45

7.4%

0.8%

DJ UBS Comm.

141.8

1.1%

144.32

1.8%

1.8%

145.90

2.9%

1.1%

146.07

3.0%

0.1%

145.57

2.7%

-0.3%

148.21

4.5%

1.8%

WTI $ B
82.98

5.5%

85.75

3.3%

3.3%

85.31

2.8%

-0.5%

84.75

2.1%

-0.7%

84.44

1.8%

-0.4%

87.31

5.2%

3.4%

Brent $/B

106.02

3.6%

109.29

3.1%

3.1%

110.50

4.2%

1.1%

110.77

4.5%

0.2%

111.29

4.9%

0.5%

112.75

6.3%

1.3%

Gold $/OZ

1640.6

1.1%

1677.3

2.2%

2.2%

1667.4

1.6%

-0.6%

1678.3

2.3%

0.6%

1668.7

1.7%

-0.6%

1682.6

2.6%

0.8%

Note: USD: US dollar; JPY: Japanese Yen; CHF: Swiss

Franc; AUD: Australian dollar; Comm.: commodities; OZ: ounce

Sources:

http://www.bloomberg.com/markets/

http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/page/marketsdata.html?mod=WSJ_hps_marketdata

There was again turbulence in financial assets but of different direction in flight from safe havens and return to risk financial assets during the week of Oct 10. Risk appetite is present in the depreciation of the USD by 3.7 percent. Continuing strength of the Japanese yen suggests remaining risk aversion because of nil depreciation of the yen by 0.7 percent in the week. Exchange rate controls by the Swiss National Bank (SNB) fixing the rate at a minimum of CHF 1.20/EUR (http://www.snb.ch/en/mmr/reference/pre_20110906/source/pre_20110906.en.pdf) has prevented flight of capital into the Swiss franc. The Swiss franc appreciated 2.3 percent relative to the USD and 0.3 percent relative to the euro also suggesting remaining risk aversion. Another symptom of risk appetite is the appreciation of the Australian dollar by 1.0 percent in new carry trades from zero interest rates in the US and Japan into high yielding currencies such as in Australia (see Pelaez and Pelaez, Globalization and the State, Vol. II (2008b), 202-4, Pelaez and Pelaez, Government Intervention in Globalization (2008c), 70-4).

Risk aversion is also captured by decline of the yield of the 10-year Treasury note to 1.912 percent on Sep 30, increasing to 2.078 percent by Fri Oct 7 but still at a level well below consumer price inflation of 3.8 percent in the 12 months ending in Aug (http://www.bls.gov/cpi/). Treasury securities continue to be safe haven for investors fearing risk but with concentration in shorter maturities such as the two-year Treasury with relatively stable yield of 0.269 percent on Oct 14 while the ten-year Treasury yield has risen to 2.251 percent by Oct 14 because of duration risk. Rising yields of longer term securities can cause higher capital losses. Investors are willing to sacrifice yield relative to inflation in defensive actions to avoid turbulence in valuations of risk financial assets but may be managing duration more carefully. During the financial panic of Sep 2008, funds moved away from risk exposures to government securities. A similar risk aversion phenomenon occurs in Europe with low levels of the yield of the 10-year government bond on Fri Oct 7 at 0.60 percent for the two-year maturity and 2.00 percent for the 10-year maturity while the flash euro zone CPI inflation for Sep is at 3.0 percent (http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/cache/ITY_PUBLIC/2-30092011-AP/EN/2-30092011-AP-EN.PDF) and the final report confirming that higher level (http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/cache/ITY_PUBLIC/2-14102011-BP/EN/2-14102011-BP-EN.PDF). Safety overrides inflation-adjusted yield but there could be duration aversion.

There were substantial gains in equity indexes in Europe and the US in Table 7 in the week of Fri Oct 14 because of the commitment by France and Germany of a new plan to be released in a few weeks to solve the sovereign risk financial crisis. The Dow Asia Pacific gained 3.3 percent and the Nikkei Average 1.7 percent in the week. Gains throughout the week were driven by optimism of a solution to the European sovereign risk dilemma by means of recapitalization of banks.

Commodities roughly tracked other risk financial assets. All three indexes commodity prices in Table 7 rose in the week of Oct 14 and the DJ UBS Commodity Index rose 4.5 percent in the week. In the absence of risk aversion, risk financial assets tend to increase in value because of the carry trade from zero interest rates. Exposures are reduced because of risk aversion, causing collapse of valuations of risk financial assets.

There are three factors dominating valuations of risk financial assets that are systematically discussed in this blog.

1. Euro zone survival risk. The fundamental issue of sovereign risks in the euro zone is whether the group of countries with euro as common currency and unified monetary policy through the European Central Bank will (i) continue to exist; (ii) downsize to a limited number of countries with the same currency; or (iii) revert to the prior system of individual national currencies.

2. United States Growth, Employment and Fiscal Soundness. Recent posts of this blog analyze the mediocre rate of growth of the US in contrast with V-shaped recovery in all expansions following recessions since World War II, deterioration of social and economic indicators, unemployment and underemployment of 30 million, decline of yearly hiring by 17 million, falling real wages and unsustainable central government or Treasury debt (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/10/us-growth-standstill-at-08-percent.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/collapse-of-household-income-and-wealth.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/global-growth-standstill-recession.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/08/united-states-gdp-growth-standstill.html).

3. World Economic Slowdown. Careful, detailed analysis of the slowdown of the world economy is provided in Section IV World Economic Slowdown. Data and analysis are provided for regions and countries that jointly account for about three quarters of world output.

The issue of rescuing sovereigns in difficulty is increasingly becoming the issue of survival of the euro. Cochrane (2011Sep28), writing in the Wall Street Journal on Sep 28, argues, contrary to official doctrine and rescue efforts, that survival of the euro requires allowing sovereigns to default and maintaining the European Central Bank (ECB) isolated from the defaults. The practical problem in the bailouts of sovereigns is that the bailout fund has been approved for €440 billion while several trillion euro are required if there are difficulties with the larger sovereigns such as Italy and Spain. A proposal consists of leveraging by using the €440 billion to borrow the trillions of dollars of euro. Davies (2011Sep28) finds two options for the borrowing, both involving “other people’s money.” (1) The rescue fund would receive loans from the ECB; and (2) the rescue fund would receive loans from sovereign wealth funds of emerging markets with large reserves. Cochrane (2011Sep28) argues correctly, as it occurred with credit-risk transfer products, that the risk does not disappear but is just merely transferred. The risk would end up with the lenders such as the ECB and would deteriorate the reserves of emerging markets. Cochrane (2011Sep28) finds resemblance with the purchase of bonds before the financial crisis to increase leverage while writing CDS (credit default swaps). The ECB would find significant deterioration of its already high subprime collateral. Davies (2011Sep28) finds that the ECB would become a gigantic collateralized debt obligation (CDO). The bailout fund would issue notes for the more than one trillion euro required in the bailout that would be insured by the €440 billion, increasing the possibility of raising the loans because of the AAA rating of a few core sovereigns, in particular, Germany. The trillions of euro loans from the ECB or emerging markets could be used to acquire subprime sovereign debt and recapitalize European banks that also own some of that debt. The credit risk would be transferred almost entirely to Germany and its taxpayers who effectively guarantee the loans. Germany would be faced with the same issue as unsustainable reparations from World War II only in that in this case Germany did not provoke a war (see the classic treatment by Keynes (1929, 1929R and Ohlin 1929; see also Samuelson 1952, Johnson 1975, Darity and Frank 2003 and Lane and Milessi-Ferretti 2004).

The G20 meeting of finance ministers and governors of central banks issued in Paris on Oct 15 the following statement (http://www.g20.utoronto.ca/2011/2011-finance-111015-en.html ) but little hope of other people’s money to solve the European sovereign risk crisis:

“We have progressed in delivering the commitments we made three weeks ago in Washington DC. In particular, we welcome the adoption of the ambitious reform of the European economic governance. We also welcome the completion by Euro area countries of the actions necessary to implement the decisions taken by Euro area Leaders on 21 July 2011 to increase the capacity and the flexibility of the EFSF. We look forward to further work to maximize the impact of the EFSF in order to avoid contagion, and to the outcome of the European Council on October 23 to decisively address the current challenges through a comprehensive plan. We made progress on our action plan of coordinated policies for consideration by our Leaders at the Cannes Summit. This action plan will encompass a set of measures to address immediate vulnerabilities and strengthen the foundations for a strong, sustainable and balanced growth whereby:

· Advanced economies, taking into account different national circumstances, will adopt policies to build confidence and support growth, and implement clear, credible and specific measures to achieve fiscal consolidation. Those with large current account surpluses will also implement policies to shift to growth based more on domestic demand. Those with large current account deficits will implement policies to increase national savings;

· Emerging market economies will adjust macroeconomic policies, where needed, to maintain growth momentum in the face of downside risks, contain inflationary pressures and endeavor to enhance resilience in the face of volatile capital flows; Surplus emerging market economies will accelerate the implementation of structural reforms to rebalance demand toward more domestic consumption, supported by continued efforts to move toward more marketdetermined exchange rate systems and achieve greater exchange rate flexibility to reflect economic fundamentals;

· All countries will undertake further structural reforms to raise potential growth;

· In all of our actions we will strive to foster growth, job creation and promote social inclusion.

We remain committed to take all necessary actions to preserve the stability of banking systems and financial markets. We will ensure that banks are adequately capitalized and have sufficient access to funding to deal with current risks. Central banks have recently taken decisive actions to this end and will continue to stand ready to provide liquidity to banks as required. Monetary policies will maintain price stability and continue to support economic recovery.”

The commitment of the Jul 21, 2011 agreement is only €440 billion (see section IB in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/07/debt-and-financial-risk-aversion-and.html). The actual amount required maybe in excess of a trillion or two of euro. One possibility that is being explored is to increase haircuts to debt holders such as banks and investors. Banks are required by regulation to increase their common equity capital while their balance sheets are hit by draconian regulation. The New York State Comptroller Thomas P. DiNapoli explains vividly the consequences of regulation on the securities industry (http://www.osc.state.ny.us/press/releases/oct11/101111.htm):

“’The securities industry had a strong start to 2011, but its prospects have cooled considerably for the second half of this year,’ DiNapoli said. ‘It now seems likely that profits will fall sharply, job losses will continue, and bonuses will be smaller than last year. These developments will have a rippling effect through the economy and adversely impact State and City tax collections. As we know, when Wall Street slows, New York City and New York State’s budgets feel the impact and that is a concern.’   

The economies and budgets of New York City and New York State are very dependent on the securities industry. According to the Office of the State Comptroller, last year securities-related activities accounted for 14 percent of New York State’s tax revenues and almost 7 percent of New York City’s. In addition, one in 8 jobs in New York City and 1 in 13 jobs in New York State are linked to the securities industry. Given the current weakness, tax collections are likely to fall short of City and State targets in their current fiscal years and may decline by more the following year.

DiNapoli’s analysis also found that:

  • The member firms of the New York Stock Exchange earned $9.3 billion in the first quarter of 2011 (almost half of the City’s $20 billion target for the entire year), but profits declined sharply in the second quarter. The Office of the State Comptroller forecasts that profits are unlikely to reach $18 billion for all of 2011, which is one-third less than in 2010.
  • After adding 9,900 jobs between January 2010 and April 2011, the securities industry has lost 4,100 jobs through August 2011. Job losses are likely to continue given declines in profitability and recent layoff announcements. OSC estimates that the securities industry could lose nearly 10,000 additional jobs by the end of 2012, which would bring total industry job losses to 32,000 since January 2008.
  • Cash bonuses are likely to be smaller in 2011, the second year in a row in which they have declined.
  • The average salary in the securities industry in 2010 grew by 16.1 percent to $361,330, 5.5 times higher than the average salary in the private sector of $66,120. The disparity between average salaries in the securities industry and the rest of the private sector narrowed in 2008 and 2009, but widened in 2010.
  • In 2010, the securities industry accounted for 23.5 percent of all wages paid in the private sector despite accounting for only 5.3 percent of all private sector jobs.
  • The State Comptroller’s Office estimates that each job gained (or lost) in the securities industry leads to the creation (or loss) of almost two additional jobs in other industries in the New York City and another job elsewhere in New York State.“

This may be the beginning of the loss of jobs and business to the US because of the erosion of the country’s competitiveness by recession-inspired regulatory fervor. Regulatory erosion of the competitiveness of the US in capital markets had even begun earlier (see Pelaez and Pelaez, Globalization and the State, Vol. II (2009b), 168-179).

Raising capital at currently depressed prices of bank shares for regulatory purposes and to absorb haircuts is extremely expensive. Patrick Jenkins, Brooke Masters and Alex Barker, writing on Oct 12, 2011, on “EU banks could shrink to hit capital rules,” published by the Financial Times (http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/f2e62f82-f4f2-11e0-9023-00144feab49a.html#axzz1aeiD8tdo), analyze the solution to increasing capital needs: some banks are planning to sell assets. The sale of assets reduces the balance sheet to existing capital. Shrinking assets is equal to reduction of loans. Disintermediation of banking harms economic growth as found in extensive scholarly literature (see Pelaez and Pelaez, Regulation of Banks and Finance (2009a), 22-6, Financial Regulation after the Global Recession (2009b), 37-44). Large financial centers in Europe will experience the same downsizing and job losses as New York City. Peter Spiegel, writing on Oct 14, 2011, on “Investor threat to second Greek bail-out,” published in the Financial Times (http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/3be6b6aa-f676-11e0-86dc-00144feab49a.html#axzz1atpiPINZ), finds that investors on Greek debt are unwilling to increase the haircut above the 21 percent agreed on Jul 21 (see section IB in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/07/debt-and-financial-risk-aversion-and.html). With little prospects of other people’s money the solution turns again to taxpayers in Germany and possibly France with equally dark prospects. The economic issue is not whether Germany should, which would be decided in elections, but whether Germany can pay alone for the profligacy of other sovereigns in the European Monetary Union. The Wriston “doctrine” on sovereign lending was predicated on the argument that countries do not bankrupt (Wriston 1982). Another Wriston idea was that the old Citibank should be more valuable dead than alive: if Citibank followed the model of the old Merrill Lynch and sold the individual components or franchises the value would be higher than that of the unbroken Citibank. There was a rise in leveraged buy outs (LBO) in the 1980s that has been extensively analyzed in academic literature (see Pelaez and Pelaez, Regulation of Banks and Finance (2009b), 159-66). The debt crisis of the 1980s and many other episodes in history actually proved that a country can bankrupt and that many countries can bankrupt simultaneously.

Welfare economics considers the desirability of alternative states, which in this case would be evaluating the “value” of Germany (1) within and (2) outside the euro zone. Is the sum of the wealth of euro zone countries outside of the euro zone higher than the wealth of these countries maintaining the euro zone? On the choice of indicator of welfare, Hicks (1975, 324) argues:

“Partly as a result of the Keynesian revolution, but more (perhaps) because of statistical labours that were initially quite independent of it, the Social Product has now come right back into its old place. Modern economics—especially modern applied economics—is centered upon the Social Product, the Wealth of Nations, as it was in the days of Smith and Ricardo, but as it was not in the time that came between. So if modern theory is to be effective, if it is to deal with the questions which we in our time want to have answered, the size and growth of the Social Product are among the chief things with which it must concern itself. It is of course the objective Social Product on which attention must be fixed. We have indexes of production; we do not have—it is clear we cannot have—an Index of Welfare.”

If the burden of the debt of the euro zone falls on Germany and France or only on Germany, is the wealth of Germany and France or only Germany higher after breakup of the euro zone or if maintaining the euro zone? In practice, political realities will determine the decision through elections.

The euro zone faces a critical survival risk because several of its members may default on their sovereign obligations if not bailed out by a few of the other members. Contrary to the Wriston doctrine, investing in sovereign obligations is a credit decision. The value of a bond today is equal to the discounted value of future obligations of interest and principal until maturity. On Oct 14, the yield of the 2-year bond of the government of Greece was quoted above 58 percent and the 10-year bond yield traded at over 24 percent. In contrast, the 2-year US Treasury note traded at 0.269 percent and the 10-year at 2.251 percent while the comparable 2-year government bond of Germany traded at 0.66 percent and the 10-year government bond of Germany traded at 2.20 percent (see Table 7). There is no need for sovereign ratings: the perceptions of investors are of relatively higher probability of default by Greece, defying Wriston (1982), and nil probability of default of the US Treasury and the German government. The essence of the sovereign credit decision is whether the sovereign will be able to finance new debt and refinance existing debt without interrupting service of interest and principal. Prices of sovereign bonds incorporate multiple anticipations such as inflation and liquidity premiums of long-term relative to short-term debt but also risk premiums on whether the sovereign’s debt can be managed as it increases without bound or close to the maximum desired by investors.

Much of the analysis and concern over the euro zone centers on the default risk of the debt of a few countries while there is little if any risk of default of the debt of the euro zone as a whole. In practice, there is convergence in valuations and concerns toward the fact that there may not be survival of the euro zone as a whole. The fluctuations of financial risk assets of members of the euro zone move together with risk aversion toward the countries with nil default probability. This movement raises the need to consider analytically sovereign debt valuation of the euro zone as a whole in the essential analysis of whether the single-currency will (or should) survive without major changes.

The prospects of survival of the euro zone are dire. Table 8 is constructed with IMF World Economic Outlook database released during the prior week for GDP in USD billions, primary net lending/borrowing as percent of GDP and general government debt as percent of GDP for selected regions and countries in 2010.

Table 8, World and Selected Regional and Country GDP and Fiscal Situation

 

GDP 2010
USD Billions

Primary Net Lending Borrowing
% GDP 2010

General Government Net Debt
% GDP 2010

World

62,911.2

   

Euro Zone

12,167.8

-3.6

65.9

Portugal

229.2

-6.3

88.7

Ireland

206.9

-28.9

78.0

Greece

305.4

-4.9

142.8

Spain

1,409.9

-7.8

48.8

Major Advanced Economies G7

31,716.9

-6.5

76.5

United States

14,526.6

-8.4

68.3

UK

2,250.2

-7.7

67.7

Germany

3,286.5

-1.2

57.6

France

2,562.7

-4.9

76.5

Japan

5,458.8

-8.1

117.2

Canada

1,577.0

-4.9

32.2

Italy

2,055.1

-0.3

99.4

China

5,878.3

-2.3

33.8*

Cyprus

23.2

-5.3

61.6

*Gross Debt

Source: http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2011/01/weodata/index.aspx

The data in Table 8 are used for some very simple calculations in Table 9. The column “Net Debt USD Billions” in Table 9 is generated by applying the percentage in Table 8 column “General Government Net Debt % GDP 2010” to the column “GDP USD Billions.” The total debt of France and Germany in 2010 is $3853.5 billion, as shown in row “B+C” in column “Net Debt USD Billions” The sum of the debt of Italy, Spain, Portugal, Greece and Ireland is $3531.6 billion. There is some simple “unpleasant bond arithmetic” in the two final columns of Table 9. Suppose the entire debt burdens of the five countries with probability of default were to be guaranteed by France and Germany, which de facto would be required by continuing the euro zone. The sum of the total debt of these five countries and the debt of France and Germany is shown in column “Debt as % of Germany plus France GDP” to reach $7385.1 billion, which would be equivalent to 126.3 percent of their combined GDP in 2010. Under this arrangement the entire debt of the euro zone including debt of France and Germany would not have nil probability of default. The final column provides “Debt as % of Germany GDP” that would exceed 224 percent if including debt of France and 165 percent of German GDP if excluding French debt. The unpleasant bond arithmetic illustrates that there is a limit as to how far Germany and France can go in bailing out the countries with unsustainable sovereign debt without incurring severe pains of their own such as downgrades of their sovereign credit ratings. A central bank is not typically engaged in direct credit because of remembrance of inflation and abuse in the past. There is also a limit to operations of the European Central Bank in doubtful credit obligations. Wriston (1982) would prove to be wrong again that countries do not bankrupt but would have a consolation prize that similar to LBOs the sum of the individual values of euro zone members outside the current agreement exceeds the value of the whole. Internal rescues of French and German banks may be less costly than bailing out other euro zone countries so that they do not default on French and German banks.

Table 9, Guarantees of Debt of Sovereigns in Euro Area as Percent of GDP of Germany and France, USD Billions and %

 

Net Debt USD Billions

Debt as % of Germany Plus France GDP

Debt as % of Germany GDP

A Euro Area

8,018.6

   

B Germany

1,893.0

 

$7385.1 as % of $3286.5 =224.7%

$5424.6 as % of $3286.5 =165.1%

C France

1,960.5

   

B+C

3,853.5

GDP $5849.2

Total Debt

$7385.1

Debt/GDP: 126.3%

 

D Italy

2,042.8

   

E Spain

688.0

   

F Portugal

203.3

   

G Greece

436.1

   

H Ireland

161.4

   

Subtotal D+E+F+G+H

3,531.6

   

Source: calculation with IMF data http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2011/01/weodata/index.aspx

There is extremely important information in Table 51 anticipated here from subsection IVE Germany for the current sovereign risk crisis in the euro zone. Table 51 provides the structure of regional and country relations of Germany’s exports and imports. German exports to other European Union members are 57.1 percent of total exports in Aug and 59.7 percent in Jan-Aug. Exports to the euro area are 36.9 percent in Aug and 40.1 percent in Jan-Aug. Exports to third countries are only 42.9 percent of the total in Aug and 40.2 percent in Jan-Aug. There is similar distribution for imports. Economic performance in Germany is closed related to its high competitiveness in world markets. Weakness in the euro zone and the European Union in general could affect the German economy.

Table 51, Germany, Structure of Exports and Imports by Region, € Billions and ∆%

 

Aug 2011
€ Billions

12 Months
∆%

Jan-Aug
2011 € Billions

Jan-Aug 2011/
Jan-Jul 2010 ∆%

Total
Exports

85.3

14.6

696.8

14.0

A. EU
Members

48.7

% 57.1

12.7

415.8

% 59.7

13.3

Euro Area

31.5

% 36.9

11.5

279.5

% 40.1

11.9

Non-euro Area

17.1

% 20.0

15.1

136.3

% 19.6

16.5

B. Third Countries

36.6

% 42.9

17.1

281.0

% 40.3

15.1

Total Imports

73.5

12.6

595.3

16.1

C. EU Members

44.8

% 60.9

12.4

376.4

% 63.2

16.6

Euro Area

31.3

% 42.6

13.0

265.4

% 44.6

15.9

Non-euro Area

13.5

11.0

111.0

18.5

D. Third Countries

28.7

% 39.1

12.8

218.9

% 36.8

15.1

Notes: Total Exports = A+B; Total Imports = C+D

Source: http://www.destatis.de/jetspeed/portal/cms/Sites/destatis/Internet/EN/press/pr/2011/10/PE11__373__51,templateId=renderPrint.psml

IV Global Inflation. There is inflation everywhere in the world economy, with slow growth and persistently high unemployment in advanced economies. Table 10 updated with every post, provides the latest annual data for GDP, consumer price index (CPI) inflation, producer price index (PPI) inflation and unemployment (UNE) for the advanced economies, China and the highly-indebted European countries with sovereign risk issues. The table now includes the Netherlands and Finland that with Germany make up the set of northern countries in the euro zone that hold key votes in the enhancement of the mechanism for solution of the sovereign risk issues (http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/55eaf350-4a8b-11e0-82ab-00144feab49a.html#axzz1G67TzFqs). Newly available data on inflation is considered below in this section. The data in Table 10 for the euro zone and its members is updated from information provided by Eurostat but individual country information is provided in this section  as soon as available, following Table 10. Data for other countries in Table 10 is also updated with reports from their statistical agencies. Economic data for major regions and countries is considered in Section IV World Economic Slowdown following individual country and regional data tables.

Table 10, GDP Growth, Inflation and Unemployment in Selected Countries, Percentage Annual Rates

 

GDP

CPI

PPI

UNE

US

1.6

3.8

6.5

9.1

Japan

-1.1

0.2

2.5

4.4

China

9.6

6.1

6.5

 

UK

1.8

4.5*
RPI 5.2

6.3* output
17.5*
input
13.3**

8.1

Euro Zone

1.6

3.0

5.9

10.0

Germany

2.8

2.9

5.4

6.0

France

1.6

2.4

6.3

9.9

Nether-lands

1.5

3.0

7.7

4.4

Finland

2.7

3.5

7.5

7.8

Belgium

2.5

3.4

7.1

6.8

Portugal

-0.9

3.5

5.5

12.3

Ireland

-1.0

1.3

4.7

14.6

Italy

0.8

3.6

4.8

7.9

Greece

-4.8

2.9

7.4

15.1

Spain

0.7

3.0

7.1

21.2

Notes: GDP: rate of growth of GDP; CPI: change in consumer price inflation; PPI: producer price inflation; UNE: rate of unemployment; all rates relative to year earlier

*Office for National Statistics

PPI http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/dcp171778_233900.pdf

CPI http://www.statistics.gov.uk/pdfdir/cpi0611.pdf

** Excluding food, beverage, tobacco and petroleum

Source: EUROSTAT; country statistical sources http://www.census.gov/aboutus/stat_int.html

Table 10 shows the simultaneous occurrence of low growth, inflation and unemployment in advanced economies. The US grew at 1.6 percent in IIQ2011 relative to IIQ2010 (Table 8, p 15 in http://www.bea.gov/newsreleases/national/gdp/2011/pdf/gdp2q11_3rd.pdf); Japan’s GDP contracted 1.1 percent in IIQ2011 relative to IIQ2010 because of the Tōhoku or Great East Earthquake and Tsunami of Mar 11, 2011 but growth has been at low rates; the UK grew at 1.8 percent in IIQ2011 relative to IIQ2010; and the Euro Zone grew at 1.6 percent in IIQ2011 relative to IIQ2010. These are stagnating or growth recession rates. The rates of unemployment are quite high: 9.1 percent in the US but 18.5 percent for unemployment/underemployment (see Table 3 in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/10/twenty-nine-million-unemployedunderempl.html), 4.4 percent for Japan, 8.1 percent for the UK and 10.0 percent in the Euro Zone. Twelve months rates of inflation have been quite high, even when some are moderating at the margin: 3.8 percent in the US, 0.2 percent for Japan and 3.0 percent for the Euro Zone. Stagflation is still an unknown event but the risk is sufficiently high to be worthy of consideration (see http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/06/risk-aversion-and-stagflation.html). The analysis of stagflation also permits the identification of important policy issues in solving vulnerabilities that have high impact on global financial risks. There are six key interrelated vulnerabilities in the world economy that have been causing global financial turbulence: (1) sovereign risk issues in Europe resulting from countries in need of fiscal consolidation and enhancement of their sovereign risk ratings (see Section II World Financial Turbulence in this post, http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/10/twenty-nine-million-unemployedunderempl.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/10/us-growth-standstill-at-08-percent.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/imf-view-of-world-economy-and-finance.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/collapse-of-household-income-and-wealth.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/financial-turbulence-wriston-doctrine.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/global-growth-standstill-recession.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/08/united-states-gdp-growth-standstill.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/08/world-financial-turbulence-global.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/08/global-growth-recession-25-to-30.html section II in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/08/global-growth-recession-25-to-30.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/07/twenty-five-to-thirty-million.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/06/risk-aversion-and-stagflation.html and Section I Increasing Risk Aversion in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/06/increasing-risk-aversion-analysis-of.html and section IV in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/04/budget-quagmire-fed-commodities_10.html); (2) the tradeoff of growth and inflation in China; (3) slow growth (see http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/10/us-growth-standstill-at-08-percent.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/global-growth-standstill-recession.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/08/united-states-gdp-growth-standstill.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/08/global-growth-recession-25-to-30.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/07/growth-recession-debt-financial-risk.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/06/financial-risk-aversion-slow-growth.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/05/slowing-growth-global-inflation-great.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/05/mediocre-growth-world-inflation.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011_03_01_archive.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/02/mediocre-growth-raw-materials-shock-and.html), weak hiring (see Section II United States Hiring Collapse, http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/financial-turbulence-wriston-doctrine.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/08/world-financial-turbulence-global.html and section III Hiring Collapse in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/04/fed-commodities-price-shocks-global.html ) and continuing job stress of 24 to 30 million people in the US and stagnant wages in a fractured job market (see Section I Twenty Nine Million Unemployed/Underemployed in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/10/twenty-nine-million-unemployedunderempl.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/global-growth-standstill-recession.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/07/twenty-five-to-thirty-million.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/05/job-stress-of-24-to-30-million-falling.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/04/twenty-four-to-thirty-million-in-job_03.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/03/unemployment-and-undermployment.html); (4) the timing, dose, impact and instruments of normalizing monetary and fiscal policies (see II Budget/Debt Quagmire in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/08/united-states-gdp-growth-standstill.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/03/is-there-second-act-of-us-great.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/03/global-financial-risks-and-fed.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/02/policy-inflation-growth-unemployment.html) in advanced and emerging economies; (5) the Tōhoku or Great East Earthquake and Tsunami of Mar 11, 2011 that had repercussions throughout the world economy because of Japan’s share of about 9 percent in world output, role as entry point for business in Asia, key supplier of advanced components and other inputs as well as major role in finance and multiple economic activities (http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052748704461304576216950927404360.html?mod=WSJ_business_AsiaNewsBucket&mg=reno-wsj); and (6) the geopolitical events in the Middle East.

Table 11 provides the forecasts of the Federal Reserve Board Members and Federal Reserve Bank Presidents for the FOMC meeting in Jun. There are lags in effect of monetary policy (Batini and Nelson 2002, Culbertson 1960, 1961, Friedman 1961, Romer and Romer 2004). Central banks forecast inflation in the effort to program monetary policy to attain effects at the correct timing of need by taking into account lags in effects of policy (Pelaez and Pelaez, Regulation of Banks and Finance (2009b), 99-116). Inflation by the price index of personal consumption expenditures (PCE) was forecast for 2011 in the Apr meeting of the FOMC between 2.1 to 2.8 percent. Table 11 shows that the interval has narrowed to PCE (personal consumption expenditures) headline inflation of between 2.3 and 2.5 percent. The FOMC focuses on core PCE inflation, which excludes food and energy. The Apr forecast of core PCE inflation was an interval between 1.3 and 1.6 percent. Table 11 shows the revision of this forecast in Jun to a higher interval between 1.5 and 1.8 percent. A new forecast with significant changes will be provided in Nov.

Table 11, Forecasts of PCE Inflation and Core PCE Inflation by the FOMC, %

 

PCE Inflation

Core PCE Inflation

2011

2.3 to 2.5

1.5 to 1.8

2012

1.5 to 2.0

1.4 to 2.0

2013

1.5 to 2.0

1.4 to 2.0

Longer Run

1.7 to 2.0

 

Source: http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/fomcprojtabl20110622.pdf

In testimony to the Joint Economic Committee of the US Congress, Chairman Bernanke (2011Oct4, 6) provides more current evaluation of the inflation outlook:

“As the FOMC anticipated, however, inflation has begun to moderate as these transitory influences wane. In particular, the prices of oil and many other commodities have either leveled off or have come down from their highs, and the step-up in automobile production has started to reduce pressures on the prices of cars and light trucks. Importantly, the higher rate of inflation experienced so far this year does not appear to have become ingrained in the economy. Longer-term inflation expectations have remained stable according to surveys of households and economic forecasters, and the five-year-forward measure of inflation compensation derived from yields on nominal and inflation-protected Treasury securities suggests that inflation expectations among investors may have moved lower recently. In addition to the stability of longer-term inflation expectations, the substantial amount of resource slack in U.S. labor and product markets should continue to restrain inflationary pressures.”

The measures taken by the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) are described by Chairman Bernanke (2011Oct4, 6-7) as follows:

“In view of the deterioration in the economic outlook over the summer and the subdued inflation picture over the medium run, the FOMC has taken several steps recently to provide additional policy accommodation. At the August meeting, the Committee provided greater clarity about its outlook for the level of short-term interest rates by noting that economic conditions were likely to warrant exceptionally low levels for the federal funds rate at least through mid-2013. And at our meeting in September, the Committee announced that it intends to increase the average maturity of the securities in the Federal Reserve’s portfolio. Specifically, it intends to purchase, by the end of June 2012, $400 billion of Treasury securities with remaining maturities of 6 years to 30 years and to sell an equal amount of Treasury securities with remaining maturities of 3 years or less, leaving the size of our balance sheet approximately unchanged. This maturity extension program should put downward pressure on longer-term interest rates and help make broader financial conditions more supportive of economic growth than they would otherwise have been. The Committee also announced in September that it will begin reinvesting principal payments on its holdings of agency debt and agency mortgage-backed securities in agency mortgage-backed securities rather than in longer-term Treasury securities. By helping to support mortgage markets, this action too should contribute to a stronger economic recovery.”

Three distinguished economists have analyzed current monetary policy from different perspectives. These contributions are considered in turn.

First, Professor Alan S. Blinder (2011Sep28) of Princeton University, former Vice Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, writing on “Ben Bernanke deserves a break,” on Sep 28, 2011, published in the Wall Street Journal (http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052970204422404576594682273860392.html?mod=WSJ_hps_sections_opinion), analyzes the need and possible effects of “let’s twist again” monetary policy: (1) weak US economic growth is insufficient to reduce high unemployment; (2) political division prevents further fiscal stimulus; (3) financial markets anticipated “let’s twist again” monetary policy and could downtrend in the absence of any measure; and (4) with policy interest rates mear zero there are not many additional tools of monetary policy. Blinder (2011Sep28) finds that policy action was needed. The first round of quantitative easing attempted to reduce the spread between Treasury securities and mortgage-backed securities with the objective of stimulating the real estate sector. An added advantage of “let’s twist again” is that it provides for the reinvestment of principal and interest of the Fed’s portfolio of mortgage-backed securities into mortgage-backed securities and not in Treasury securities. Blinder (2011Sep28) also ponders if future quantitative easing could focus on corporate bonds, syndicated loans, consumer receivables and similar private-sector instruments.

Second, Professor Charles I. Plosser (2011Sep29), currently President and CEO of the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, analyzes the economic outlook and the reasons for his dissenting votes in two successive meetings of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC). An important constraint of policy is that deflation was a risk when quantitative easing two was deliberated and implemented on Nov 3, 2010. The environment of inflation has changed according to Plosser (2011Sep29, 5):

“Thus, with inflation higher and unemployment lower, it is appropriate to ask what criteria we are using to justify further accommodation. In this environment, I think it is very important that we refrain from actions that risk fueling a steady rise in inflation or inflation expectations over the medium term. We must not become too sanguine that high unemployment will lead to low inflation. The lesson of the 1970s is clear – high unemployment or low resource utilization is not sufficient to prevent high rates of inflation. The current environment in the U.K. should also be a warning. The unemployment rate in Britain is near 8 percent, having risen sharply during its recession, yet inflation is now approaching 5 percent and has been steadily rising for nearly two years.”

Monetary policy, according to Plosser (2011Sep29, 6) should be decided on the basis of cost and benefit analysis and not merely on just doing something. Quantitative easing two and the original Operation Twist reduced yields of long-term Treasury securities by 20 basis points or less. The problem is that “the pass-through to the rates at which consumers and businesses actually borrow is likely to be much less” (Plosser 2011Sep29, 6). Unconventional policies in high doses may also have high potential costs as analyzed by Plosser (2011Sep29, 6):

“We have provided a great deal of monetary accommodation to the economy, and given the stubbornness of the unemployment rate in responding to these efforts, we should be cautious and vigilant that our previous accommodative policies do not translate into a steady rise in inflation over the medium term even while the unemployment rate remains elevated. Creating an environment of stagflation, reminiscent of the 1970s, will not help businesses, the unemployed, or the consumer. It is an outcome we must carefully guard against.”

Third, Professor Ronald McKinnon (2011Sep30) of Stanford University, writing on “Where are the bond vigilantes?” on Sep 30, published in the Wall Street Journal (http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424053111904332804576538363789127084.html?mod=WSJ_hps_sections_opinion), analyzes how unconventional monetary policy has removed fiscal discipline imposed by Treasury bond yields while also disrupting the functioning of financial markets. In historical episodes of proposed high fiscal deficits, bond yields surged in anticipation of unsustainable debt that helped to elicit agreements among politicians to control deficits and debt. McKinnon (2011Sep30) finds two conditions for “bond vigilantes” to impose fiscal discipline by increases in Treasury yields. (1) Treasury securities must be held by institutions that are sensitive to changes in yields, meaning that they worry about future inflation and risk premiums on government debt resulting from uncontrolled fiscal deficits. (2) Private holders of Treasury securities must have expectations that decreases in short-term interest rates toward zero are only temporary, meaning that the FOMC is not committed to maintaining interest rates at zero forever. Long-term interest rates are viewed as expected future short-term interest rates plus the liquidity premium required in holding securities with higher duration. These two conditions have disappeared. (1) Near zero interest rates during almost all of the past decade or the threat of such rates as policy is dominated by unconventional monetary policy has caused a global hunt for yields that bloated assets in emerging markets. As a result of hot money capital flows, foreign monetary authorities are major holders of Treasury securities and are less concerned about yields. (2) The various rounds of quantitative easing have converted the Fed in holder of large part of Treasury debt and the Fed is yield conscious in the opposite direction of near zero interest rates.

McKinnon (2011Sep30) considers three adverse effects of unconventional monetary policy besides eroding imposition of fiscal discipline by rising bond yields in the presence of uncontrolled deficits and unsustainable debt. (1) In past monetary policy, borrowers believed temporarily short-term interest rates would be eventually reversed such that they took advantage of low borrowing costs. This is no longer true as the FOMC decided on Aug 9, 2011, to leave fed fund rates at 0 to ¼ percent for years in advance (http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20110809a.htm): “The Committee currently anticipates that economic conditions--including low rates of resource utilization and a subdued outlook for inflation over the medium run--are likely to warrant exceptionally low levels for the federal funds rate at least through mid-2013.” Why borrow to invest or consume now when rates are going to be almost zero indefinitely? (2) Quantitative easing is financed by creating bank reserves that banks prefer to leave deposited at the Federal Reserve System remunerated at 0.25 percent but without risk instead of lending them at near zero interest rates with risk in the interbank market. (3) Maintaining short-term interest rates creates major disruptions of many financial institutions such as pension funds. McKinnon (2011Sep30) provides the example of calculations by pension actuaries that California pension funds require a yield of 7.5 percent to break even in honoring their annuities. A review of arguments of Professor McKinnon is in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/professor-mckinnons-bubble-economy.html

The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, the staff of Federal Reserve System and the members of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) include highly qualified individuals who have access to the frontier of knowledge in economics. The difficulty in finding common ground on policy, typical of economics, is found in the multiple views on what to do with quantitative easing revealed in the minutes of the FOMC of the meeting on Sep 20-1, 2011 (pages 2-3 in http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/fomcminutes20110921.pdf):

“Meeting participants expressed a range of views on the potential efficacy of policy tools tied to the size and composition of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet. Many judged that these policies could provide additional monetary policy accommodation by lowering longer-term interest rates and easing financial conditions at a time when further reductions in the federal funds rate are infeasible. However, a number saw the potential effects on real economic activity as limited or only transitory, particularly in the current environment of balance sheet deleveraging, credit constraints, and household and business uncertainty about the economic outlook. Participants noted that a SOMA maturity extension program would not expand the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet or the level of reserve balances, and that the scale of such a program was necessarily limited by the size of the Federal Reserve’s holdings of shorter-term securities so that it could not be repeated to provide further stimulus. A number of participants saw large-scale asset purchases as potentially a more potent tool that should be retained as an option in the event that further policy action to support a stronger economic recovery was warranted. Some judged that large-scale asset purchases and the resulting expansion of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet would be more likely to raise inflation and inflation expectations than to stimulate economic activity and argued that such tools should be reserved for circumstances in which the risk of deflation was elevated. In commenting on the implications of a maturity extension program or another large-scale asset purchase program, several participants noted that the System should avoid holding a very large proportion of the outstanding stock of longer-term Treasury securities in its portfolio because the result could be a deterioration in market functioning. A number of participants suggested directing some purchases or reinvestments into agency MBS; however, a couple of participants saw such actions as unlikely to have benefits, or as a form of credit allocation.”

Unconventional monetary policy of near zero interest rates and quantitative easing has been successful mainly in promoting the carry trade from near zero interest rates to leveraged positions in risk financial assets, in particular commodity futures. Chart 20 of the Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) shows the Food Price Index that trended down during the recession of 2001. An upward trend was promoted by unconventional monetary policy of 1 percent fed funds rate together with the suspension of the auction of the 30-year Treasury bond to lower mortgage rates, encouraging refinancing that was more important in cash infusion of households than tax rebates. Food prices trended upward and with sharp reductions of monetary policy rates peaked in a big jump to more than $140/barrel in 2008 during a global recession. The flight out of risk financial assets after the announcement of the Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP) (see Cochrane and Zingales 2009) is shown in Chart 20 in a collapse of the Food Price Index of FAO. With zero interest rates after the FOMC meeting on Dec 16, 2008 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20081216b.htm) and realization in early 2009 that bank assets were not as worrisome as argued for approval of TARP, food prices jumped again to even higher levels.

clip_image044

Chart 20, Food and Agriculture Organization Food Price Index 1990-2011

Source: UN Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) 

http://www.fao.org/worldfoodsituation/wfs-home/foodpricesindex/en/

Chart 21 of the US Energy Information Administration shows exactly the same behavior of the price of crude oil. There is the same decline after the 2001 recession that was confused as global deflation. Oil prices trend upward with the near zero interest rates and suspension of the auction of the 30-year Treasury, which was quantitative easing by reduction of supply in a desired segment of the yield curve. There is the same jump of oil prices in 2008 in the midst of sharp global contraction and vertical drop in the flight to safety away from risk financial assets. A new upward trend was promoted by the carry trade from zero interest rates after Dec 16, 2008 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20081216b.htm) and the return of risk appetite in early 2009. Prices have dropped recently because of risk aversion resulting from the European sovereign risk crisis and growth slowdown in the US and the world. The success of unconventional monetary policy of zero interest rates and quantitative easing is in promoting carry trades from zero interest rates into risk financial assets such as equities, emerging markets, currencies and commodities’ futures.

clip_image045

Chart 21, Crude Oil Cushing, OK, Contract 1

Source: US Energy Information Administration

http://www.eia.gov/dnav/pet/hist/LeafHandler.ashx?n=PET&s=RCLC1&f=D

Inflation in advanced economies has been moderating at the producer price level with moderation of the commodity price shock. Table 12 provides the month and 12 months rates of inflation of Japan’s corporate goods price index (CGPI). Inflation measured by the CGPI fell 0.1 percent in Sep and increased 2.5 percent in 12 months. Measured by 12 months rates, CGPI inflation has increased from minus 0.2 percent in Jul 2010 to a high of 2.8 percent in Jul and now 2.5 percent in Sep. At the margin, annual equivalent inflation in the quarter Jul to Sep 2011 is 0 percent compared with annual equivalent inflation in Jan-Set 2011 of 2.7 percent. Moderation of commodity price increases after May 2011, influenced by risk aversion, has caused collapse of monthly inflation toward zero.

Table 12, Japan Corporate Goods Price Index (CGPI)  ∆%

 

Month

Year

Sep 2011

-0.1

2.5

Aug

-0.2

2.6

Jul

0.2

2.8

AE ∆% Jul-Aug

0.0

 

Jun

0.0

2.5

May

-0.2

2.2

Apr

1.0

2.6

Mar

0.6

2.0

Feb

0.1

1.7

Jan

0.6

1.6

AE ∆% Jan-Set

2.7

 

Dec 2010

0.4

1.2

Nov

0.0

0.9

Oct

0.2

0.9

Sep

0.0

-0.1

Aug

0.0

0.0

Jul

-0.1

-0.2

AE: annual equivalent

Source: http://www.boj.or.jp/en/statistics/pi/cgpi_release/cgpi1109.pdf

Further insight into inflation of the corporate goods price index (CGPI) of Japan is provided in Table 13. Manufactured products accounting for 92.8 percent of the products in the index fell 0.2 percent in Sep and increased 2.5 percent in 12 months. Petroleum and coal with weight of 5.4 percent fell 1.2 percent in Sep but increased 17.2 percent in 12 months. Japan exports manufactured products and imports raw materials and commodities such that the country’s terms of trade, or export prices relative to import prices, deteriorate during commodity price increases. In contrast, machinery and equipment rose 0.1 percent in Sep and 0.0 percent in 12 months. In general, most manufactured products experienced mild increases in prices while inflation rates were high in 12 months for products originating in raw materials and commodities. Ironically, unconventional monetary policy of zero interest rates and quantitative easing deteriorated the terms of trade of advanced economies.

Table 13, Japan, Corporate Goods Prices and Selected Components, % Weights, Month and 12 Months ∆%

Sep 2011

Weight

Month ∆%

12 Month ∆%

Total

100.0

-0.1

2.5

Mfg

92.8

-0.2

2.5

Processed
Food

11.5

0.5

4.2

Petroleum & Coal

5.4

-1.2

17.2

Machinery & Equipment

10.8

0.1

0.0

Electric & Electronic

12.9

-0.1

-3.6

Electric Power, Gas & Water

4.7

1.2

5.2

Iron & Steel

5.3

0.2

4.3

Chemicals

8.5

-0.2

5.4

Transport
Equipment

12.5

0.1

0.2

Source: http://www.boj.or.jp/en/statistics/pi/cgpi_release/cgpi1109.pdf

Percentage point contributions to change of the corporate goods price index (CGPI) are provided in Table 14 divided into the domestic, export and import segments. Petroleum and coal contributed minus 0.16 percentage points to the fall of the domestic CGPI of Japan of 0.1 percent in Sep. Nonferrous metals contributed minus 0.07 percentage points. The most important source of increase was positive contributions by electric power, gas and water of 0.06 percentage points with processed foodstuffs also contributing 0.06 percentage points. The exports CGPI fell 0.2 percent on the basis of the contract currency and 1.0 percent on the basis of the yen with negative contributions of 0.11 percentage points by metals and related products and 0.10 percentage points by chemicals and related products. The imports CGPI fell 1.2 percent on the contract currency basis and 1.7 percent on the yen basis. The most important contributions were minus 0.88 percentage points by petroleum, coal and natural gas and minus 0.30 percent by metals and related products. 

Table14, Japan, Percentage Point Contributions to Change of Corporate Goods Price Index

Groups Sep 2011

Contribution to Change Percentage Points

A. Domestic Corporate Goods Price Index

Monthly Change: 
-0.1%

Petroleum & Coal

-0.16

Nonferrous Metals

-0.07

Agriculture, Forestry & Fishery

-0.03

Information & Telecommunication Equipment

-0.02

Chemicals & Related Products

-0.01

Electric Power, Gas & Water

0.06

Processed Foodstuffs

0.06

Iron & Steel

0.01

B. Export Price Index

Monthly Change: 
-0.2% contract currency basis
-1.0% yen basis

Metals & Related Products

-0.11

Chemicals & Related Products

-0.10

C. Import Price Index

Monthly Change: 
-1.2% contract currency basis
-1.7% yen basis

Petroleum, Coal & Natural Gas

-0.88

Metals & Related Products

-0.30

Foodstuffs & Feedstuffs

-0.07

Wood, Lumber & Related Products

-0.03

Transportation Equipment

0.06

Source: http://www.boj.or.jp/en/statistics/pi/cgpi_release/cgpi1109.pdf

China is experiencing the same inflation behavior as the advanced economies, as shown in Table 15. Sep inflation of the price indexes for industry is 0 but 12 months inflation is 6.5 percent and inflation in Jan/Sep 2011 relative to the same period in 2010 is 7.0 percent. With the exception of food, increasing 0.6 percent in Sep, 8.2 percent in 12 months and 8.0 percent in the first nine months relative to a year earlier, drivers of past inflation were subdued in Sep. This is the case of prices of raw materials which are flat in Sep after increasing 10.6 percent in 12 months and 10.7 percent in the first nine months. Mining fell 0.1 percent in Sep after increasing 17.2 percent in 12 months and 16.7 percent in the first nine months relative to a year earlier. The various categories of inputs in the purchaser price index show inflation of only 0.1 percent in Sep after increasing 10.0 percent in 12 months and 10.4 in the first nine months relative to a year earlier. 

Table 15, China, Price Indexes for Industry ∆%

 

Month   Sep ∆%

12 Months Sep ∆%

Jan-Sep 2011/
Jan-Sep 2010 ∆%

I Producer Price Indexes

0.0

6.5

7.0

Means of Production

-0.1

7.1

7.8

Mining

-0.1

17.2

16.7

Raw Materials

0.0

10.6

10.7

Processing

-0.1

4.6

5.7

Consumer Goods

0.3

4.6

4.5

Food

0.6

8.2

8.0

Clothing

0.3

4.5

4.3

Daily Use Articles

0.2

4.4

4.4

Durable Consumer Goods

-0.2

-0.6

-0.6

II Purchaser Price Indexes

0.1

10.0

10.4

Nonferrous Metals

-0.4

14.7

15.1

Fuel and Power

-0.1

12.3

11.2

Ferrous Metals

0.2

8.8

11.3

Raw Chemical Materials

0.3

12.7

12.3

Source: http://www.stats.gov.cn/enGliSH/newsandcomingevents/t20111014_402759197.htm

http://www.stats.gov.cn/enGliSH/newsandcomingevents/t20111014_402759197.htm

Producer price inflation in China was 0.0 percent in Sep and 6.5 percent in 12 months, as shown in Table 16. In the quarter Jul-Sep 2011 annual equivalent inflation is only 0.4 percent. In contrast, in the first half of the year annual equivalent inflation was 20.4 percent.

Table 16, China, Month and 12 Months Rate of Change of Producer Price Index, ∆%

 

12 Month ∆%

Month ∆%

Sep 2011

6.5

0.0

Aug

7.3

0.1

Jul

7.5

0.0

AE ∆% Jul-Sep

   

Jun

7.1

0.0

May

6.8

0.3

Apr

6.8

0.5

Mar

7.3

0.6

Feb

7.2

0.8

Jan

6.6

0.9

AE ∆% Jan-Jun

 

20.4

Dec 2010

5.9

0.7

Source:

http://www.stats.gov.cn/enGliSH/newsandcomingevents/t20111014_402759197.htm

http://www.stats.gov.cn/enGliSH/newsandcomingevents/t20111014_402759197.htm

Chart 22 of the National Bureau of Statistics of China provides monthly and 12 months rates of inflation of the price indexes for the industrial sector. The fall of the monthly rates eventually pulled down the 12 months rates. At the margin since Jun inflation has been almost zero.

clip_image046

Chart 22, China, Producer Prices for the Industrial Sector Month and 12 months ∆%

Source: National Bureau of Statistics of China

http://www.stats.gov.cn/enGliSH/newsandcomingevents/t20111014_402759197.htm

http://www.stats.gov.cn/enGliSH/newsandcomingevents/t20111014_402759197.htm

China is highly conscious of food price inflation because of its high weight in the basket of consumption of the population. Consumer price inflation in China in Sep was 0.5 percent, 6.1 percent in 12 months and 5.7 percent in Jan-Sep 2011 relative to Jan-Sep 2010, as shown in Table 17. By far the highest increase occurred in food with 1.1 percent in Sep, 13.4 percent in Sep and 12.5 percent in the first nine months relative to a year earlier. Another area of concern is housing with price inflation of 0.2 percent in Sep, 5.1 percent in 12 months and 6.0 percent in the first nine months relative to a year earlier. Prices of services rose 0.2 percent in Sep, 3.4 percent in 12 months and 3.9 percent in the first nine months relative to a year earlier. In contrast with producer prices, there were increases in all components with the exception of transport and communications and recreation and education.

Table 17, China, Consumer Price Index

 

Sep Month ∆%

Sep 12 Month ∆%

Jan/Sep 2011/
Jan/Sep 2010

Consumer Prices

0.5

6.1

5.7

Urban

0.4

5.9

5.5

Rural

0.6

6.6

6.2

Food

1.1

13.4

12.5

Non-food

0.2

3.0

2.8

Consumer Goods

0.7

7.3

6.4

Services

0.2

3.4

3.9

Commodity Categories:

     

Food

1.1

13.4

12.5

Tobacco, Liquor

0.6

3.4

2.5

Clothing

0.9

3.2

1.6

Household

0.1

3.0

2.2

Healthcare and Personal

0.2

4.1

3.4

Transport Comm.

-0.1

1.0

0.5

Recreation, Education

-0.3

0.0

0.5

Housing

0.2

5.1

6.0

Source: http://www.stats.gov.cn/enGliSH/newsandcomingevents/t20111014_402759206.htm

http://www.stats.gov.cn/enGliSH/

Month and 12 months rates of change of consumer prices are provided in Table 18. In contrast with producer prices, the annual equivalent rate of consumer price inflation rose from 2.0 percent in Apr to Jun to 5.3 percent in Jul to Sep. At the marginal monthly level, consumer prices are increasing at a relatively high rate of 5.3 percent even if lower than 8.3 percent in annual equivalent in Jan-Mar. 

Table 18, China, Month and 12 Months Rates of Change of Consumer Price Index ∆%

 

12 Month ∆%

Month ∆%

Sep 2011

6.1

0.5

Aug

6.2

0.3

Jul

6.5

0.5

AE ∆% Jul to Sep

5.3

 

Jun

6.4

0.3

May

5.5

0.1

Apr

5.3

0.1

AE ∆% Apr to Jun

2.0

 

Mar

5.4

-0.2

Feb

4.9

1.2

Jan

4.9

1.0

AE ∆% Jan to Mar

8.3

 

Dec 2010

4.6

0.5

AE: Annual Equivalent

Source: http://www.stats.gov.cn/enGliSH/newsandcomingevents/t20110909_402753248.htm

http://www.stats.gov.cn/english/newsandcomingevents/index.htm

Chart 23 of the National Bureau of Statistics of China provides monthly and 12 months rates of consumer price inflation. In contrast with producer prices, consumer prices have not moderated at the monthly marginal rates. 

clip_image047

Chart 23, China, Consumer Prices ∆% Month and 12 Months Aug 2010 to Aug 2011

Source: National Bureau of Statistics of China

http://www.stats.gov.cn/enGliSH/newsandcomingevents/t20110909_402753248.htm

http://www.stats.gov.cn/english/newsandcomingevents/index.htm

Inflation accelerated in the euro zone in Sep with 0.8 percent in the month and 3.0 percent in 12 months, as shown in Table 19. The annual equivalent rate in Jul-Aug 2011 of 1.6 is somewhat lower than 1.9 percent annual equivalent in Jan-Sep. Monthly rates have been subdued since the moderation of the commodity price shock beginning in May with only two positive rates of 0.2 percent in Aug and 0.8 percent in Sep. Excluding the high rate of 0.8 percent in Sep, the cumulative monthly rate from May to Aug is negative by 0.4 percent.

Table 19, Euro Area Harmonized Index of Consumer Prices Month and 12 Months ∆%

 

Month ∆%

12 Months ∆%

Sep 2011

0.8

3.0

Aug

0.2

2.5

Jul

-0.6

2.5

AE ∆%  Jul-Aug

1.6

 

Jun

0.0

2.7

May

0.0

2.7

Apr

0.6

2.8

Mar

1.4

2.7

Feb

0.4

2.4

Jan

-0.7

2.3

AE ∆% Jan-Sep

1.9

 

Dec 2010

0.6

2.2

AE: annual equivalent

Source: http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/tgm/refreshTableAction.do?tab=table&plugin=1&pcode=teicp000&language=en

Eurostat provides the decomposition in percentage point contributions of the rate of inflation in 12 months in Sep 2011 relative to Sep 2010 shown in Table 20. Energy-rich components account for the 12 month rate of inflation with percentage point contributions: 0.55 by fuel for transport, 0.19 by heating oil and 0.12 by electricity. Table 20 only lists highest magnitudes of positive and negative contributions. 

Table 20, Euro Area, Harmonized Index of Consumer Prices Sub-Indices with Most Important Impact %

Sep 2011/
Sep 2010

Weight 2011 %

Rate ∆%

Impact
Percentage
Points PP

Positive Contribution

     

Fuel for Transport

46.9

14.7

0.55

Heating Oil

9.5

23.9

0.19

Electricity

24.5

7.7

0.12

Gas

16.7

8.4

0.09

Tobacco

24.8

5.4

0.06

Jewelry & Watches

5.3

12.3

0.05

Negative Contribution

     

Restaurants & Cafés

70.1

2.1

-0.07

IT Equipment

5.0

-12.3

-0.08

Cars

39.3

0.9

-0.08

Rents

59.8

1.4

-0.10

Vegetables

15.8

-4.4

-0.11

Telecom

30.1

-2.1

-0.16

PP: percentage points

Source: http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/cache/ITY_PUBLIC/2-14102011-BP/EN/2-14102011-BP-EN.PDF

Eurostat also provides the highest positive and negative contributions in percentage points to the monthly rate of inflation in Sep, shown in Table 21. The highest contributions were 0.64 percentage points by garments and 0.16 percentage points by footwear. These appear to be seasonal price increases and may not be sustained in coming months.

Table 21, Euro Area, Harmonized Index of Consumer Prices Sub-Indices with Most Important Impact %

Sep 2011/
Aug 2011

Weight 2011 %

Rate ∆%

Impact Percentage Points

Positive

     

Garments

49.5

15.0

0.64

Footwear

13.8

14.0

0.16

Fuels for Transport

46.9

1.3

0.03

Heating Oil

9.5

2.2

0.01

Other Personal Effects

4.3

3.6

0.01

Household Textiles

4.9

2.6

0.01

Negative

     

Telecom

30.1

-0.3

-0.03

Restaurants & Cafés

70.1

0.3

-0.03

Rents

59.8

-0.3

-0.07

Air Transport

5.8

-11.6

-0.09

Accomm.

Services

15.7

-6.1

-0.12

Package Holidays

15.1

-8.9

-0.15

Acomm: accommodation

Source: http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/cache/ITY_PUBLIC/2-14102011-BP/EN/2-14102011-BP-EN.PDF

Consumer price inflation in Germany in Sep was 0.1 percent and 2.6 percent in 12 months, as sown in Table 22. Most of the inflation in Germany in 2011 has concentrated in three months: 0.4 percent in Jul, 0.5 percent in Mar and 0.5 percent in Feb. A quarter composed of those three months repeated for an entire year would result in annual equivalent inflation of 5.8 percent. Annual equivalent inflation in the quarter Jul-Sep was at the annual equivalent rate of 2.0 percent, which is lower than the 2.6 percent 12 months rate in Sep.

Table 22, Germany, Consumer Price Index  ∆%

 

12 Months ∆%

Month ∆%

Sep 2011

2.6

0.1

Aug

2.4

0.0

Jul

2.4

0.4

AE ∆% Jul-Sep

 

2.0

Jun

2.3

0.1

May

2.3

0.0

Apr

2.4

0.2

Mar

2.1

0.5

Feb

2.1

0.5

Jan

2.0

-0.4

AE ∆% Jan-Sep

 

1.9

Dec 2010

1.7

1.0

Nov

1.5

0.1

Oct

1.3

0.1

Sep

1.3

-0.1

Aug

1.0

0.0

Annual Average ∆%

   

2010

1.1

 

2009

0.4

 

2008

2.6

 

Source: http://www.destatis.de/jetspeed/portal/cms/Sites/destatis/Internet/EN/press/pr/2011/10/PE11__380__611,templateId=renderPrint.psml

Table 23 provides the monthly and 12 months rate of inflation for segments of the consumer price index. Inflation excluding energy fell 0.1 percent in Sep and rose 1.5 percent in 12 months. Excluding household energy inflation was flat in Sep and rose 2.1 percent in 12 months. High increases in Germany’s consumer prices in Sep were 0.9 percent in total goods, 2.8 percent in motor fuels, 0.9 percent in household energy and 3.6 percent in heating oil.

Table 23, Germany, Consumer Price Index ∆%

Sep 2011

12 Months ∆%

Month ∆%

Total

2.6

0.1

Excluding heating oil and motor fuels

1.9

-0.1

Excluding household energy

2.1

0.0

Excluding Energy

1.5

-0.1

Total Goods

3.8

0.9

Nondurable Consumer Goods

5.2

0.6

Medium-Term Life Consumer Goods

2.0

2.6

Durable Consumer Goods

-0.1

0.0

Energy Components

   

Motor Fuels

13.9

2.8

Household Energy

9.8

0.9

Heating Oil

23.8

3.6

Food

2.5

-0.1

Source: http://www.destatis.de/jetspeed/portal/cms/Sites/destatis/Internet/EN/press/pr/2011/10/PE11__380__611,templateId=renderPrint.psml

Consumer price inflation is more moderate in France. Table 24 provides monthly and 12 months rates of consumer price inflation in France in 2010 and 2011. The 12 months rate of inflation of consumer prices in France has risen from 1.1 percent in Jan 2010 to 2.2 percent in Sep 2011. The big jump occurred in the quarter of Feb to Apr with monthly rates of 0.5 percent in Feb, 0.8 percent in Mar and 0.3 percent in Apr, equivalent to 6.6 percent per year. With the exception of 0.5 percent in Aug, inflation has been moderate in France in recent months. 

Table 24, France, Consumer Price Index, Month and 12 Months ∆%

 

Month

12 Months

Sep

-0.1

2.2

Aug

0.5

2.2

Jul

-0.5

1.9

Jun

0.1

2.1

May

0.1

2.0

Apr

0.3

2.1

Mar

0.8

2.0

Feb

0.5

1.6

Jan

-0.2

1.8

Dec 2010

0.4

1.8

Nov

0.1

1.6

Oct

0.1

1.6

Sep

-0.1

1.5

Aug

0.2

1.4

Jul

-0.3

1.7

Jun

0.0

1.5

May

0.1

1.6

Apr

0.3

1.7

Mar

0.5

1.6

Feb

0.6

1.3

Jan

-0.3

1.1

Source: http://www.bdm.insee.fr/bdm2/choixCriteres.action?request_locale=en&codeGroupe=142

Chart 24 of the Institut National de la Statistique et des Études Économiques of France shows the headline and core consumption price inflation of France. Inflation rose during the commodity price shock of unconventional monetary policy. Risk aversion in late 2008 and 2009 caused collapse of valuation of commodity futures with resulting decline in inflation. Unconventional monetary policy with alternations of risk aversion resulted in higher inflation in France that has stabilized in recent months.

clip_image049

Chart 24, France, Consumer Price Index (IPC) and Core Consumer Price Index (ISJ) 12 Months Rates of Change

Source:  Institut National de la Statistique et des Études Économiques

http://www.insee.fr/en/themes/info-rapide.asp?id=29&date=20110913

Inflation has been subdued in France since 1999 with the exception of the commodity shock in 2008 as shown in Table 25. The increase in inflation to 2.8 percent in 2008 in the middle of a global recession can be explained only by the carry trade from interest rates collapsing toward zero to valuation of commodity futures contracts.

Table 25, France, Consumer Price Index,  ∆%

 

CPI ∆%

2010

1.5

2009

0.1

2008

2.8

2007

1.5

2006

1.6

2005

1.8

2004

2.1

2003

2.1

2002

1.9

2001

1.7

2000

1.7

1999

0.5

Source:  http://www.bdm.insee.fr/bdm2/choixCriteres.action?request_locale=en&codeGroupe=142

Monthly and 12 months rate of consumer price inflation in Italy are provided in Table 26. Consumer price inflation in Italy rose from the 12 month rate of 1.9 percent in Dec 2010 to 3.0 percent in Sep 2011. Monthly rates moderated to 0.1 percent in May and 0.1 percent in Jun but rose again to 0.3 percent in both Jul and Aug then to decline to zero in Sep. The annual equivalent rate in Jul-Sep is 2.4 percent, which is lower than 3.7 percent annual equivalent in Jan-Sep. The bottom part of Table 26 provides annual inflation in Italy from 2005 to 2010. Unconventional monetary policy of rates collapsing toward zero caused increases in valuation of commodity futures that inflated prices worldwide. Italy was another victim with inflation of 3.3 percent in 2008 during a global recession.

Table 26, Italy, Consumer Price Index, ∆%

 

Month ∆%

12 Months ∆%

Sep 2011

0.0

3.0

Aug

0.3

2.8

Jul

03

2.7

AE ∆% Jul-Sep

2.4

 

Jun

0.1

2.7

May

0.1

2.6

Apr

0.5

2.6

Mar

0.4

2.5

Feb

0.3

2.4

Jan

0.4

2.1

AE ∆% Jan-Sep

3.7

 

Dec 2010

0.4

1.9

Year

   

2010

 

1.5

2009

 

0.8

2008

 

3.3

2007

 

1.8

2006

 

2.1

2005

 

1.9

Source: http://www.istat.it/it/archivio/42529

Chart 25 of the Istituto Nazionale di Statistica of Italy captures the increase in 12 months rates of inflation in Italy. The slope becomes more pronounced in the final months of 2010 and into 2011, then flattens and increases again in Aug and Sep. 

clip_image050

Chart 25, Italy, Consumer Price Index, 12 Months ∆%

Source: Istituto Nazionale di Statistica of Italy

http://www.istat.it/it/archivio/42529

Month and 12 months rate of inflation for components of the consumer price index of Italy are provided in Table 27. As in Germany, there is the same likely seasonal increase of prices of clothing and footwear by 0.8 percent in Sep but only 2.0 percent in 12 months. The highest increase in 12 months is by transport, 6.7 percent, which declined 2.0 percent in Sep.

Table 27, Italy, Consumer Price Index by Components, ∆%

 

Month ∆%

12 Months ∆%

All Items

0.0

3.0

Food and Non-alcoholic Beverages

0.3

2.3

Alcoholic Beverages

0.0

3.8

Clothing & Footwear

0.8

2.0

Residential Water, Electricity, Gas, Fuel

0.1

5.2

Household Goods

0.2

1.8

Health

0.1

0.6

Transport

-2.0

6.7

Communications

-0.3

-1.6

Recreation & Culture

0.2

1.4

Education

1.0

2.2

Hotels, Cafes and Restaurants

1.0

2.7

Miscellaneous

0.7

3.6

Source: http://www.istat.it/it/archivio/42529

IV World Economic Slowdown. The JP Morgan Global Manufacturing & Services PMI produced by JP Morgan and Markit in association with ISM and IFPSM finds that growth of the world economy accelerated toward the end of IIIQ2011 (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=8672). The JP Morgan all-industry, manufacturing and services, PMI seasonally adjusted diffusion index is closely associated with the seasonally-adjusted annual equivalent rate of global GDP. The JP Morgan global all-industry output index registered 52.0 in Sep, which is slightly higher than 51.4 in Aug that was a low in 25 months. The rate of growth in IIIQ2011 was the weakest since IIIQ2009, falling significantly lower than that in IQ2011, which was close to a five-year high. US growth of all-industry output was the driver of global acceleration with industry reaching a six-month high. Additional dynamism was contributed by China and the UK. While global new business showed an enhanced trend in Sep, the growth rate was lower than at the turn of the year. David Hensley, Director of Global Economics Coordination at JP Morgan finds that in Sep global output and new orders grew at relatively higher rates. The implicit growth rate is still quite weak with manufacturing slowing to standstill and services performing below expectations. The adverse impact of world growth slowdown on labor markets could restrict future growth. The JP Morgan Global Manufacturing PMI fell from 50.2 in Aug to 49.9 in Sep for the first time below the contraction frontier of 50 since Jun 2009 (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=8648). David Hensley, Director of Global Economics Coordination at JP Morgan finds stagnating PMI out in the past few months with declining trend of new orders fed by falling flows of international trade. The information in the index suggests declining monthly world industrial production in future months. The table of world manufacturing purchasing managers’ indexes of Real Time Economics the Wall Street Journal (http://blogs.wsj.com/economics/2011/10/03/world-wide-factory-activity-by-country-18/tab/interactive/) shows indexes below 50 for the euro zone (France, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Spain), Netherlands, Australia, Brazil and Taiwan. Most other indexes are slightly above 50.

Short-term indicators of economies accounting for some three-quarters of world output are followed in this blog. The purchasing managers’ indexes are more current and integrated providing the best available world view. There are five conclusions based on the overall information.

1. Recession. The R (recession) word is similarly forbidden as the L (lose) word in positions in trading desks. There appears to be improvement in output data globally in Jul and Aug. There is growing consensus that the world economy may not fall in recession but with higher doubts on Europe that manages a sovereign risk crisis with tough political restrictions. Naturally, slower growth bring economies closer to contraction

2. Inflation. There is evidence of moderation of inflation in recent monthly data. Concern with 12 months is because of wage increases. In a return of risk appetite with zero interest rates, commodity prices would soar again, raising world inflation. There is a good characterization that central banks attempt to inflate the economy in a negatively-sloping short-term Phillips curve that may prove yet another academic myth already disproved by the increase in interest rates by the Fed in 1981

3. Labor Markets. Advanced economies continue to be plagued by fractured labor markets without improving perspectives

4. Output Growth. The world economy and especially advanced economies are struggling with low rates of growth. Advanced economies have accumulated substantial imbalances that may restrict future growth but at some point expectations of inevitable consolidation by taxation and increases in interest rates to end unparalleled accommodation may reduce growth rates

5. Financial Turbulence. There will continue to be sharp fluctuations in valuations of risk financial assets. In recent weeks, volumes have thinned in various financial markets with the possibility of sharper fluctuations by professionals accustomed to reversing exposures to realize profits. This is an essential function of price discovery. European sovereign risks and increasingly the legislative agenda in the US will continue causing turbulence in financial markets

IVA United States. Bradley J. Holcomb, chair of the Institute for Supply Management (ISM) Manufacturing Business Committee, summarizes the Manufacturing ISM Report on Business® (http://www.ism.ws/ISMReport/MfgROB.cfm):

"The PMI registered 51.6 percent, an increase of 1 percentage point from August, indicating expansion in the manufacturing sector for the 26th consecutive month, at a slightly higher rate. The Production Index registered 51.2 percent, indicating a return to growth after contracting in August for the first time since May of 2009. The New Orders Index remained unchanged from August at 49.6 percent, indicating contraction for the third consecutive month. The Backlog of Orders Index decreased 4.5 percentage points to 41.5 percent, contracting for the fourth consecutive month and reaching its lowest level since April 2009, when it registered 40.5 percent. Comments from respondents generally reflect concern over the sluggish economy, political and policy uncertainty in Washington, and forecasts of ongoing high unemployment that will continue to put pressure on demand for manufactured products."

The Sep report shows that the manufacturing sector continues producing at 51.2, which is above the contraction frontier of 50. New orders deteriorated marginally with the Sep index at 49.6, which is slight below the contraction frontier of 50 and equal to the Aug index of also 49.6. The backlog of orders contracted 4.5 percentage points to 41.5 percent that indicates contraction and is the lowest number since 2009 when it registered 40.5 points. Important information in the report is the increase in the price segment from 55.6 in Aug to 56.0 in Sep. The export index rose from 50.5 in Aug to 53.5 in Sep. The overall Manufacturing ISM Report on Business® rose by one percentage point, from 50.6 in Aug to 51.6 in Sep, indicating that manufacturing is growing at a higher rate in 26 months of expansion.

The Sep 2011 Non-manufacturing ISM Report on Business® registered 53.0 in Sep, which was lower by 0.3 percentage points than 53.3 in Aug, which indicates growth at a slightly slower pace (http://www.ism.ws/ISMReport/NonMfgROB.cfm). This is by far compensated by the increase of 3.7 percentage points in the index of new orders from 52.8 in Aug to 56.5 in Sep. Employment was lower by 2.9 percentage points declining from 53.0 in Aug to 49.5, reversing direction to contraction. Another favorable aspect of the report is the decline in the price segment by 2.3 percentage points from 64.2 in Aug to 61.9, indicating increasing prices at slower pace.

Table USA provides the summary indicators of the US economy and where to locate them in the blog. Indicators released in the week of Sep 30 are discussed after Table USA

Table USA, US Economic Indicators

Consumer Price Index

Aug 12 months NSA ∆%: 3.8; ex food and energy ∆%: 2.0
Aug month ∆%: 0.4; ex food and energy ∆%: 0.2
Blog 09/18/11

Producer Price Index

Jun 12 months NSA ∆%: 6.5; ex food and energy ∆% 2.4
Aug month SA ∆% 0.2; ex food and energy∆%: 0.1
Blog 09/18/11

PCE Inflation

Jul 12 months NSA ∆%: headline 2.8; ex food and energy ∆% 1.6
Blog 09/04/11

Employment Situation

Household Survey: Aug Unemployment Rate SA 9.1%
Blog calculation People in Job Stress Aug: 29.9 million NSA
Establishment Survey:
Aug Nonfarm Jobs 0 (zero jobs created); Private +17,000 job created 
Jul 12 months Average Hourly Earnings Inflation Adjusted ∆%: minus 1.3%
Blog 09/04/11

Nonfarm Hiring

Nonfarm Hiring fell from 64.9 million in 2006 to 47.2 million in 2010 or by 17.7 million
Private-Sector Hiring Jul 2011 3.985 million lower by 1.393 million than 5.378 million during contraction in Jul 2001
Blog 09/11/11

GDP Growth

BEA Revised National Income Accounts back to 2003
IQ2011 SAAR ∆%: 0.4
IIQ2011 SAAR ∆%: 1.3

First semester 2011 AE

∆% 0.8 
Blog 09/02/11

Personal Income and Consumption

Jul month ∆% SA Real Disposable Personal Income (RDPI) -0.1
Jul month SA ∆% Real Personal Consumption Expenditures (RPCE): 0.5
12 months NSA ∆%:
RDPI: 1.2; RPCE ∆%: 1.6
Blog 09/04/11

Quarterly Services Report

IIQ11/IQII SA ∆%:
Information 2.0
Professional 1.6
Administrative 2.1
Hospitals 1.8
Blog 09/11/11

Employment Cost Index

IIQ2011 SA ∆%: 0.7
Jun 12 months ∆%: 3.4
Blog 08/07/11

Industrial Production

Aug month SA ∆%: 0.2
Aug 12 months NSA ∆%: 3.4
Capacity Utilization: 77.4
Blog 09/18/11

Productivity and Costs

Nonfarm Business Productivity IIQ2011∆% SAAE -0.7; IIQ2011/IIQ2010 ∆% minus 0.7; Unit Labor Costs IIQ2011 ∆% 3.3; IIQ2011/IIQ2010 ∆%: 1.9

Blog 09/04/11

New York Fed Manufacturing Index

General Business Conditions From -7.72 Aug to Sep: –8.82
New Orders: From -7.82 Aug to –8.0
Blog 09/18/11

Philadelphia Fed Business Outlook Index

General Index from -30.7 Aug to -17.5 Sep
New Orders from Aug -26.8 to -11.3 Sep
Blog 09/18/11

Manufacturing Shipments and Orders

Jul/Aug New Orders SA ∆%: minus 0.2; ex transport ∆%: minus 0.2
12 months Jan-Aug NSA ∆%: 13.0; ex transport ∆% 13.0
Blog 10/09/11

Durable Goods

Aug New Orders SA ∆%: -0.1; ex transport ∆%: -0.1
Aug 12 months NSA New Orders ∆%: 10.1; ex transport ∆% : 9.3
Blog 10/02/11

Sales of Merchant Wholesalers

Jan-Aug 2011/2010 ∆%: Total 15.1; Durable Goods: 12.3; Nondurable
Goods 17.4
Blog 10/09/11

Sales and Inventories of Manufacturers, Retailers and Merchant Wholesalers

Aug 11/Aug 10 NSA ∆%: Total Business 13.7; Manufacturers 13.4
Retailers 9.3; Merchant Wholesalers 18.2
Blog 10/16/11

Sales for Retail and Food Services

Sep 12 months ∆%: Retail and Food Services: 8.1; Retail ∆% 7.6
Blog 10/16/11

Value of Construction Put in Place

Aug SAAR month SA ∆%: 1.4
Aug 12 months NSA: 1.4
Blog 10/09/11

Case-Shiller Home Prices

Jul 2011/Jun 2010 ∆% NSA: 10 Cities –3.7; 20 Cities: –4.1
∆% Jul SA: 10 Cities -0.1 ; 20 Cities: 0.1
Blog 10/02/11

FHFA House Price Index Purchases Only

Jul SA ∆% 0.8;
12 month ∆%: minus 3.2
Blog 09/25/11

New House Sales

Aug month SAAR ∆%:
-2.3
Jan/Aug 2011/2010 NSA ∆%: minus 8.3
Blog 10/02/11

Housing Starts and Permits

Aug Starts month SA ∆%:

-5.0; Permits ∆%: 3.2
Jan/Jul 2011/2010 NSA ∆% Starts -3.8; Permits  ∆% –2.8
Blog 09/25/11

Trade Balance

Balance Aug SA -$45,608 million versus Jul -$45,625 million
Exports Aug SA ∆%: -0.1 Imports Aug SA ∆%: -0.1
Exports Jan-Aug 2011/2010 NSA ∆%: 18.0
Imports Jan-Aug 2011/2010 NSA ∆%: 17.0
Blog 10/16/11

Export and Import Prices

Sep 12 months NSA ∆%: Imports 13.4; Exports 9.5
Blog 10/16/11

Consumer Credit

Aug ∆% annual rate: 5 minus 4.6%
Blog 10/09/11

Net Foreign Purchases of Long-term Treasury Securities

Jul Net Foreign Purchases of Long-term Treasury Securities: $9.5 billion Jul versus Jun $3.4 billion
Major Holders of Treasury Securities: China $1173 billion; Japan $915 billion 
Blog 09/11/11

Treasury Budget

Fiscal Year 2011/2010 ∆%: Receipts 6.5; Outlays 4.2; Individual Income Taxes 21.5
Deficit Fiscal Year 2011 $1,298,614 million
Blog 10/16/11

Flow of Funds

IIQ2011 ∆ since 2007

Assets -$6311B

Real estate -$5111B

Financial -$1490

Net Worth -$5802

Blog 09/18/11

Current Account Balance of Payments

IIQ2011 -121B

%GDP 3.2

Blog 09/18/11

Links to blog comments in Table USA: 10/09/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/10/twenty-nine-million-unemployedunderempl.html

10/02/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/10/us-growth-standstill-at-08-percent.html

09/25/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/imf-view-of-world-economy-and-finance.html

09/18/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/collapse-of-household-income-and-wealth.html

09/11/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/financial-turbulence-wriston-doctrine.html

09/05/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/global-growth-standstill-recession.html

There was mild improvement in the balance of international trade in goods and services of the US in Aug declining from deficit of $45,625 in Jul to deficit of $45,608 in Aug, as shown in Table 28. Exports and imports declined by the same 0.1 percent. In Jul, exports rose 3.4 percent with almost unchanged imports for a reduction of the monthly trade deficit from $51,570 million in Jun to $45,625 in Jul. The trade balance deteriorated from cumulative deficit of $337,265 million in Jan-Aug 2010 to deficit of $376,199 million in Jan-Aug 2011.

Table 28, US, Trade Balance of Goods and Services Seasonally Adjusted Millions of Dollars

 

Trade Balance

Exports

Imports

Aug 2011

-45,608

177,611

223,220

∆%

 

-0.1

-0.05

Jul

-45,625

177,706

223,331

∆%

 

3.4

-0.02

Jun

-51,570

171,802

223,372

∆%

 

-2.2

-1.1

May

-50,182

175,673

225,855

∆%

 

-0.3

2.9

Apr

-43,242

176,267

219,509

∆%

 

1.3

-0.4

Mar

-46,397

173,981

220,378

∆%

 

4.9

4.2

Feb

-45,718

165,727

211,444

∆%

 

-1.3

-1.9

Jan

-47,858

167,849

215,707

∆%

 

2.3

5.5

Dec 2010

-40,454

164,006

204,459

Jan-Aug
2011

-376,199

1,386,617

1,762,816

Jan-Aug
2010

-337,265

1,197,178

1,534,443

Note: Trade Balance of Goods and Services = Exports of Goods and Services less Imports of Goods and Services. Trade balance may not add exactly because of errors of rounding.

Source: http://www.census.gov/foreign-trade/Press-Release/current_press_release/ft900.pdf

Chart 26 of the US Bureau of the Census of the Department of Commerce shows that the trade deficit fell during the economic contraction after 2007 but has grown again during the expansion. There has been a slight improvement in the margin in Jul and Aug.

clip_image052

Chart 26, US Balance, Exports and Imports of Goods and Services $ Billions

Source: US Census Bureau

http://www.census.gov/briefrm/esbr/www/esbr042.html

The balance of international trade in goods of the US seasonally-adjusted is shown in Table 29. The US has a dynamic surplus in services that reduces the large deficit in goods for a still very sizeable deficit in international trade of goods and services. The balance in international trade of goods deteriorated sharply from Jan-Aug 2010 to Jan-Aug 2011. Deterioration occurred both in the petroleum balance, exports less imports of petroleum, as well as in the non-petroleum balance, exports less imports of non-petroleum goods. Exports rose 18.0 percent with non-petroleum exports growing by 15.1 percent. Total imports rose by 17.0 percent with petroleum imports increasing by 30.5 percent and non-petroleum imports by 13.9 percent.

Table 29, US, International Trade in Goods Balance, Exports and Imports $ Millions and ∆% SA

 

Jan-Aug 2011

Jan-Aug 2010

∆%

Total Balance

-495,350

-430,134

 

Petroleum

-220,156

-179,038

 

Non Petroleum

-268,476

-244,444

 

Total Exports

988,115

837,284

18.0

Petroleum

71,808

44,620

60.9

Non Petroleum

904,341

785,467

15.1

Total Imports

1,483,465

1,267,419

17.0

Petroleum

291,964

223,657

30.5

Non Petroleum

1,172,817

1,029,911

13.9

Details may not add because of rounding and seasonal adjustment

Source: http://www.census.gov/foreign-trade/Press-Release/current_press_release/ft900.pdf

US exports and imports of goods not seasonally adjusted in Jan-Aug 2010 and Jan-Aug 2011 are shown in Table 30. The rate of growth of exports was 18.1 percent, which is slightly higher than 17.2 percent for imports. The US has partial hedge of commodity price increases in exports of agricultural commodities that rose 29.4 percent and of mineral fuels that increased 61.4 percent both because of higher prices of raw materials and commodities. The US exports an insignificant amount of crude oil. US exports and imports consist mostly of manufactured products, with less rapidly increasing prices. US manufactured exports rose only 11.7 percent while imports rose 14.2 percent. Significant part of the US trade imbalance originates in mineral fuels growing by 27.9 percent and crude oil increasing by 28.3 percent. The limited hedge in exports of agricultural commodities and mineral fuels compared with substantial imports of mineral fuels and crude oil results in deterioration of the terms of trade of the US, export prices relative to import prices, originating in commodity price increases caused by carry trades from zero interest rates.

Table 30, US, Exports and Imports of Goods, Not Seasonally Adjusted Millions of Dollars and %

 

Jan- Aug
2011 $
Millions

Jan-Aug 2010 $ Millions

∆%

Exports

980,945

830,112

18.1

Manu-
factured

636,609

569,997

11.7

Agricultural
Commodities

90,224

69,720

29.4

Mineral Fuels

81,586

50,549

61.4

Crude Oil

879

1,088

-19.2

Imports

1,470,328

1,254,508

17.2

Manu-
factured

1,049,374

921,912

13.8

Agricultural
Commodities

65,873

54,366

21.2

Mineral Fuels

307,769

240,450

27.9

Crude Oil

225,115

175,395

28.3

Source: http://www.census.gov/foreign-trade/Press-Release/current_press_release/ft900.pdf

Prices of US imports rose 13.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Sep 2011, as shown in Table 31, but increased only at the annual equivalent rate of 0.8 percent in the quarter Jul-Sep. At the margin, overall import price inflation is at a low annual equivalent rate. An important determinant of lower inflation is fuels and lubricants with share of 26.8 percent in total imports but falling at the annual equivalent rate of 4.7 percent in Jul-Sep 2011 in contrast with increase of 43.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Sep 2011. Inflation appears to have spread throughout the production chain. The index of all imports ex fuels with weight of 73.2 percent rose 5.5 percent in 12 months and 2.4 percent in annual equivalent in the quarter Jul-Sep 2011. The index of prices of consumer goods ex automotive rose 3.7 percent in the quarter Jul-Sep but only 2.4 percent in 12 months. Exports rose 2.4 percent in annual equivalent in the quarter Jul-Sep and 9.5 percent in 12 months. Agricultural exports, which are the US hedge against commodity price increases, rose 22.9 percent in 12 months but fell at the annual equivalent rate of 1.7 percent in the quarter Jul-Sep 2011. Agricultural exports are an imperfect hedge with share of only 11.4 percent in total exports. Industrial supplies and material rose a vigorous 3.7 percent in the Jul-Sep quarter and 18.9 percent in 12 months. Consumer goods ex autos rose 4.5 percent in the quarter Jul-Sep and 5.1 percent in 12 months.

Table 31, US, Prices of Exports and Imports 12 Months Growth and Annual Equivalent %

 

12 Month  ∆% Sep 2011

Annual ∆%Equivalent Jul-Sep 2011

% Total

Imports

13.4

0.8

100.0

Fuels & Lubricants

43.4

-4.7

26.8

All Imports ex Fuels

5.5

2.4

73.2

Capital Goods

1.3

1.2

20.8

Automotive vehicles, parts & engines

3.7

0.0

9.2

Consumer Goods
Ex Automotive

2.4

3.7

24.2

Nondurable
Manufactured

2.5

4.1

11.9

Durables Manufactured

1.4

1.6

11.3

Non-Manufactured
Consumer Goods

11.5

10.8

1.0

Exports

9.5

2.4

100.0

Agricultural

22.9

-1.7

11.4

Non-Agricultural

8.1

3.3

88.4

Industrial Supplies and Materials

18.9

3.7

35.2

Capital Goods

1.0

-0.4

34.2

Automotive vehicles, parts & engines

2.5

4.5

6.7

Consumer Goods Excluding Autos

5.1

4.5

13.4

Nondurable Manufactured

1.6

2.0

6.7

Durables Manufactured

3.5

3.7

5.3

Source: http://www.bls.gov/news.release/pdf/ximpim.pdf

Chart 27 provides US prices of total US imports 2001-2011. Prices fell during the contraction of 2001. Import price inflation accelerated after unconventional monetary policy of near zero interest rates in 2003-2004 and quantitative easing by withdrawing supply with the suspension of 30-Treasury auctions. Slow pace of adjusting fed funds rates from 1 percent by 25 basis points increments in 17 consecutive meetings of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) between Jun 2004 and Jun 2006 continued to give impetus to carry trades. The reduction of fed funds rates toward zero in 2008 fueled a spectacular hunt for yields that caused commodity price inflation in the middle of a global recession. After risk aversion in 2009 because of the announcement of TARP (Troubled Asset Relief Program) creating anxiety on “toxic assets” in bank balance sheets (see Cochrane and Zingales 2009), prices collapsed. Renewed price increases returned with zero interest rates and quantitative easing. Monetary policy impulses in massive doses have driven inflation and valuation of risk financial assets in wild fluctuations over a decade. 

clip_image054

Chart 27, US, Prices of Total US Imports 2001-2011

Source: http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm

Chart 28 provides the index of US export prices. There is not much difference in the Chart 27 and Chart 28. Import and export prices have driven by impulses of unconventional monetary policy in massive doses.

clip_image056

Chart 28, US, Prices of Total US Exports 2001-2011

Source: http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm

Twelve months percentage rates of change of US prices of exports and imports are provided in Table 32. Import prices have been driven since 2003 by unconventional monetary policy of near zero interest rates influencing commodity prices according to moods of risk aversion. In a global recession without risk aversion until Sep, import prices rose 13.1 percent in 2008 and fell 12.0 percent when risk aversion developed until mid 2009. Import prices rose again sharply in 2011 until May in the presence of zero interest rates with relaxed mood of risk aversion. There is similar behavior of prices of imports ex fuels and export ex agricultural goods.

Table, 32, US, Twelve Months Percentage Rates of Change of Prices of Exports and Imports

 

Imports

Imports Ex Fuels

Exports

Exports Non-Ag

Sep 2011

13.4

5.5

9.5

8.0

Sep 2010

3.6

2.5

4.9

4.3

Sep 2009

-12.0

-4.2

-5.6

-4.4

Sep 2008

13.1

6.1

7.0

5.8

Aug 2007

4.8

2.1

4.5

2.9

Sep 2006

1.6

2.9

3.9

3.8

Sep 2005

9.9

1.4

3.6

3.6

Sep 2004

8.2

2.8

4.0

4.3

Sep 2003

0.7

0.5

1.0

0.6

Sep 2002

-0.4

NA

-0.2

-0.6

Sep 2001

-5.6

NA

-1.4

-2.2

Source: http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm#

Chart 29 shows the US monthly import price index of all commodities excluding fuels from 2010 to 2011. All curves of nominal values follow the same behavior under the influence of unconventional monetary policy. Zero interest rates without risk aversion result in jumps of nominal values and zero interest rates with strong risk aversion result in declines of nominal values.

clip_image058

Chart 29, US, Import Price Index All Commodities Excluding Fuels, 2001=100

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

Chart 30 provides the monthly US import price index ex petroleum from 2001 to 2011. Prices including or excluding commodities follow the same fluctuations and trends originating in impulses of unconventional monetary policy of zero interest rates.

clip_image060

Chart 30, US, Import Price Index ex Petroleum, 2001=100

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm

Chart 31 of the US Energy Information Administration provides the futures prices of crude oil. Future prices were driven by unconventional monetary policy diverting carry trade toward risk financial assets such as commodity futures.

clip_image045[1]

Chart 31, Daily Crude Oil Cushing OK Future Contract  1

Source: US Energy Information Administration

http://www.eia.gov/dnav/pet/hist/LeafHandler.ashx?n=PET&s=WCESTUS1&f=W

The price index of US imports of petroleum and petroleum products in shown in Chart 32. There is similar behavior of the curves all driven by the same impulses of monetary policy.

clip_image062

Chart 32, US, Import Price Index of Petroleum and Petroleum Products, 2011=100

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm

The US exports price index of agricultural commodities is in Chart 33. There are similar fluctuations and trends as in all other price index originating in unconventional monetary policy repeated over a decade.

clip_image064

Chart 33, US, Exports Price Index of Agricultural Commodities, 2001=100

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm

The final Chart 34 shows the export price index of nonagricultural commodities. Unconventional monetary policy of zero interest rates drove price behavior during the past decade. Policy has been based on the myth of stimulating the economy by climbing the negatively slope of an imaginary short-term Phillips curve.

clip_image066

Chart 34, US, Exports Price Index of Nonagricultural Commodities, 2001=100

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics

http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm

Growth of sales of manufacturers, retailers and merchant wholesalers are provided in Table 33. Total business sales rose 0.3 percent in Aug after 0.7 percent in Jul and were up by 13.7 percent in Aug 2011 relative to Aug 2010. Sales of manufacturers fell 0.2 percent in Aug but after strong growth of 1.2 percent in Jul and rose 13.4 percent in the 12 months to Aug. Retailers experienced growth of 0.3 percent in sales in Aug and 9.3 in 12 months. Sales of merchant wholesalers rose 1.0 percent in Aug and a strong 18.2 percent in 12 months. These data are not adjusted for price changes such that they reflect increases in both quantities and prices.

Table 33, US, Percentage Changes for Sales of Manufacturers, Retailers and Merchant Wholesalers

 

Aug 11/   Jul 11
∆% SA

Jul 11/  
Jun 11
∆% SA

Aug 11/  
Aug 10
∆% NSA

Total Business

0.3

0.7

13.7

Manu-
facturers

-0.2

1.2

13.4

Retailers

0.3

0.5

9.3

Merchant Whole-
salers

1.0

0.3

18.2

Source: http://www.census.gov/mtis/www/data/pdf/mtis_current.pdf

Businesses added to inventories to replenish stocks in an environment of strong sales. Retailers added 0.8 percent to inventories in Aug with growth of 4.1 percent in 12 months, as shown in Table 34. Total business increased inventories by 0.5 percent in both Aug and Jul and 10.4 percent in 12 months. Inventories sales/ratios of business continued at a level close to 1.28 under judicious management to avoid costs. 

Table 34, US, Percentage Changes for Inventories of Manufacturers, Retailers and Merchant Wholesalers and Inventory/Sales Ratios

Inventory Change

Aug 11/   
Jul 11
∆% SA

Jul 11/  
Jun 11
∆% SA

Aug 11/  
Aug 10
∆% NSA

Total Business

0.5

0.5

10.4

Manu-
facturers

0.4

0.6

13.0

Retailers

0.8

0.1

4.1

Merchant
Wholesalers

0.4

0.8

14.0

Inventory/
Sales Ratio NSA

Aug 2011

Jul 2011

Aug 2010

Total Business

1.28

1.28

1.29

Manu-
facturers

1.34

1.33

1.33

Retailers

1.34

1.34

1.39

Merchant Wholesalers

1.17

1.16

1.17

Source: http://www.census.gov/mtis/www/data/pdf/mtis_current.pdf

Inventories follow business cycles. When recession hits sales inventories pile up, declining with expansion of the economy. In a fascinating classic opus, Lloyd Meltzer (1941, 129) concludes:

“The dynamic sequences (I) through (6) were intended to show what types of behavior are possible for a system containing a sales output lag. The following conclusions seem to be the most important:

(i) An economy in which business men attempt to recoup inventory losses will always undergo cyclical fluctuations when equilibrium is disturbed, provided the economy is stable.

This is the pure inventory cycle.

(2) The assumption of stability imposes severe limitations upon the possible size of the marginal propensity to consume, particularly if the coefficient of expectation is positive.

(3) The inventory accelerator is a more powerful de-stabilizer than the ordinary acceleration principle. The difference' in stability conditions is due to the fact that the former allows for replacement demand whereas the usual analytical formulation of the latter does not. Thus, for inventories, replacement demand acts as a de-stabilizer. Whether it does so for all types of capital goods is a moot question, but I believe cases may occur in which it does not.

(4) Investment for inventory purposes cannot alter the equilibrium of income, which depends only upon the propensity to consume and the amount of non-induced investment.

(5) The apparent instability of a system containing both an accelerator and a coefficient of expectation makes further investigation of possible stabilizers highly desirable.”

Chart 35 shows the increase in the inventory/sales ratios during the recessions of 2001 and 2007-2009. The inventory/sales ratio fell during the expansions.

clip_image067

Chart 35, Total Business Inventories/Sales Ratios 2002 to 2011

Source: US Census Bureau

http://www2.census.gov/retail/releases/historical/mtis/img/mtisbrf.gif

Markets responded positively to the announcement of growth of sales of retail and food services by 1.1 percent in Sep, shown in Table 35. Sales of motor vehicles and parts rose 3.5 percent in Sep and 10.4 percent in 12 months and 0.6 per cent ex motor vehicles and parts. Gasoline station sales rose 1.2 percent in fluctuating prices of gasoline.

Table 35, US, Percentage Change in Monthly Sales for Retail and Food Services, ∆%

 

Sep/Aug ∆% SA

Aug/Jul ∆% SA

12 Months Jan to Sep 2011 to Jan to Sep 2010 ∆% NSA

Retail and Food Services

1.1

0.3

8.1

Excluding Motor Vehicles and Parts

0.6

0.5

7.6

Motor Vehicles & Parts

3.6

-0.8

10.4

Retail

1.1

0.3

8.4

Building Materials

-0.1

1.2

5.8

Food and Beverage

-0.2

0.4

5.6

Grocery

-0.3

0.4

5.8

Health & Personal Care Stores

0.3

0.6

5.2

Clothing & Clothing Accessories Stores

1.3

-0.4

5.9

Gasoline Stations

1.2

0.8

19.5

Source: http://www.census.gov/retail/marts/www/marts_current.pdf

Chart 36 of the US Bureau of the Census shows percentage change of retails and food services sales. Sep was strong in multiple categories.

Chart 36, US, Advance Monthly Retail Sales Report

clip_image068

Source: http://www.census.gov/retail/marts/www/marts_current.pdf

Twelve months rates of growth of US sales of retail and food services in Sep from 2001 to 2011 are shown in Table 36. Nominal sales have been dynamic in 2011 and 2010 after declines in 2009 and 2008.

Table 36, US, Percentage Change in 12 Months Sales for Retail and Food Services, ∆% NSA

Sep

12 Months ∆%

2011

8.6

2010

7.6

2009

-7.2

2008

-0.8

2007

2.3

2006

3.9

2005

6.3

2004

6.7

2003

7.5

2002

4.3

2001

-2.6

2000

5.9

Source: http://www.census.gov/retail/

Treasury reported a budget deficit of $1,298,614 million in the fiscal year of 2011. This is the second highest deficit since World War II. Individual income taxes grew 21.5 percent from 2010 to 2011.

Table 37, US, Treasury Budget in Fiscal Year to Date Million Dollars

 

Sep 2011

Sep 2010

∆%

Receipts

2,302,495

2,161,728

6.5

Outlays

3,601,109

3,455,931

4.2

Deficit

-1,298,614

-1,294,204

NA

Individual Income Taxes

1,091,473

898,549

21.5

Source: http://www.fms.treas.gov/mts/mts0911.pdf

An important characteristic of US Treasury debt is the large holdings by foreign countries, shown in Table 38. The US is heavily dependent on foreign savings to finance its balance of payments and fiscal deficits. 

Table 38, US, Major Foreign Holders of Treasury Securities $ Billions at End of Period

 

Jul 2011

Jun 2011

Dec 2010

China

1173.5

1165.5

1160.1

Japan

914.8

911.0

882.3

United Kingdom

352.5

347.8

270.4

Oil Exporters

234.3

229.6

211.9

Brazil

210.0

207.1

186.1

Taiwan

154.3

153.4

155.1

Caribbean Banking Centers

124.5

141.7

168.4

Hong Kong

111.9

118.4

134.2

Switzerland

108.4

108.0

106.8

Russia

100.2

109.8

151.0

Source: http://www.treasury.gov/resource-center/data-chart-center/tic/Documents/mfh.txt

IVB Japan. The strong yen and weak world economic growth are beginning to affect manufacturing in Japan. The Markit/JMMA Purchasing Managers’ Index for Sep, released on Sep 30, registered a decline from 51.9 in Aug to 49.3 in Sep, which indicates that the manufacturing sector deteriorates but only marginally (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=8595). The marginal contraction interrupts V-shaped recovery from the Tōhoku or Great East Earthquake and Tsunami of Mar 11, 2011. For the first time in four months, incoming new business contracted. Weaker demand from China partially explains the fall in demand for new export orders. The survey finds sharp increases in input prices for raw materials and fuels but falling prices for manufacturers’ finished goods. Composite data in the Markit Japan Services PMI shows falling output in the private sector of the Japanese economy in Sep for a seventh consecutive month. Confidence in the service sector fell to the lowest in five months. Companies were forced to reduce their sales prices because of intensive competition. The composite index remained below 50 for the seventh consecutive month, indicating strong reduction in activity of the private sector. Alex Hamilton, economist at Markit, finds that the combination of falling manufacturing production for the first time in five months together with contraction of services indicates contraction of the private sector of the Japanese economy.

Table JPY provides the country data table for Japan followed with indicators released in the week of Oct 14.

Table JPY, Japan, Economic Indicators

Historical GDP and CPI

1981-2010 Real GDP Growth and CPI Inflation 1981-2010
Blog 07/31/11

Corporate Goods Prices

Sep ∆% -0.2
12 months ∆% 2.5
Blog 10/16/11

Consumer Price Index

Jul SA ∆% 0.0
Jul 12 months NSA ∆% 0.2
Blog 08/28/11

Real GDP Growth

IIQ2011 ∆%: –0.5 on IQ2011; 
∆% from quarter a year earlier: –1.1%
Blog 09/11/11

Employment Report

Aug Unemployed 2.76 million

Change in unemployed since last year: minus 450 thousand
Unemployment rate: 4.4%
Blog 10/02/11

All Industry Index

Jul month SA ∆% 0.4
12 months NSA ∆% minus 0.8 Blog 09/25/11

Industrial Production

Aug SA month ∆%: 0.8
12 months NSA ∆% 0.6
Blog 10/02/11

Machine Orders

Total Aug ∆% 6.5

Private Aug ∆%: -3.6
Aug ∆% Excluding Volatile Orders -3.6
Blog 10/16/2011

Tertiary Index

Aug month SA ∆% -0.2
Aug 12 months NSA ∆% 0.2
Blog 10/16/2011

Wholesale and Retail Sales

Aug 12 months:
Total ∆%: 3.3
Wholesale ∆%: 5.6
Retail ∆%: -2.6
Blog 10/02/11

Family Income and Expenditure Survey

Aug 12 months ∆% total nominal consumption minus 3.9, real minus 4.1 Blog 10/02/11

Trade Balance

Exports Aug 12 months ∆%: 2.8 Imports Aug 12 months ∆% 19.2 Blog 09/25/11

Links to blog comments in Table JPY:

10/09/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/10/twenty-nine-million-unemployedunderempl.html

10/02/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/10/us-growth-standstill-at-08-percent.html

09/25/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/imf-view-of-world-economy-and-finance.html

09/25/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/collapse-of-household-income-and-wealth.html

09/11/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/financial-turbulence-wriston-doctrine.html

09/04/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/global-growth-standstill-recession.html

08/28/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/08/united-states-gdp-growth-standstill.html

07/31/11: http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/07/growth-recession-debt-financial-risk.html

Japan’s machinery orders in Table 39 enjoyed a good month in Aug. Total orders rose 6.5 percent. Private-sector orders excluding volatile orders, which are closely watched, rose 11.0 percent. Orders for manufacturing increased 5.5 percent and overseas orders rose 32.3 percent.

Table 39, Japan, Machinery Orders, Month ∆%

 

Aug

Jul

Jun

May

Total

6.5

-11.3

5.6

-2.3

Private Sector

-3.6

-15.9

19.4

4.9

Excluding Volatile Orders

11.0

-8.2

7.7

3.0

Mfg

13.7

-5.2

9.3

-1.4

Non
Mfg

-6.1

-1.4

15.7

-5.4

Gvt

-5.5

-1.7

-3.2

10.7

From Overseas

32.3

-9.8

-5.9

-6.6

Through Agencies

-0.2

-1.5

-6.6

-22.4

Note: Mfg: manufacturing; Gvt: government

Source: http://www.esri.cao.go.jp/en/stat/juchu/1108juchu-e.html

Total orders for machinery and total private-sector orders excluding volatile orders for Japan are shown in Chart 37 of Japan’s Economic and Social Research Institute at the Cabinet Office. The trend of private-sector orders excluding volatile orders is increasing smoothly. There could be reversal of the trend of decline in total orders.

clip_image069

Chart 37, Japan, Machinery Orders

Source: Japan Economic and Social Research Institute, Cabinet Office

http://www.esri.cao.go.jp/en/stat/juchu/1108juchu-e.html

The value of machinery orders in Japan in Aug 2011 expressed in million yen and the 12 months rates of growth in Aug 2011 and in Dec for the years from 2006 to 2010 are provided in Table 40. The important segment of private-sector orders excluding volatile orders grew at 2.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Aug 2011. Machinery orders for Japan fell 25.6 percent in 2008. Overseas orders fell 28.2 percent in 2008 but rose 10.8 percent in the 12 months ending in Aug 2011.

Table 40, Japan, Machinery Orders, 12 Months ∆% and Million Yen

 

Total

Overseas

Domestic

Private ex Volatile

Value Aug 2011

1,983,385

933,877

1,165,961

804,877

% Total

100.0

47.1

58.8

40.6

Aug 2011

-3.6

10.8

-11.7

2.2

Dec 2010

9.0

3.5

13.6

-0.4

Dec 2009

1.7

1.8

2.6

-1.2

Dec 2008

-25.6

-28.2

-18.1

-24.2

Dec 2007

4.5

12.6

-4.9

-6.0

Dec 2006

-2.7

1.1

-0.4

0.1

Note: Value in first row does not add to the other columns

Source: http://www.esri.cao.go.jp/en/stat/juchu/1108juchu-e.html

The tertiary activity index of Japan fell 0.2 percent in Aug but rose 0.2 percent in 12 months, as shown in Table 41. There was strong impact from the Tōhoku or Great East Earthquake and Tsunami of Mar 11, 2011 in the decline of the tertiary activity index by 5.9 percent in Mar and 3.1 percent in 12 months. Monthly rates in Aug and Jul have been negative by 0.2 percent and 0.2 percent respectively.

Table 41, Japan, Tertiary Activity Index  ∆%

 

Month ∆% SA

12 Months ∆% NSA

Aug 2011

-0.2

0.2

Jul

-0.3

-0.3

Jun

1.9

0.9

May

0.9

-0.2

Apr

2.7

-2.3

Mar

-5.9

-3.1

Feb

0.8

2.0

Jan

-0.1

1.1

Dec 2010

-0.2

1.8

Nov

0.6

2.5

Oct

0.2

0.5

Sep

-0.4

1.3

Aug

0.1

2.3

Jul

0.7

1.6

Jun

0.1

1.0

May

-0.3

1.2

Source: http://www.meti.go.jp/statistics/tyo/sanzi/result/pdf/hv37903_201108j.pdf

Month and 12 months rates of growth of the tertiary activity index of Japan and components in Aug are provided in Table 42. Electricity, gas and water fell 9.2 percent in 12 months and 1.1 percent in Aug. There is weakness in the index and in components.

Table 42, Japan, Tertiary Index and Components, Month and 12 Months Rates of Change ∆%

Aug 2011

12 Months ∆%

Month ∆%

Tertiary Index

0.2

-0.2

Electricity, Gas, & Water

-9.3

-1.1

Information & Communications

-0.8

-0.1

Wholesale & Retail Trade

1.4

-1.1

Finance & Insurance

1.2

-1.8

Real Estate & Goods Rental & Leasing

-1.4

0.1

Scientific Research, Professional & Technical Services

2.2

-0.3

Accommodations, Eating, Drinking

-1.1

0.2

Living-Related, Personal, Amusement Services

-2.7

1.6

Learning Support

-2.3

0.3

Medical, Health Care, Welfare

3.8

0.1

Miscellaneous ex Government

3.1

0.4

Source:  http://www.meti.go.jp/statistics/tyo/sanzi/result/pdf/hv37903_201108j.pdf

IVC China. The seasonally-adjusted HSBC Purchasing Managers’ Index compiled by Markit was unchanged at 49.9 in Sep, indicating marginal deterioration of overall manufacturing in China (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=8596). The quarterly average of the index is the lowest since IQ2009. Hongbin Qu, Chief Economist, China & Co-head of Asian Economic Research at HSBC does not find that the data suggest sharp slowing of manufacturing and that the results of the survey indicate continuing economic growth at 8.5 percent to 9 percent in the future years. The composite output index of manufacturing and services of the HSBC China Services PMI compiled by Markit rose to 51.5 in Sep, moving away from near stagnation in Aug (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=8635). The index is below the long-run average of the series of 54.6 and its level is the lowest since IQ2009. The improvement was caused by an increase in the activity of the services sector with the index climbing to 53.0 in Sep from 50.6 in Aug. Performance is still substandard relative to historical data. Inflation of input prices registered the highest in four months. Table CNY provides the country data table for China.

Table CNY, China, Economic Indicators

Price Indexes for Industry

Sep 12 months ∆%: 6.5
Jan-Sep ∆%: 7.0

Sep month ∆%: 0.0
Blog 10/16/11

Consumer Price Index

Sep month ∆%: 0.5
Sep 12 month ∆%: 6.1
Jan-Sep ∆%: 5.7
Blog 10/16/11

Value Added of Industry

Aug 12 month ∆%: 13.5

Jan-Aug 2011/Jan-Aug 2010 ∆%: 14.2
Blog 09/11/11

GDP Growth Rate

Year IIQ2011 ∆%: 9.6
Quarter IIQ2011 ∆%: 2.2
Blog 08/14/11

Investment in Fixed Assets

Total Jan-Aug ∆%: 25.0

Jan-Aug ∆% real estate development: 33.2
Blog 09/11/11

Retail Sales

Aug month ∆%: 1.4
Aug 12 month ∆%: 17.0

Jan-Aug ∆%: 16.9
Blog 09/11/11

Trade Balance

Sep balance $14.51 billion
Exports ∆% 17.1
Imports ∆% 30.9
Blog 10/16/11

Links to blog comments in Table CNY:

10/09/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/10/twenty-nine-million-unemployedunderempl.html

09/11/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/financial-turbulence-wriston-doctrine.html

09/04/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/global-growth-standstill-recession.html

08/14/11 (08/9): http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/08/turbulence-in-world-financial-markets.html

China’s exports and imports and their 12 months rates of growth together with the trade balance in Sep are shown in Table 43. The 12 months rate of growth of exports fell from 24.5 percent in Aug to 17.1 percent in Sep and the 12 months rates of growth of imports fell from 30.2 percent in Aug to 20.9 percent in Sep. Growth is still extremely high and in comparison with trade data for other countries. The Dow Jones Newswires informs on Oct 15 that the premier of China Wen Jiabao announced that the Chinese yuan will not be further appreciated to prevent adverse effects on exports (http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052970203914304576632790881396896.html?mod=WSJ_hp_LEFTWhatsNewsCollection). It is difficult to separate various possibilities from the Senate bill designed to curb imports from China in the US such as weakening international trade.

Table 43, China, Exports, Imports and Trade Balance USD Billion and ∆%

 

Exports
USD
Billion

∆% Relative
Year Earlier

Imports USD
Billion

∆% Relative
Year Earlier

Balance
USD
Billion

Sep 2011

169.67

17.1

155.16

20.9

14.51

Aug

173.31

24.5

155.56

30.2

17.75

Jul

175.13

20.4

143.64

22.9

31.49

Jun

161.98

17.9

139.71

19.3

22.27

May

157.16

19.4

144.11

28.4

13.05

Apr

155.69

29.9

144.26

21.8

11.43

Mar

152.2

35.8

152.06

27.3

0.14

Feb

96.74

2.4

104.04

19.4

-7.3

Jan

150.73

37.7

144.27

51.0

6.46

Dec 2010

154.15

17.9

141.07

25.6

13.08

Source: http://english.customs.gov.cn/publish/portal191/

http://english.mofcom.gov.cn/static/column/statistic/BriefStatistics.html/1

Table 44 provides China’s cumulative exports and imports and their yearly growth rates together with the trade balance. China is still enjoying strong trade growth.

Table 44, China, Year to Date Exports, Imports and Trade Balance USD Billion and ∆%

 

Exports
USD
Billion

∆% Relative
Year Earlier

Imports USD
Billion

∆% Relative
Year Earlier

Balance
USD
Billion

Sep 2011

1,391.7

22.7

1,285.2

26.8

107.1

Aug

1,222

23.6

1,130

27.5

92.7

Jul

1,049.4

23.4

973.2

26.9

76.2

Jun

874.3

24.0

829.4

27.6

44.9

May

712.4

25.5

689.4

29.4

23.0

Apr

555.3

27.4

545.0

29.6

10.3

Mar

399.6

26.5

400.7

32.6

-1.1

Feb

247.47

21.3

248.36

36.0

-0.9

Jan

150.7

37.7

144.3

51.0

6.4

Dec 2010

1577.9

31.3

1394.8

38.7

183.1

Source: http://english.mofcom.gov.cn/static/column/statistic/BriefStatistics.html/1

IVD Euro Area. The Markit Eurozone Manufacturing PMI® registered the weakest reading in 24 months of 48.5 in Sep (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=8611). New orders fell at the highest rate in more than two years. The indexes for Italy (48.3), France (48.2), Ireland (47.3) and Spain (43.7) are the lows in 24 to 26 months while that of Greece (43.2) fell to a 7-month low. Chris Williamson, Chief Economist at Markit, finds that manufacturers face the weakest business environment in more than two years because of the joint occurrence of mediocre internal demand and declining export demand. The prospects are for further drop in production in coming months because of the acceleration of decline of new orders. The Markit Eurozone PMI® Composite Output Index fell to 49.1 in Sep from 50.7 in Aug for the first decline in private sector activity in the euro area since Jul 2009 (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=8613). The index average for IIIQ2011 registered 50.3, indicating stagnation of private-sector activity, falling below 55.6 in IIQ2011 and 57.6 in IQ2011. Chris Williamson, Chief Economist at Markit finds that the PMI reading for Sep shows the euro zone economy at standstill. The contraction of output in Sep suggests stagnation for the entire third quarter. The sharp decline in new business indicates possible contraction of GDP in the final quarter of 2011 (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=8613). Table EUR provides the data table for the euro zone.

Table EUR, Euro Area Economic Indicators

GDP

IIQ2011 ∆% 0.2; IIQ2011/IIQ2010 ∆% 1.6 Blog 09/11/11

Unemployment 

Aug 2011: 10.0% unemployment rate

Aug 2011: 15.739 million unemployed

Blog 10/02/11

HICP

Sep month ∆%: 0.8

12 months Sep ∆%: 3.0
Blog 010/16/11

Producer Prices

Euro Zone industrial producer prices 
Aug 12 months ∆%: 5.9
Blog 10/09/11

Industrial Production

Aug month ∆%: 1.2
Aug 12 months ∆%: 5.3
Blog 10/16/11

Industrial New Orders

Jul month ∆%: minus 2.1 Jul 12 months ∆%: 8.5
Blog 09/25/11

Construction Output

Jul month ∆%: 1.4
Jul 12 months ∆%: 1.2
Blog 09/25/11

Retail Sales

Aug month ∆%: minus 0.3
Aug 12 months ∆%: minus 1.0
Blog 10/09/11

Confidence and Economic Sentiment Indicator

Sentiment 95.0 Sep 2011 down from 107 in Dec 2010

Confidence minus 19.1 Sep 2011 down from minus 11 in Dec 2010

Blog 10/02/11

Trade

Jan-Aug 2011/2010 Exports ∆%: 15.2
Imports ∆%: 15.8
Blog 10/16/11

HICP, Rate of Unemployment and GDP

Historical from 1999 to 2011 Blog 09/04/11

Links to blog comments in Table EUR:

10/09/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/10/twenty-nine-million-unemployedunderempl.html

10/02/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/10/us-growth-standstill-at-08-percent.html

09/25/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/imf-view-of-world-economy-and-finance.html

09/18/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/collapse-of-household-income-and-wealth.html

09/11/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/financial-turbulence-wriston-doctrine.html

09/04/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/global-growth-standstill-recession.html

After weakness from Mar to Jun, euro zone industrial production rebounded with growth of 1.2 percent in Aug after 1.1 percent in Jul, as shown in Table 45. Capital goods surged by 3.2 percent in Jul and 2.1 in Aug after much weaker performance in Mar to Jun.

Table 45, Euro Zone, Industrial Production Month ∆%

2011

Aug

Jul

Jun

May

Apr

Mar

Feb

Jan

Total

1.2

1.1

-0.6

0.2

0.4

0.0

0.5

0.1

Inter-mediate

1.7

0.7

-0.6

0.1

0.1

0.0

0.5

2.3

Energy

0.0

0.1

1.1

0.3

-3.7

-0.3

-1.3

-4.7

Capital
Goods

2.1

3.2

-1.4

1.2

0.9

-0.6

2.2

-1.8

Durable

0.0

3.7

-2.4

-0.5

1.1

0.0

0.9

1.1

Non
Durable

1.1

-0.7

-0.6

-0.1

0.4

0.4

0.9

-0.1

Source: http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/cache/ITY_PUBLIC/4-12102011-AP/EN/4-12102011-AP-EN.PDF

Table 46 provides 12 months rate of growth of industrial production in the euro zone. Rates fell to lower levels of 4.3 percent in May and Jun but rose to 5.3 in the 12 months ending in Aug.

Table 46, Euro Zone, Industrial Production 12 Months ∆%

2011

Aug

Jul

Jun

May

Apr

Mar

Feb

Jan

Total

5.3

4.4

2.8

4.3

5.4

5.7

7.8

6.2

Inter-mediate

5.3

4.2

3.1

4.5

5.4

7.5

10.0

9.5

Energy

-3.5

-4.2

-3.6

-7.2

-5.3

-2.1

-2.8

-1.9

Capital
Goods

12.2

11.9

6.8

10.7

10.7

11.5

15.1

13.0

Durable

2.8

4.3

-2.4

1.3

4.9

2.5

3.5

2.0

Non
Durable

1.9

-0.7

1.0

2.7

3.7

0.7

2.6

0.5

Source: http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/cache/ITY_PUBLIC/4-12082011-AP/EN/4-12082011-AP-EN.PDF

Euro zone trade growth continues to be strong as shown in Table 47. Exports grew at 15.2 percent and imports at 15.8 percent in the first eight months of 2011 relative to 2010. The 12 months rates of growth of exports were 14.3 percent in Aug and 11.3 percent for imports.

Table 47, Euro Zone, Exports, Imports and Trade Balance, Billions of Euros and Percent, NSA

 

Exports

Imports

Jan-Aug 2011

1130.9

1154.8

Jan-Aug 2010

981.8

997.0

∆%

15.2

15.8

Aug 2011

137.8

141.2

Aug 2010

120.6

126.9

∆%

14.3

11.3

Trade Balance

Jan-Aug 2011

Jan-Aug 2010

€ Billions

-23.9

-15.3

Source: http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/cache/ITY_PUBLIC/6-14102011-AP/EN/6-14102011-AP-EN.PDF

The structure of trade of the euro zone in Jan-Jul is provided in Table 48. Data are still not available for trade structure for Aug. Manufactured exports grew 13.9 percent in Jan-Jul 2011 relative to Jan-Jul 2010 while imports grew 12.3 percent.

Table 48, Euro Zone, Structure of Exports, Imports and Trade Balance, € Billions, ∆%

 

Primary

Manu-
factured

Other

Total

Exports

       

Jan-Jul 2011 € B

149.6

817.0

26.5

993.1

Jan-Jul 2010 € B

119.1

717.3

24.8

861.2

∆%

25.6

13.9

6.9

15.3

Imports Jan-Jul 2011 € B

354.8

642.9

15.8

1013.6

Imports Jan-Jul 2010  € B

280.3

572.6

17.3

870.2

∆%

26.6

12.3

-8.7

16.5

Trade Balance Jan-Jul 2011

-205.2

174.2.0

10.6

-20.4

Trade Balance Jan-Jul 2010

-161.2

144.7

7.5

-9.0

Source: http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/cache/ITY_PUBLIC/6-14102011-AP/EN/6-14102011-AP-EN.PDF

IVE Germany. The Markit/BME Germany Manufacturing PMI® registered the lowest reading in two years at 50.3 in Sep, which is slightly lower than 50.9 in Aug (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=8632). Tim Moore, Senior Economist at Markit, finds that manufacturing recovery in Germany is at standstill. There is support for the observation that growth may have peaked early in 2011 with weak prospects for the coming months because of the decline of new orders at the highest rate since the middle of 2009 particularly accentuated by weak export demand. The Germany Composite Output Index of the Markit Germany Services PMI® fell from 51.3 in Aug to 50.5 in Sep. Manufacturing supported the composite index as the Germany Services Business Activity index fell from 51.1 in Aug to 49.7 in Sep (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=8668). Tim Moore, Senior Economist at Markit, finds that Germany’s private sector experienced slowing activity in IIIQ2011 that is consistent with GDP stagnation. There is concern about the final quarter of 2011 because of the lack of drivers of economic activity. Table DE provides the data table for Germany.

Table DE, Germany, Economic Indicators

GDP

IIQ2011 0.1 ∆%; II/Q2011/IIQ2010 ∆% 2.7
Blog 09/11/11

Consumer Price Index

Sep month SA ∆%: 0.1
Aug 12 months ∆%: 2.6
Blog 10/16/11

Wholesale Price Index

Aug month ∆%: 0.1
12 months NSA ∆%: 6.5
Blog 09/11/11

Industrial Production

Aug month SA ∆%: minus 1.0
12 months NSA: 12.2
Blog 10/09/11

Machine Orders

Aug month ∆%: -2.8
Aug 12 months ∆%: 5.5
Blog 10/09/11

Retail Sales

Jul Month ∆% 0.0

12 Months ∆% minus 1.6

Blog 09/04/11

Employment Report

Employment Accounts:
Aug Employed 12 months NSA ∆%: 1.3
Labor Force Survey:
Aug Unemployment Rate: 5.9%
Blog 10/02/11

Trade Balance

Exports Jul 12 month NSA ∆%: 4.4 (versus ∆% 3.1 Jun and 19.9 May)
Imports Jul 12 months NSA ∆%: 9.9 (versus ∆% 6.0 Jun and 15.7 May)
Exports Jul month SA ∆%: minus 1.8 percent, versus Jun minus 1.2; Imports Jul month SA minus 0.3∆% versus Jun 0.3
Blog 09/11/11

Links to blog comments in Table DE:

10/09/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/10/twenty-nine-million-unemployedunderempl.html

10/02/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/10/us-growth-standstill-at-08-percent.html

09/18/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/collapse-of-household-income-and-wealth.html

09/11/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/financial-turbulence-wriston-doctrine.html

09/04/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/global-growth-standstill-recession.html

Twelve months rates of growth Germany’s exports and imports are shown in Table 49. There was sharp decline in the rates in Jun and Jul to single-digit levels. In the 12 months ending in Aug, exports rose 14.6 percent and imports 12.6 percent. Growth had been much stronger in the recovery during 2010 and 2011 from the fall from 2007 to 2009. Germany’s trade grew at high rates in 2006 and 2005. 

Table 49, Germany, Exports and Imports NSA Euro Billions and 12 Months ∆%

 

Exports

EURO Billions

12 Months
∆%

Imports
EURO
Billions

12 Months
∆%

Aug 2011

85.3

14.6

73.5

12.6

Jul

85.8

4.3

75.3

9.7

Jun

88.3

3.1

75.6

6.0

May

92.2

20.1

77.4

15.7

Apr

84.3

13.4

73.4

20.1

Mar

98.2

15.7

79.4

17.0

Feb

84.1

21.1

72.1

27.3

Jan

78.6

24.4

68.5

24.3

Dec 2010

81.7

21.0

69.6

26.4

Nov

87.2

20.6

74.1

31.6

Oct

85.9

18.5

71.6

19.3

Sep

86.1

21.4

69.2

16.5

Aug

74.5

24.0

65.3

27.8

Jul

82.2

16.5

68.6

24.8

Jun

85.6

28.0

71.3

34.1

May

76.8

26.6

66.9

32.9

Apr

74.3

15.4

61.2

12.5

Mar

84.9

21.0

67.9

15.5

Feb

69.4

8.8

56.7

3.0

Jan

63.3

-0.5

55.1

-1.8

Dec 2009

67.5

1.2

55.0

-7.3

Dec 2008

66.7

-8.6

59.4

-5.0

Dec 2007

72.9

-0.6

62.5

-0.1

Dec 2006

73.4

10.2

62.6

8.5

Dec 2005

66.6

11.5

57.7

18.1

Dec 2004

59.7

9.2

48.9

10.8

Dec 2003

54.7

7.6

44.1

3.9

Dec 2002

50.8

5.5

   

Dec 2001

48.2

-3.7

   

Dec 2000

50.0

     

Source: http://www.destatis.de/jetspeed/portal/cms/Sites/destatis/Internet/EN/Content/Statistics/TimeSeries/EconomicIndicators/KeyIndicators/ForeignTradeBalance/liste__ahbilanz,templateId=renderPrint.psml

Chart 38 of the Statistisches Bundesamt Deutschland shows exports and trend of German exports. Growth has been with fluctuations around a strong upward trend.

clip_image070

Chart 38, Germany, Exports Original Value and Trend 2007-2011

Source: Statistisches Bundesamt Deutschland

http://www.destatis.de/jetspeed/portal/cms/Sites/destatis/Internet/EN/Content/Statistics/TimeSeries/EconomicIndicators/KeyIndicators/ForeignTradeBalance/liste__ahbilanz,templateId=renderPrint.psml

Chart 39 of the Statistisches Bundesamt Deutschland provides German imports and trend. Imports also fell sharply and have been recovering with fluctuations around a strong upward trend.

clip_image071

Chart 39, Germany, Imports Original Value and Trend 2007-2011

Source:

Statistisches Bundesamt Deutschland

http://www.destatis.de/jetspeed/portal/cms/Sites/destatis/Internet/EN/Content/Statistics/TimeSeries/EconomicIndicators/KeyIndicators/ForeignTradeBalance/liste__ahbilanz,templateId=renderPrint.psml

Chart 40 of the Statistisches Bundesamt Deutschland shows the trade balance of Germany since 2003. There was sharp decline during the global recession and fluctuations around an upward trend during the recovery.

clip_image072

Chart 40, Germany, Trade Balance Original Value and Trend 2007-2011

Source:

Statistisches Bundesamt Deutschland

http://www.destatis.de/jetspeed/portal/cms/Sites/destatis/Internet/EN/Content/Statistics/TimeSeries/EconomicIndicators/KeyIndicators/ForeignTradeBalance/liste__ahbilanz,templateId=renderPrint.psml

Table 50 provides monthly rates of growth of exports and imports of Germany. Exports surged in Aug after weak rates in Jul and Jun.

Table 50, Germany, Exports and Imports Month ∆% Calendar and Seasonally Adjusted 

 

Exports

Imports

Aug 2011

3.5

0.0

Jul

-1.2

0.5

Jun

-0.5

0.0

May

3.4

3.0

Apr

-4.5

-1.6

Mar

5.8

2.6

Feb

2.4

3.2

Jan

-0.5

2.8

Dec 2010

0.7

-2.1

Source: http://www.destatis.de/jetspeed/portal/cms/Sites/destatis/Internet/EN/press/pr/2011/10/PE11__373__51,templateId=renderPrint.psml

There is extremely important information in Table 51 for the current sovereign risk crisis in the euro zone. Table 51 provides the structure of regional and country relations of Germany’s exports and imports. German exports to other European Union members are 57.1 percent of total exports in Aug and 59.7 percent in Jan-Aug. Exports to the euro area are 36.9 percent in Aug and 40.1 percent in Jan-Aug. Exports to third countries are only 42.9 percent of the total in Aug and 40.2 percent in Jan-Aug. There is similar distribution for imports. Economic performance in Germany is closed related to its competitiveness in world markets and weakness in the euro zone and the European Union in general could affect the German economy. 

Table 51, Germany, Structure of Exports and Imports by Region, € Billions and ∆%

 

Aug 2011
€ Billions

12 Months
∆%

Jan-Aug
2011 € Billions

Jan-Aug 2011/
Jan-Jul 2010 ∆%

Total
Exports

85.3

14.6

696.8

14.0

A. EU
Members

48.7

% 57.1

12.7

415.8

% 59.7

13.3

Euro Area

31.5

% 36.9

11.5

279.5

% 40.1

11.9

Non-euro Area

17.1

% 20.0

15.1

136.3

% 19.6

16.5

B. Third Countries

36.6

% 42.9

17.1

281.0

% 40.3

15.1

Total Imports

73.5

12.6

595.3

16.1

C. EU Members

44.8

% 60.9

12.4

376.4

% 63.2

16.6

Euro Area

31.3

% 42.6

13.0

265.4

% 44.6

15.9

Non-euro Area

13.5

11.0

111.0

18.5

D. Third Countries

28.7

% 39.1

12.8

218.9

% 36.8

15.1

Notes: Total Exports = A+B; Total Imports = C+D

Source: http://www.destatis.de/jetspeed/portal/cms/Sites/destatis/Internet/EN/press/pr/2011/10/PE11__373__51,templateId=renderPrint.psml

IVF France. The Markit France Composite Output Index of the Markit France Services PMI® fell from 53.7 in Aug to a 26 month low while the Markit France Services Activity Index fell from 56.8 in Aug to 51.5 in Sep for a 25-month low (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=8666). Jack Kennedy, Senior Economist at Markit, finds that output of the private sector of France moved close to stagnation in Sep. Manufacturing continued in contraction while the strength of services disappeared. The sovereign crisis in the euro zone and slowing world growth are eroding optimism that registered the lowest reading since Apr 2009. Table FR provides the data table for France.

Table FR, France, Economic Indicators

CPI

Sep month ∆% -0.1
12 months ∆%: 2.2
10/16/11

PPI

Aug month ∆%: 0.0
Aug 12 months ∆%: 6.3

Blog 10/02/11

GDP Growth

IIQ2011/IQ2011 ∆%: 0.0
IIQ2011/IIQ2010 ∆%: 1.6
Blog 10/02/11

Industrial Production

Aug/Jul SA ∆%:
Industrial Production 0.5;
Manufacturing 0.7
Aug 12 months NSA ∆%:
Industrial Production 3.5;
Manufacturing 4.2
Blog 10/16/11

Consumer Spending

Aug Manufactured Goods
∆%: 0.1
Jun Manufactured Goods
∆%: 0.4
Blog 10/02/11

Employment

IIQ2011 Unemployed 2.580 million
Unemployment Rate: 9.1%
Employment Rate: 63.9%
Blog 09/04/11

Trade Balance

Aug Exports ∆%: month 6.1, 12 months 10.4

Aug Imports ∆%: month 1.8, 12 months 8.4

Blog 10/09/11

Confidence Indicators

Historical averages 100

Mfg Business Climate 99

Household Confidence 80

Wholesale Trade 99

Blog 9/25/11

Links to blog comments in Table FR:

10/09/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/10/twenty-nine-million-unemployedunderempl.html

10/02/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/10/us-growth-standstill-at-08-percent.html

09/25/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/imf-view-of-world-economy-and-finance.html

09/18/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/collapse-of-household-income-and-wealth.html

09/11/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/financial-turbulence-wriston-doctrine.html

09/04/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/global-growth-standstill-recession.html

France’s industrial production by segments is provided in Table 52. Manufacturing grew 1.8 percent in Jul and 0.5 percent in Aug. Manufacturing increased 4.2 percent in Aug relative to a year earlier.

Table 52, France, Industrial Production ∆%

 

Aug/Jul

Jul/Jun

QOQ

YOY

Industry

0.5

1.8

1.0

3.5

Manufac-
turing

0.7

1.8

0.5

4.2

Mining

2.2

0.7

3.5

-5.9

Construc-
ion

3.2

0.3

-0.5

-0.1

Note: QOQ: quarter on quarter; YOY:most recent quarter on the same quarter a year earlier

Source: http://www.insee.fr/en/themes/info-rapide.asp?id=10&date=20111010

Chart 41 of France’s Institut National de la Statistique et des Études Économiques shows indices of manufacturing in France from 2007 to 2011. Manufacturing, which is CZ in the chart, fell deeply in 2008 and part of 2009. All curves of industrial indices tend to flatten recently.

clip_image073

Chart 41, France, Industrial Production Indices 2007-2011

Legend : CZ : Manufacturing - (C1) : Manufacture of food products and beverages - (C3) : Electrical and electronic equipment; machine equipment - (C4) : Manufacture of transport equipment - (C5) : Other manufacturing

Source: Institut National de la Statistique et des Études Économiques

http://www.insee.fr/en/themes/info-rapide.asp?id=10&date=20111010

IVG Italy. The seasonally adjusted Markit/ADACI Business Activity Index of the Markit/ADACI Italy Services PMI® fell from 48.4 in Aug to 45.8 in Sep for the fourth consecutive month of decline (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=8670). Phil Smith, economist at Markit, finds that the quarterly average of the index is the lowest in the 13 years of the survey. The impact of the euro zone sovereign crisis and new austerity measures restricted business inflows. Table IT provides the data table for Italy.

Table IT, Italy, Economic Indicators

Consumer Price Index

Sep month ∆%: 0.0
Sep 12 months ∆%: 3.0
Blog 10/16/11

Producer Price Index

Jul month ∆%: 0.0
Aug 12 months ∆%: 4.5

Blog 10/02/11

GDP Growth

IIQ2011/IIQ2010 SA ∆%: 0.8
IIQ2011/IQ2011 NSA ∆%: 0.3
Blog 09/11/11

Labor Report

Jul 2011

Participation rate 62%

Employment ratio 56.9%

Unemployment rate 8.0%

Blog 09/04/11

Industrial Production

Aug month ∆%: 4.3
12 months ∆%: 4.7
Blog 10/16/11

Retail Sales

Jul month ∆%: -0.1

Jul 12 months ∆%: -2.4

Blog 09/25/11

Business Confidence

Mfg Aug 99.9, Apr 102.6

Construction Jul 75.8, Apr 73.1

Blog 09/04/11

Consumer Confidence

Consumer Confidence Aug 100.3, Apr 103.7

Economy Aug 70.0, Apr 72.8

Blog 09/04/11

Trade Balance

Balance Aug SA -€ 2707 million versus Jul -€ 2440
Exports Aug month SA ∆%: 0.1; Imports Aug month SA ∆%: 0.9
Exports 12 months NSA ∆%: 16.2 Imports 12 months NSA ∆%: 12.5
Blog 10/16/11

Links to blog comments in Table IT: 10/09/11 Table UK, UK Economic Indicators

   

CPI

Aug month ∆%: 0.6
Aug 12 months ∆%: 4.5
Blog 09/18/11

Output/Input Prices

Output Prices:
Sep 12 months NSA ∆%: 6.3; excluding food, petroleum ∆%: 3.8
Input Prices:
Sep 12 months NSA
∆%: 17.5
Excluding ∆%: 13.3
Blog 10/09/11

GDP Growth

IIQ2011 prior quarter ∆% 01; year earlier same quarter ∆%: 0.6
Blog 10/09/11

Industrial Production

Aug 2011/Aug 2010 NSA ∆%: Industrial Production -1.0; Manufacturing 1.5
Blog 10/16/11

Retail Sales

Aug month SA ∆%: 0.0
Jul 12 months ∆%: 4.7
Blog 09/18/11

Labor Market

May-Jul Unemployment Rate: 8.1%
Blog 10/16/11

Trade Balance

Balance Aug -₤1,877 million
Exports Aug ∆%: 0.5 Jun/Aug ∆%: 9.8
Imports Aug ∆%: -0.5 Jun/Aug ∆%: 6.4
Blog 10/16/11

Links to blog comments in Table UK:

10/09/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/10/twenty-nine-million-unemployedunderempl.html

10/02/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/10/us-growth-standstill-at-08-percent.html

09/25/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/imf-view-of-world-economy-and-finance.html

09/18/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/collapse-of-household-income-and-wealth.html

09/11/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/financial-turbulence-wriston-doctrine.html

09/04/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/global-growth-standstill-recession.html

09/25/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/imf-view-of-world-economy-and-finance.html

09/18/22 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/collapse-of-household-income-and-wealth.html

09/11/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/financial-turbulence-wriston-doctrine.html

09/04/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/global-growth-standstill-recession.html

Italy’s industrial production rebounded in Aug with monthly growth of 4.3 percent and 12-month growth of 4.7 percent, as shown in Table 53. The annual equivalent rate in the first eight months of 2011 is 6.8 percent. Industrial production fell 18.8 percent in 2009 after falling 3.5 percent in 2008.

Table 53, Italy, Industrial Production ∆% 

 

Month ∆%

12 Months ∆%

Aug 2011

4.3

4.7

Jul

-0.3

-1.1

Jun

-0.6

0.1

May

-0.4

1.8

Apr

1.0

3.9

Mar

0.7

3.5

Feb

1.5

2.4

Jan

-1.7

0.4

Jan-Aug Annual Equivalent

6.8

 

Dec 2010

0.1

6.3

Nov

1.3

5.2

Oct

-0.3

3.8

Sep

-1.6

5.5

Aug

-0.2

11.0

Jul

0.7

7.0

Jun

1.0

9.6

May

1.4

8.4

Apr

0.8

9.1

Mar

-0.2

7.8

Feb

-0.5

4.2

Jan

3.9

0.7

Dec 2009

-1.1

-6.6

Year

   

2010

 

6.4

2009

 

-18.8

2008

 

-3.5

Source: http://www.istat.it/en/archive/41898

Chart 42 of the Istituto Nazionale di Statistica of Italy captures the fluctuations in 12 months rates of growth.

clip_image074

Chart 42, Italy, Industrial Production

Source: Istituto Nazionale di Statistica

http://www.istat.it/en/

Month and 12 months growth rates of industrial production in Italy by components are shown in Table 54. There was very strong performance throughout all segments of industrial production in Italy in Aug.

Table 54, Italy, Industrial Production Rate of Change ∆%

Aug 2011

Month ∆%

12 Months ∆%

Total

4.3

4.7

Consumer Goods

4.2

0.6

   Durable

2.8

17.3

   Nondurable

4.6

-0.7

Construction Goods

4.0

6.9

Intermediate Goods

2.7

8.3

Energy

3.3

3.5

Source: http://www.istat.it/en/archive/41898

Exports and imports of Italy and monthly growth rates are provided in Table 55. There have been significant fluctuations. Exports grew 1.0 percent in Jul and imports 1.9 percent. In Aug, exports rose 0.1 percent and imports 0.9 percent.

Table 55, Italy, Exports, Imports and Trade Balance SA Million Euros and Month SA ∆%

 

Exports

€ M

Exports
Month ∆%

Imports

€ M

Imports
Month ∆%

Balance

€ M

Aug

31,376

0.1

34,083

0.9

-2,707

Jul

31,354

1.0

33,794

1.9

-2,440

Jun

31,031

-0.8

33,172

-3.9

-2,141

May

31,291

0.0

34,533

-1.0

-3,242

Apr

31,296

0.7

34,895

-0.1

-3,599

Mar

31,089

1.6

34,940

3.5

-3,851

Feb

30,614

-1.5

33,767

-0.6

-3,153

Jan

31,090

4.1

33,954

2.5

-2,864

AE ∆%

         

Dec 2010

29,852

0.6

33,121

0.3

-3,269

AE: annual equivalent

Source: http://www.istat.it/it/archivio/42516

Italy’s trade not seasonally adjusted is provided in Table 56. Values are different because the data are original and not adjusted. Twelve months rates of growth picked up again in Aug with 16.2 percent for exports and 12.5 percent for imports. Exports fell 20.9 percent and imports 22.1 percent during the global recession in 2009.

Table 56, Italy, Exports, Imports and Trade Balance NSA Million Euros and 12 Month ∆%

 

Exports

€ M

Exports
12 Months ∆%

Imports

€ M

Imports
12 Months ∆%

Balance

€ M

Aug

24,501

16.2

27,653

12.5

-3,152

Jul

35,131

5.4

33,696

6.1

1,435

Jun

32,696

8.1

34,445

3.0

-1,749

May

33,612

19.9

36,014

18.9

-2,402

Apr

31,220

12.8

34,987

20.7

-3,767

Mar

34,454

14.1

38,392

20.4

-3,938

Feb

29,825

18.4

33,467

19.4

-3,642

Jan

26,163

24.5

32,762

30.6

-6,599

Dec 2010

29,792

20.5

32,511

30.8

-2,719

Year

         

2010

337,810

15.8

367,122

23.4

-29,312

2009

291,733

-20.9

297,609

-22.1

-5,876

2008

369,016

1.2

382,050

2.3

-13,034

Source: http://www.istat.it/it/archivio/42516

Growth rates of Italy’s trade and major products are provided in Table 57 for the period Jan-Aug 2011 relative to Jan-Aug 2010. Growth rates are high for the total and all segments with the exception of a decline in imports of consumer durables.

Table 57, Italy, Exports and Imports % Share of Products in Total and ∆%

 

Exports
Share %

Exports
∆% Jan-Aug 2011/ Jan-Aug 2010

Imports
Share %

Imports
∆% Jan-Aug 2011/ Jan-Aug 2010

Consumer
Goods

29.4

10.2

25.2

9.2

Durable

6.3

6.8

3.5

-5.0

Non
Durable

23.1

11.1

21.8

11.4

Capital Goods

32.3

14.1

22.1

4.7

Inter-
mediate Goods

33.4

16.9

33.8

24.9

Energy

4.8

21.0

18.9

23.0

Total ex Energy

95.2

13.9

81.1

14.3

Total

100.0

14.2

100.0

16.0

Source: http://www.istat.it/it/archivio/42516

Italy’s structure of regional trade in Jan-Aug 2011 and growth rates is in Table 58. Exports to members of the European Union are 57.3 percent of the total. Exports to the euro zone or European Monetary Union (EMU) are 43.5 percent. Imports to members of the European Union account for 54.9 percent of the total and imports from members of EMU are 44.1 percent of the total. After years of integration, members of EMU are dependent on each other such that the end of the common currency could be disruptive. 

Table 58, Italy, Exports and Imports by Regions and Countries, % Share and 12 Months  ∆%

 

Exports
% Share

∆% Jan-Aug 2011/ Jan-Aug 2010

Imports
% Share

Imports
∆% Jan-Aug 2011/ Jan-Aug 2010

EU

57.3

12.5

54.9

11.9

EMU

43.5

12.4

44.1

11.2

France

11.6

13.3

8.3

8.4

Germany

13.0

17.2

15.9

12.8

Spain

5.8

4.9

4.5

12.6

UK

5.3

3.1

3.3

22.9

Non EU

42.7

16.5

45.1

20.8

Europe non EU

12.1

25.2

10.3

22.5

USA

6.0

14.2

3.0

22.0

China

2.5

18.8

7.8

18.3

OPEC

5.3

-0.6

9.4

5.2

Total

100.0

14.2

100.0

16.0

Notes: EU: European Union; EMU: European Monetary Union (euro zone)

Source: http://www.istat.it/it/archivio/42516

IVH United Kingdom. The Markit/CIPS UK Manufacturing PMI® rose to 51.1 in Sep away from the contraction level of 49.4 in Aug for the first reading above 50 in three months (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=8631). The average reading of the PMI in IIIQ2011 of 50 is substantially lower than 59.4 in IIQ2011, which was close to a record, and 52.7 in IIQ2011. David Noble, Chief Executive Officer at the Chartered Institute of Purchasing & Supply finds improvement after the low of 26 months registered in Aug. The concern is with falling export orders resulting from the weak global economy and especially conditions in the euro zone. The seasonally adjusted Business Activity Index of the Markit/CIPS UK Services PMI® rose from 51.1 in Aug, which was an eight-month low, to 52.9 in Sep (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=8669). There has been growth for nine consecutive months but the average in IIIQ2011 of 53.1 is the weakest quarterly level in 2011. Table UK provides the data table for the United Kingdom.

Table UK, UK Economic Indicators

   

CPI

Aug month ∆%: 0.6
Aug 12 months ∆%: 4.5
Blog 09/18/11

Output/Input Prices

Output Prices:
Sep 12 months NSA ∆%: 6.3; excluding food, petroleum ∆%: 3.8
Input Prices:
Sep 12 months NSA
∆%: 17.5
Excluding ∆%: 13.3
Blog 10/09/11

GDP Growth

IIQ2011 prior quarter ∆% 01; year earlier same quarter ∆%: 0.6
Blog 10/09/11

Industrial Production

Aug 2011/Aug 2010 NSA ∆%: Industrial Production -1.0; Manufacturing 1.5
Blog 10/16/11

Retail Sales

Aug month SA ∆%: 0.0
Jul 12 months ∆%: 4.7
Blog 09/18/11

Labor Market

May-Jul Unemployment Rate: 8.1%
Blog 10/16/11

Trade Balance

Balance Aug -₤1,877 million
Exports Aug ∆%: 0.5 Jun/Aug ∆%: 9.8
Imports Aug ∆%: -0.5 Jun/Aug ∆%: 6.4
Blog 10/16/11

Links to blog comments in Table UK: 10/09/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/10/twenty-nine-million-unemployedunderempl.html

09/25/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/imf-view-of-world-economy-and-finance.html

09/18/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/collapse-of-household-income-and-wealth.html

09/11/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/financial-turbulence-wriston-doctrine.html

09/04/11 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/global-growth-standstill-recession.html

The UK Office for National Statistics provides the output of production industries with revisions. Table 59 incorporates the revisions provided in the released on Oct 11, 2011(http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/rel/iop/index-of-production/august-2011/index.html). Manufacturing accounts for 66.6 percent of the production industries of the UK and grew at 1.5 percent in the 12 months ending in Aug, declining from the high rate of growth of 6.1 percent in the 12 months ending in Jan. Capital goods industries grew at 5.0 percent in the 12 months ending in Aug and has been growing at very high rates during the current cyclical recovery. Mining and quandary fell 14.5 percent in the 12 months ending in Aug mostly as a result of decline in gas and oil. The 12 months rates of growth of the entire index of production industries registered declines from Mar to Aug 2011. Energy and mining have been the factors of decline. The lower part of Table 59 provides rates of change of yearly values. Manufacturing output fell 9.6 percent in 2009 after falling 2.6 percent in 2008.

Table 59, UK, Output of the Production Industries, 12 Months ∆%

 

PROD
IND

MNG

MFG

ENGY

CON
DUR

CON
NDUR

CAP

2011

             

Aug

-1.0

-14.5

1.5

-8.6

3.3

2.0

5.0

Jul

-0.9

-15.8

2.6

-10.2

5.0

3.9

5.3

Jun

--

-14.4

3.5

-8.6

8.5

3.1

8.3

May

-0.9

-20.3

3.9

-12.6

3.1

4.4

6.4

Apr

-1.7

-15.9

2.2

-11.7

2.1

4.5

4.4

Mar

-0.4

-15.9

3.2

-10.7

1.8

1.2

8.8

Feb

1.6

-12.1

5.1

-8.1

1.1

1.4

11.1

Jan

3.5

-4.3

6.1

-3.8

4.7

0.2

11.1

2010

             

Dec

3.4

-4.8

4.5

0.7

-4.1

3.5

8.2

Nov

2.8

-6.0

5.2

-3.0

-9.3

1.4

9.7

Oct

2.6

-5.9

5.3

-3.1

-9.4

4.0

8.0

Sep

3.5

1.5

5.2

0.5

-9.3

2.5

9.8

Aug

4.1

0.8

6.5

-0.6

-0.2

4.4

12.6

Jul

1.8

-8.0

5.1

-6.4

-1.7

-0.3

12.5

Jun

1.3

-9.9

4.1

-6.7

-6.0

0.9

9.6

May

2.4

-2.2

3.6

-2.1

-1.9

-3.3

12.4

Apr

1.0

-5.8

2.3

-3.6

-2.6

-6.3

10.7

Mar

2.3

-1.4

3.3

-1.0

1.1

-1.6

9.5

Feb

-0.6

-8.3

1.1

-5.9

-1.1

-2.7

7.7

Jan

-1.7

-9.1

-0.4

-5.3

-4.0

-1.4

4.9

2010/
2009

1.9

-5.0

3.8

-3.1

-4.1

--

9.6

2009/ 2008

-9.0

-9.0

-9.6

-6.2

-7.5

-0.8

-10.7

2008/ 2007

-2.8

-6.5

-2.6

-2.9

-5.6

-1.9

-3.0

2007/
2006

0.5

-2.5

0.8

-1.2

1.0

-1.7

2.5

2006/ 2005

--

-7.6

1.7

-5.4

0.3

0.7

2.9

Notes: PROD IND: Production Industries; MNG: Mining; MFG: Manufacturing; ENGY: Electricity, Gas and Water Supply; CON DUR: Consumer Durables; CONS NDUR: Consumer Nondurables; CAP: Capital Goods

Source: http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/publications/re-reference-tables.html?edition=tcm%3A77-233027

The weights of components of the production index and contributions by components to the monthly and 12 month rate of change are provided in Table 60. The 12 month rate of output of the production industries of minus 1.0 percent was driven by negative contribution of 2.23 percentage points of the general component of mining with the subcomponent of oil and gas contributing negative 2.36 percentage points. The component of electricity, gas, steam and air conditioning contributed 0.2 percentage points. The contributions do not add exactly because of rounding. Manufacturing fell 0.3 percent in Aug contributing minus 0.24 percentage points but the production industries index still grew 0.2 percent because of positive contribution by mining of 0.28 percentage points and 0.19 percentage points by electricity.

Table 60, UK, Weights of Components, Volume 12 Months and Month ∆% and Percentage Point Contributions of Production Industries by Components

 

Weight
%

Volume
12 Months
∆% Ending in Aug 2011

% Point
Contri
-bution

Volume
Month
∆% Aug
2011/
Jul 2011

% Point
Contri
-bution

PROD
IND

100.0

-1.0

-1.0

0.2

0.2

MNG

16.4

-14.5

-2.23

2.1

0.28

MNG 06

14.1

-18.0

-2.36

2.3

0.24

MFG

66.6

1.5

1.03

-0.3

-0.24

ELEC

9.3

2.1

0.2

1.9

0.19

WATER
& SEW

7.7

-0.2

-0.02

-0.2

-0.01

Notes: PROD IND: Index of Production; MNG: Mining and Quarrying (of which 14.4 percent of the total weight in oil and gas extraction); MNG 06: Subdivision of Mining including oil and gas extraction; MFG: Manufacturing; ELEC: Electricity, gas, steam and air conditioning; WATER & SEW: water supply, sewerage and waste management

Source: http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/publications/re-reference-tables.html?edition=tcm%3A77-224807

Percentage changes in the production industries and major components in the latest month relative to the prior month are shown in Table 61. Manufacturing has fallen in three consecutive months ending in Aug. Output of consumer durables fell 1.0 percent in Jul and then fell another 0.5 percent in Aug. Output of capital goods fell 0.8 percent in Jul and then another 0.1 percent in Aug.

Table 61, UK, Output of the Production Industries,  Latest Month on Previous Month   ∆%

 

PROD
IND

MNG

MFG

ENGY

CON
DUR

CON
NDUR

CAP

2011

             

Aug

0.2

2.1

-0.3

1.8

-0.5

0.3

-0.1

Jul

-0.4

-0.1

-0.2

-1.0

-1.0

-0.1

-0.8

Jun

0.3

1.5

-0.1

1.5

0.6

0.7

0.2

May

1.0

-4.5

1.9

-0.8

0.5

1.0

2.6

Apr

-1.7

-1.0

-1.4

-2.2

-0.6

--

-3.3

Mar

0.2

-0.6

0.4

-0.4

1.3

1.5

0.7

Feb

-1.1

-7.9

0.3

-5.4

-0.6

0.3

1.7

Jan

0.2

2.8

0.9

-2.5

2.6

-0.8

2.1

2010

             

Dec

0.3

-2.7

-0.6

2.0

4.4

0.4

-0.6

Notes: PROD IND: Production Industries; MNG: Mining; MFG: Manufacturing; ENGY: Electricity, Gas and Water Supply; CON DUR: Consumer Durables; CONS NDUR: Consumer Nondurables; CAP: Capital Goods

Source: http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/publications/re-reference-tables.html?edition=tcm%3A77-233027

In the quarter Jun to Aug 2011 output of production industries fell 0.6 percent relative to the same quarter in 2010 but output of manufacturing rose 2.5 percent, as shown in Table 62. In the quarter Jun to Aug 2011 the output of production industries rose 0.2 percent relative to the output in the prior quarter of Mar to May 2011 while the output of manufacturing rose 0.4 percent.

Table 62, UK, Production and Manufacturing ∆%

 

Index of Production

Index of Manufacturing

Aug 2011/ 
Aug 2010

-1.0

1.5

Jun to Aug 2011/

Jun to Aug 2010

-0.6

2.5

Aug 2011/ 
Jul 2011

0.2

-0.3

Jun to Aug 2011/ 
Mar to May 2011

0.2

0.4

Source: http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/publications/re-reference-tables.html?edition=tcm%3A77-224807

The revision of the national accounts and the production industries permits an analysis of growth and contributions to growth of output components. Table 63 shows the quarter-on-quarter percentage change of output components of UK GDP. Agriculture has relatively minor share in GDP in the UK. Manufacturing has grown steadily throughout all quarters in 2010 and 2011 without a single quarter of contraction but slowed to 0.2 percent in IIQ2011. Construction has shown wide fluctuations. Services had two negative quarters, minus 0.4 percent in IVQ2010 and -0.1 percent in IQ2010. The output of the total index of production industries had stronger performance until it fell 1.2 percent in IIQ2011 after falling 0.1 percent in IQ2011.

Table 63, UK, GDP Output Components, Growth Quarter-on-Quarter ∆%

 

IIQ11

IQ11

IVQ10

IIIQ10

IIQ10

IQ10

AG

-0.9

11.2

-10.1

-0.4

-0.1

-0.4

TP

-1.2

-0.1

0.1

0.3

1.2

1.3

MFG

0.2

1.1

0.6

1.3

1.7

1.3

CONST

1.1

-2.7

-1.8

3.2

8.2

0.9

SERV

0.2

0.7

-0.4

0.4

0.4

-0.1

Notes: AG: Agriculture; TP: Total Production; MFG: Manufacturing; CONST: Construction; SERV: Services

Sources: http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/rel/naa2/quarterly-national-accounts/q2-2011/index.html

Contributions by output components in percentage points to GDP quarterly growth are shown in Table 64. The drivers of GDP growth in the UK in 2010 and 2011 have been manufacturing and services. The contribution of services exceeded the contribution of manufacturing in all quarter with the exception of IVQ2010 and IQ2010.

Table 64, UK, GDP Growth Contributions by Output Components, Quarter-on-Quarter %

 

IIQ11

IQ11

IVQ10

IIIQ10

IIQ10

IQ10

AG

0.0

0.1

-0.1

0.0

0.0

0.0

TP

-0.2

0.0

0.0

0.1

0.2

0.2

MFG

0.0

0.1

0.1

0.2

0.2

0.1

CONST

0.1

-0.2

-0.1

0.2

0.5

0.1

SERV

0.2

0.5

-0.3

0.3

0.3

0.0

Notes: AG: Agriculture; TP: Total Production; MFG: Manufacturing; CONST: Construction; SERV: Services

Sources: http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/rel/naa2/quarterly-national-accounts/q2-2011/index.html

Growth rates of output components in a quarter relative to the same quarter a year earlier are shown in Table 65. The highest rates by far are those of construction and manufacturing but manufacturing had no negative rates while construction fell 0.3 percent in IIQ2011 and 0.7 percent in IQ2010. 

Table 65, UK, GDP Output Components Growth Quarter on Same Quarter Previous Year, ∆%

 

IIQ11

IQ11

IVQ10

IIIQ10

IIQ10

IQ10

AG

-1.3

-0.5

-10.9

1.4

1.8

2.1

TP

-0.9

1.5

2.9

3.2

1.5

0.0

MFG

3.2

4.8

5.0

5.6

3.3

1.3

CONST

-0.3

6.7

10.6

13.0

10.2

-0.7

SERV

1.0

1.2

0.4

1.6

1.6

1.0

Notes: AG: Agriculture; TP: Total Production; MFG: Manufacturing; CONST: Construction; SERV: Services

Sources: http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/rel/naa2/quarterly-national-accounts/q2-2011/index.html

Contributions in percentage points to GDP growth by output components are shown in Table 66. The contributions in percentage points to GDP are highest for services because of its higher share in GDP and strong performance. Manufacturing and services have been the drivers of GDP growth of the UK. 

Table 66, UK, GDP Growth Contributions by Output Components, Quarter on Same Quarter Previous Year %

 

IIQ11

IQ11

IVQ10

IIIQ10

IIQ10

IQ10

AG

0.0

0.0

-0.1

0.0

0.0

0.0

TP

-0.1

0.3

0.5

0.5

0.3

0.0

MFG

0.4

0.6

0.6

0.7

0.4

0.1

CONST

0.0

0.4

0.6

0.7

0.6

0.0

SERV

0.7

0.9

0.3

1.3

1.3

0.8

Notes: AG: Agriculture; TP: Total Production; MFG: Manufacturing; CONST: Construction; SERV: Services

Sources: http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/rel/naa2/quarterly-national-accounts/q2-2011/index.html

Growth rates of output components of GDP using yearly data are shown in Table 67. The global recession had strong impact on the UK with manufacturing falling 9.6 percent in 2009 and 2.6 percent in 2008. Services fell 2.6 percent in 2009 after falling 0.5 percent in 2008. Services grew at much higher rates in 2005 to 2008 than in 2010, supporting UK growth and also the trade balance.

Table 67, UK, GDP Output Components Growth Year on Previous Year, ∆%

 

2010

2009

2008

2007

2006

2005

AG

-1.5

15.2

16.2

-3.7

-3.1

6.8

TP

1.9

-9.0

-2.8

0.5

0.0

-0.8

MFG

3.8

-9.6

-2.6

0.8

1.7

-0.2

CONST

8.2

-13.5

-2.8

2.1

0.7

-2.5

SERV

1.2

-2.6

-0.5

4.4

3.3

3.4

Notes: AG: Agriculture; TP: Total Production; MFG: Manufacturing; CONST: Construction; SERV: Services

Sources: http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/rel/naa2/quarterly-national-accounts/q2-2011/index.html

The strong contribution by services to GDP growth in percentage points between 2005 and 2007 is shown in Table 68. In 2010, services contributed 0.9 percentage points to GDP growth while manufacturing contributed 0.5 percentage points.

Table 68, UK, GDP Output Components Growth Contribution Year on Previous Year, %

 

2010

2009

2008

2007

2006

2005

AG

0.0

-0.1

0.1

0.0

0.0

0.0

TP

0.3

-1.5

-0.5

0.1

0.0

-0.2

MFG

0.5

-1.2

-0.3

0.1

0.2

0.0

CONST

0.5

-0.9

-0.2

0.1

0.1

-0.2

SERV

0.9

-2.0

-0.4

3.3

2.5

2.4

Notes: AG: Agriculture; TP: Total Production; MFG: Manufacturing; CONST: Construction; SERV: Services

Sources: http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/rel/naa2/quarterly-national-accounts/q2-2011/index.html

The labor market report of the UK for the quarter Jun/Aug 2011 is shown in Table 69. The unemployment rate rose to 8.1 percent and the number unemployed rose 114,000 in Jun-Aug relative to Mar-May, reaching 2.57 million. There are 867,000 unemployed over one year and 423,000 unemployed over two years. The employment rate is 70.4 percent. Earnings growth including bonuses was 2.8 percent over the earlier year. The claimant count or those receiving unemployment benefits stands at 5.0 percent. 

Table 69, UK, Labor Market Statistics

 

Quarter Jun/Aug 2011

Unemployment Rate

8.1% +0.4 % point in quarter, highest since Jul 1996

Number Unemployed

+114,000 in Jun-Aug relative to Mar-May to reach 2.57 million, highest unemployed number since Aug-Oct 1994

Unemployed over one year: 867,000

Unemployed over two years: 423,000

Number Unemployed

Number unemployed over one year: 849,000, +20,000 in May/Jul

Inactivity Rate 16-64 Years of Age

23.3%

Economically inactive +26,000 in Jun-Aug, +75,000 over year earlier

9.35 million inactive people

Employment Rate

70.4%

Number Employed

-178,000 relative to Mar-May 

-47,000 in year to reach 29.10 million, lower than peak of 29.57 million in Mar-May 2008

Earnings Growth Rates Year on Year

Total 2.8% (including bonuses) over year earlier

Regular 1.8% (excluding bonuses) over year earlier

Part-Time

7.78 million in Jun-Aug, –175.000 relative to Mar-May

 

Aug 2011

Claimant Count

Latest estimate: 1.6 million in Aug; +17,500 since Jul, +129,000 from prior year (rate: 5.0% +0.4 percentage points from year earlier)

Source: http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/dcp171778_237932.pdf

The UK trade account is shown in Table 70. In Aug 2011, the UK ran a deficit in trade of goods and services of ₤1887 million. The deficit in trade of goods was ₤7768 million and ₤7732 in goods excluding oil. A surplus in services of ₤5891 billion contributed to the smaller overall deficit in goods and services (₤7768 billion less ₤5891 equal to ₤1887). Services have contributed to lower trade account deficits and also softened the impact of the global recession on the UK economy. Exports of goods and services rose 0.5 percent in Aug 2011 and 9.8 percent in the quarter Jun-Aug 2011 relative to the same quarter a year earlier with imports falling 0.5 percent in Aug and rising 6.4 percent relative to the quarter a year earlier. Excluding oil, UK exports rose 0.3 percent in Aug and 9.8 percent relative to a year earlier while imports rose 0.1 percent and 5.6 percent relative to a year earlier. The great advantage of the UK similar to the US is the substantial surplus in services. Services exports and imports rose at the same rate of 0.3 percent in Aug while exports increased 8.0 percent relative to a year earlier and imports fell 0.7 percent.

Table 70, Value of UK Trade in Goods and Services, Balance of Payments Basis, ₤ Million  and ∆%

 

₤ Million SA 
Aug 2011

Month ∆%
Aug 2011

Jun to Aug 2011 ∆% Jun to Aug 2010

Total Trade

     

Exports

40,769

0.5

9.8

Imports

42,646

-0.5

6.4

Balance

-1,877

   

Trade in Goods

     

Exports

25,541

0.6

11.0

Imports

33,309

-0.7

8.5

Balance

-7,768

   

Trade in Goods Excluding Oil

     

Exports

22,347

0.3

9.8

Imports

29,579

0.1

5.6

Balance

-7,232

   

Trade in Services

     

Exports

15,228

0.3

8.0

Imports

9,337

0.3

-0.7

Balance

5,891

   

Source: http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/rel/uktrade/uk-trade/august-2011/stb-uk-trade-august-2011.html

V Valuation of Risk Financial Assets. The financial crisis and global recession were caused by interest rate and housing subsidies and affordability policies that encouraged high leverage and risks, low liquidity and unsound credit (Pelaez and Pelaez, Financial Regulation after the Global Recession (2009a), 157-66, Regulation of Banks and Finance (2009b), 217-27, International Financial Architecture (2005), 15-18, The Global Recession Risk (2007), 221-5, Globalization and the State Vol. II (2008b), 197-213, Government Intervention in Globalization (2008c), 182-4). Several past comments of this blog elaborate on these arguments, among which: http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/07/causes-of-2007-creditdollar-crisis.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/07/causes-of-2007-creditdollar-crisis.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/professor-mckinnons-bubble-economy.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/world-inflation-quantitative-easing.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/treasury-yields-valuation-of-risk.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2010/11/quantitative-easing-theory-evidence-and.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2010/12/is-fed-printing-money-what-are.html 

Table 71 shows the phenomenal impulse to valuations of risk financial assets originating in the initial shock of near zero interest rates in 2003-2004 with the fed funds rate at 1 percent, in fear of deflation that never materialized, and quantitative easing in the form of suspension of the auction of 30-year Treasury bonds to lower mortgage rates. World financial markets were dominated by monetary and housing policies in the US. Between 2002 and 2008, the DJ UBS Commodity Index rose 165.5 percent largely because of the unconventional monetary policy encouraging carry trade from low US interest rates to long leveraged positions in commodities, exchange rates and other risk financial assets. The charts of risk financial assets show sharp increase in valuations leading to the financial crisis and then profound drops that are captured in Table 71 by percentage changes of peaks and troughs. The first round of quantitative easing and near zero interest rates depreciated the dollar relative to the euro by 39.3 percent between 2003 and 2008, with revaluation of the dollar by 25.1 percent from 2008 to 2010 in the flight to dollar-denominated assets in fear of world financial risks and then devaluation of the dollar by 16.4 percent by Fri Oct 14, 2011. Dollar devaluation is a major vehicle of monetary policy in reducing the output gap that is implemented in the probably erroneous belief that devaluation will not accelerate inflation, misallocating resources toward less productive economic activities and disrupting financial markets. The last row of Table 71 shows CPI inflation in the US rising from 1.9 percent in 2003 to 4.1 percent in 2007 even as monetary policy increased the fed funds rate from 1 percent in Jun 2004 to 5.25 percent in Jun 2006.

Table 71, Volatility of Assets

DJIA

10/08/02-10/01/07

10/01/07-3/4/09

3/4/09- 4/6/10

 

∆%

87.8

-51.2

60.3

 

NYSE Financial

1/15/04- 6/13/07

6/13/07- 3/4/09

3/4/09- 4/16/07

 

∆%

42.3

-75.9

121.1

 

Shanghai Composite

6/10/05- 10/15/07

10/15/07- 10/30/08

10/30/08- 7/30/09

 

∆%

444.2

-70.8

85.3

 

STOXX EUROPE 50

3/10/03- 7/25/07

7/25/07- 3/9/09

3/9/09- 4/21/10

 

∆%

93.5

-57.9

64.3

 

UBS Com.

1/23/02- 7/1/08

7/1/08- 2/23/09

2/23/09- 1/6/10

 

∆%

165.5

-56.4

41.4

 

10-Year Treasury

6/10/03

6/12/07

12/31/08

4/5/10

%

3.112

5.297

2.247

3.986

USD/EUR

6/26/03

7/14/08

6/07/10

10/14 
/2011

Rate

1.1423

1.5914

1.192

1.387

CNY/USD

01/03
2000

07/21
2005

7/15
2008

10/07

2011

Rate

8.2798

8.2765

6.8211

6.379

New House

1963

1977

2005

2009

Sales 1000s

560

819

1283

375

New House

2000

2007

2009

2010

Median Price $1000

169

247

217

203

 

2003

2005

2007

2010

CPI

1.9

3.4

4.1

1.5

Sources: http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/page/marketsdata.html?mod=WSJ_hps_marketdata

http://www.census.gov/const/www/newressalesindex_excel.html

http://federalreserve.gov/releases/h10/Hist/dat00_eu.htm

ftp://ftp.bls.gov/pub/special.requests/cpi/cpiai.txt

http://federalreserve.gov/releases/h10/Hist/dat00_ch.htm

Table 72 extracts four rows of Table 71 with the Dollar/Euro (USD/EUR) exchange rate and Chinese Yuan/Dollar (CNY/USD) exchange rate that reveal pursuit of exchange rate policies resulting from monetary policy in the US and capital control/exchange rate policy in China. The ultimate intentions are the same: promoting internal economic activity at the expense of the rest of the world. The easy money policy of the US was deliberately or not but effectively to devalue the dollar from USD 1.1423/EUR on Jun 26, 2003 to USD 1.5914/EUR on Jul 14, 2008, or by 39.3 percent. The flight into dollar assets after the global recession caused revaluation to USD 1.192/EUR on Jun 7, 2010, or by 25.1 percent. After the temporary interruption of the sovereign risk issues in Europe from Apr to Jul, 2010, shown in Table 74 below, the dollar has devalued again to USD 1.387/EUR or by 16.4 percent. Yellen (2011AS, 6) admits that Fed monetary policy results in dollar devaluation with the objective of increasing net exports, which was the policy that Joan Robinson (1947) labeled as “beggar-my-neighbor” remedies for unemployment. China fixed the CNY to the dollar for a long period at a highly undervalued level of around CNY 8.2765/USD until it revalued to CNY 6.8211/USD until Jun 7, 2010, or by 17.6 percent and after fixing it again to the dollar, revalued to CNY 6.379/USD on Fri Oct 14, 2011, or by an additional 6.5 percent, for cumulative revaluation of 22.9 percent. The Dow Jones Newswires informs on Oct 15 that the premier of China Wen Jiabao announced that the Chinese yuan will not be further appreciated to prevent adverse effects on exports (http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052970203914304576632790881396896.html?mod=WSJ_hp_LEFTWhatsNewsCollection).

Table 72, Dollar/Euro (USD/EUR) Exchange Rate and Chinese Yuan/Dollar (CNY/USD) Exchange Rate

USD/EUR

6/26/03

7/14/08

6/07/10

10/14 
/2011

Rate

1.1423

1.5914

1.192

1.387

CNY/USD

01/03
2000

07/21
2005

7/15
2008

10/07

2011

Rate

8.2798

8.2765

6.8211

6.379

Source: Table 71

Dollar devaluation did not eliminate the US current account deficit, which is projected by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) with the new database of Sep 2011 at 3.1 percent of GDP in 2011 and at 2.2 percent of GDP in 2015, as shown in Table 73. Revaluation of the CNY has not reduced the current account surplus of China, which is projected by the IMF to increase from 5.2 percent of GDP in 2011 to 7.0 percent of GDP in 2015.

Table 73, Fiscal Deficit, Current Account Deficit and Government Debt as % of GDP and 2011 Dollar GDP

 

GDP
$B

2011

FD
%GDP
2011

CAD
%GDP
2011

Debt
%GDP
2011

FD%GDP
2015

CAD%GDP
2015

Debt
%GDP
2015

US

15065

-7.9

-3.1

72.6

-3.1

-2.2

86.7

Japan

5855

-8.9

2.5

130.5

-8.4

2.4

160.0

UK

2481

-5.7

-2.7

72.9

0.4

-0.9

75.2

Euro

13355

-1.5

0.1

68.6

1.5

0.5

69.3

Ger

3629

0.4

5.0

56.9

2.1

4.7

55.3

France

2808

-3.4

-2.7

80.9

-2.5

0.6

83.9

Italy

2246

0.5

-3.5

100.4

4.5

-2.0

96.7

Can

1759

-3.7

-3.3

34.9

0.3

-2.6

35.1

China

6988

-1.6

5.2

22.2

0.1

7.0

12.9

Brazil

2518

3.2

-2.3

38.6

2.9

-3.2

34.1

Note: GER = Germany; Can = Canada; FD = fiscal deficit; CAD = current account deficit

FD is primary except total for China; Debt is net except gross for China

Source: http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2011/02/weodata/index.aspx

There is a new carry trade that learned from the losses after the crisis of 2007 or learned from the crisis how to avoid losses. The sharp rise in valuations of risk financial assets shown in Table 71 above after the first policy round of near zero fed funds and quantitative easing by the equivalent of withdrawing supply with the suspension of the 30-year Treasury auction was on a smooth trend with relatively subdued fluctuations. The credit crisis and global recession have been followed by significant fluctuations originating in sovereign risk issues in Europe, doubts of continuing high growth and accelerating inflation in China, events such as in the Middle East and Japan and legislative restructuring, regulation, insufficient growth, falling real wages, depressed hiring and high job stress of unemployment and underemployment in the US now with realization of growth standstill recession. The “trend is your friend” motto of traders has been replaced with a “hit and realize profit” approach of managing positions to realize profits without sitting on positions. There is a trend of valuation of risk financial assets driven by the carry trade from zero interest rates with fluctuations provoked by events of risk aversion. Table 74, which is updated for every comment of this blog, shows the deep contraction of valuations of risk financial assets after the Apr 2010 sovereign risk issues in the fourth column “∆% to Trough.” There was sharp recovery after around Jul 2010 in the last column “∆% Trough to 10/14/11,” which has been recently stalling or reversing amidst profound risk aversion. “Let’s twist again” monetary policy during the week of Sep 23 caused deep worldwide risk aversion and selloff of risk financial assets. Monetary policy was designed to increase risk appetite but instead suffocated risk exposures. Recovering risk financial assets in column “∆% Trough to 10/14/11” are in the range from 2.0 percent for the Shanghai Composite and 20.2 percent for the DJIA. The carry trade from zero interest rates to leveraged positions in risk financial assets has proved strongest for commodity exposures. Before the current round of risk aversion, all assets in the column “∆% Trough to 10/14/11” had double digit gains relative to the trough around Jul 2, 2010. There are now several valuations lower than those at the trough around Jul 2: European stocks index STOXX 50 is now 3.2 percent below the trough on Jul 2, 2010; the NYSE Financial Index is 4.5 percent below the trough on Jul 2, 2010; and Japan’s Nikkei Average is 0.9 percent below the trough on Aug 31, 2010 and 23.2 percent below the peak on Apr 5, 2010. The Nikkei Average closed at 8747.96 on Fri Oct 14, which is 14.7 percent below 10,254.43 on Mar 11 on the date of the Great East earthquake/tsunami. Global risk aversion erased the earlier gains of the Nikkei. Germany’s DAX is 5.2 percent above the trough on Apr 25, 2010. The dollar depreciated by 16.4 percent relative to the euro and even higher before the new bout of sovereign risk issues in Europe. The column “∆% week to 10/14/2011” shows gains for all financial assets in Table 74. There are still high uncertainties on European sovereign risks, US and world growth recession and China’s growth and inflation tradeoff. Sovereign problems in the “periphery” of Europe and fears of slower growth in Asia and the US cause risk aversion with trading caution instead of more aggressive risk exposures. There is a fundamental change in Table 74 from the relatively upward trend with oscillations since the sovereign risk event of Apr-Jul 2010. Performance is best assessed in the column “∆% Peak to 10/14/11” that provides the percentage change from the peak in Apr 2010 before the sovereign risk event to Oct 14, 2011. Most financial risk assets had gained not only relative to the trough as shown in column “∆% Trough to 10/14/11” but also relative to the peak in column “∆% Peak to 10/14/11.” There are now only three indexes above the peak: DJIA by 3.9 percent, DJ UBS Commodity Index by 2.2 percent and S&P by 0.6 percent. There are several indexes well below the peak: NYSE Financial Index (http://www.nyse.com/about/listed/nykid.shtml) by 23.9 percent, Nikkei Average by 23.2 percent, Shanghai Composite by 23.2 percent, STOXX 50 by 16.3 percent, Dow Global by 11.6 percent and Dow Asia Pacific by 8.3 percent. The factors of risk aversion have adversely affected the performance of risk financial assets. The performance relative to the peak in Apr is more important than the performance relative to the trough around early Jul because improvement could signal that conditions have returned to normal levels before European sovereign doubts in Apr 2010. The situation of risk financial assets has worsened.

Table 74, Stock Indexes, Commodities, Dollar and 10-Year Treasury  

 

Peak

Trough

∆% to Trough

∆% Peak to 10/14

/11

∆% Week 10/
14/11

∆% Trough to 10/
14/11

DJIA

4/26/
10

7/2/10

-13.6

3.9

4.9

20.2

S&P 500

4/23/
10

7/20/
10

-16.0

0.6

5.9

19.8

NYSE Finance

4/15/
10

7/2/10

-20.3

-23.9

6.5

-4.5

Dow Global

4/15/
10

7/2/10

-18.4

-11.6

5.1

8.4

Asia Pacific

4/15/
10

7/2/10

-12.5

-8.3

3.3

4.8

Japan Nikkei Aver.

4/05/
10

8/31/
10

-22.5

-23.2

1.7

-0.9

China Shang.

4/15/
10

7/02
/10

-24.7

-23.2

3.1

2.0

STOXX 50

4/15/10

7/2/10

-15.3

-16.3

2.2

-1.1

DAX

4/26/
10

5/25/
10

-10.5

-5.8

5.1

5.2

Dollar
Euro

11/25 2009

6/7
2010

21.2

8.3

-3.7

-16.4

DJ UBS Comm.

1/6/
10

7/2/10

-14.5

2.2

4.5

19.5

10-Year Tre.

4/5/
10

4/6/10

3.986

2.251

   

T: trough; Dollar: positive sign appreciation relative to euro (less dollars paid per euro), negative sign depreciation relative to euro (more dollars paid per euro)

Source: http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/page/marketsdata.html?mod=WSJ_hps_marketdata

Bernanke (2010WP) and Yellen (2011AS) reveal the emphasis of monetary policy on the impact of the rise of stock market valuations in stimulating consumption by wealth effects on household confidence. Table 75 shows a gain by Apr 29, 2011 in the DJIA of 14.3 percent and of the S&P 500 of 12.5 percent since Apr 26, 2010, around the time when sovereign risk issues in Europe began to be acknowledged in financial risk asset valuations. The last row of Table 75 for Oct 14 shows that the S&P 500 is now 3.4 percent above the Apr 26, 2010 level and the DJIA is 3.9 percent above the level on Apr 26, 2010. Multiple rounds of risk aversion eroded the earlier gains, showing that risk aversion can destroy market value even with zero interest rates. Much the same as zero interest rates and quantitative easing have not had any effects in recovering economic activity while distorting financial markets and resource allocation.

Table 75, Percentage Changes of DJIA and S&P 500 in Selected Dates

2010

∆% DJIA from  prior date

∆% DJIA from
Apr 26

∆% S&P 500 from prior date

∆% S&P 500 from
Apr 26

Apr 26

       

May 6

-6.1

-6.1

-6.9

-6.9

May 26

-5.2

-10.9

-5.4

-11.9

Jun 8

-1.2

-11.3

2.1

-12.4

Jul 2

-2.6

-13.6

-3.8

-15.7

Aug 9

10.5

-4.3

10.3

-7.0

Aug 31

-6.4

-10.6

-6.9

-13.4

Nov 5

14.2

2.1

16.8

1.0

Nov 30

-3.8

-3.8

-3.7

-2.6

Dec 17

4.4

2.5

5.3

2.6

Dec 23

0.7

3.3

1.0

3.7

Dec 31

0.03

3.3

0.07

3.8

Jan 7

0.8

4.2

1.1

4.9

Jan 14

0.9

5.2

1.7

6.7

Jan 21

0.7

5.9

-0.8

5.9

Jan 28

-0.4

5.5

-0.5

5.3

Feb 4

2.3

7.9

2.7

8.1

Feb 11

1.5

9.5

1.4

9.7

Feb 18

0.9

10.6

1.0

10.8

Feb 25

-2.1

8.3

-1.7

8.9

Mar 4

0.3

8.6

0.1

9.0

Mar 11

-1.0

7.5

-1.3

7.6

Mar 18

-1.5

5.8

-1.9

5.5

Mar 25

3.1

9.1

2.7

8.4

Apr 1

1.3

10.5

1.4

9.9

Apr 8

0.03

10.5

-0.3

9.6

Apr 15

-0.3

10.1

-0.6

8.9

Apr 22

1.3

11.6

1.3

10.3

Apr 29

2.4

14.3

1.9

12.5

May 6

-1.3

12.8

-1.7

10.6

May 13

-0.3

12.4

-0.2

10.4

May 20

-0.7

11.7

-0.3

10.0

May 27

-0.6

11.0

-0.2

9.8

Jun 3

-2.3

8.4

-2.3

7.3

Jun 10

-1.6

6.7

-2.2

4.9

Jun 17

0.4

7.1

0.04

4.9

Jun 24

-0.6

6.5

-0.2

4.6

Jul 1

5.4

12.3

5.6

10.5

Jul 8

0.6

12.9

0.3

10.9

Jul 15

-1.4

11.4

-2.1

8.6

Jul 22

1.6

13.2

2.2

10.9

Jul 29

-4.2

8.4

-3.9

6.6

Aug 05

-5.8

2.1

-7.2

-1.0

Aug 12

-1.5

0.6

-1.7

-2.7

Aug 19

-4.0

-3.5

-4.7

-7.3

Aug 26

4.3

0.7

4.7

-2.9

Sep 02

-0.4

0.3

-0.2

-3.1

Sep 09

-2.2

-1.9

-1.7

-4.8

Sep 16

4.7

2.7

5.4

0.3

Sep 23

-6.4

-3.9

-6.5

-6.2

Sep 30

1.3

-2.6

-0.4

-6.7

Oct 7

1.7

-0.9

2.1

-4.7

Oct 14

4.9

3.9

5.9

3.4

Source: http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/public/page/mdc_us_stocks.html?mod=mdc_topnav_2_3014

Table 76, updated with every post, shows that exchange rate valuations affect a large variety of countries, in fact, almost the entire world, in magnitudes that cause major problems for domestic monetary policy and trade flows. Dollar devaluation is expected to continue because of zero fed funds rate, expectations of rising inflation, the large budget deficit of the federal government (http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052748703907004576279321350926848.html?mod=WSJ_hp_LEFTWhatsNewsCollection) and now zero interest rates indefinitely but with interruptions caused by risk aversion events. Such an event actually occurred in the week of Sep 23 reversing the devaluation of the dollar in the form of sharp appreciation of the dollar relative to other currencies from all over the world including the offshore Chinese yuan market. Column “Peak” in Table 76 shows exchange rates during the crisis year of 2008. There was a flight to safety in dollar-denominated government assets as a result of the arguments in favor of TARP (Cochrane and Zingales 2009). This is evident in various exchange rates that depreciated sharply against the dollar such as the South African rand (ZAR) at the peak of depreciation of ZAR 11.578/USD on Oct 22, 2008, subsequently appreciating to the trough of ZAR 7.238/USD by Aug 15, 2010 but now depreciating by 8.1 percent to ZAR 7.826/USD on Oct 14, which is still 32.4 percent stronger than on Oct 22, 2008. An example from Asia is the Singapore Dollar (SGD) highly depreciated at the peak of SGD 1.553/USD on Mar 3, 2009 but subsequently appreciating by 13.2 percent to the trough of SGD 1.348/USD on Aug 9, 2010 but is now only 6.2 percent stronger at SGD 1.265/USD on Oct 14 relative to the trough of depreciation but still stronger by 18.5 percent relative to the peak of depreciation on Mar 3, 2009. Another example is the Brazilian real (BRL) that depreciated at the peak to BRL 2.43 on Dec 5, 2008 but appreciated to the trough at BRL 1.737/USD on Apr 30, 2010, showing appreciation of only 0.2 percent relative to the trough to BRL 1.734/USD on Oct 14 but still stronger by 28.6 percent relative to the peak on Dec 5, 2008. At one point in 2011 the Brazilian real traded at BRL 1.55/USD and in the week of Sep 23 surpassed BRL 1.90/USD in intraday trading for depreciation of more than 20 percent. Unconventional monetary policy of zero interest rates and quantitative easing creates trends such as the depreciation of the dollar followed by Table 76 but with abrupt reversals during risk aversion. The main effects of unconventional monetary policy are on valuations of risk financial assets and not necessarily on consumption and investment or aggregate demand.

Table 76, Exchange Rates

 

Peak

Trough

∆% P/T

Oct 14,

2011

∆T

Oct 14  2011

∆P

Oct 14

2011

EUR USD

7/15
2008

6/7 2010

 

10/14

2011

   

Rate

1.59

1.192

 

1.387

   

∆%

   

-33.4

 

14.1

-14.6

JPY USD

8/18
2008

9/15
2010

 

10/14

2011

   

Rate

110.19

83.07

 

77.21

   

∆%

   

24.6

 

7.1

29.9

CHF USD

11/21 2008

12/8 2009

 

10/14

2011

   

Rate

1.225

1.025

 

0.894

   

∆%

   

16.3

 

12.7

27.0

USD GBP

7/15
2008

1/2/ 2009

 

10/14 2011

   

Rate

2.006

1.388

 

1.581

   

∆%

   

-44.5

 

12.2

-26.9

USD AUD

7/15 2008

10/27 2008

 

10/14
2011

   

Rate

1.0215

1.6639

 

1.034

   

∆%

   

-62.9

 

41.9

5.3

ZAR USD

10/22 2008

8/15
2010

 

10/14 2011

   

Rate

11.578

7.238

 

7.826

   

∆%

   

37.5

 

-8.1

32.4

SGD USD

3/3
2009

8/9
2010

 

10/14
2011

   

Rate

1.553

1.348

 

1.265

   

∆%

   

13.2

 

6.2

18.5

HKD USD

8/15 2008

12/14 2009

 

10/14
2011

   

Rate

7.813

7.752

 

7.776

   

∆%

   

0.8

 

-0.3

0.5

BRL USD

12/5 2008

4/30 2010

 

10/14

2011

   

Rate

2.43

1.737

 

1.734

   

∆%

   

28.5

 

0.2

28.6

CZK USD

2/13 2009

8/6 2010

 

10/14
2011

   

Rate

22.19

18.693

 

17.8075

   

∆%

   

15.7

 

4.7

19.7

SEK USD

3/4 2009

8/9 2010

 

10/14

2011

   

Rate

9.313

7.108

 

6.588

   

∆%

   

23.7

 

7.3

29.3

CNY USD

7/20 2005

7/15
2008

 

10/14
2011

   

Rate

8.2765

6.8211

 

6.379

   

∆%

   

17.6

 

6.5

22.9

Symbols: USD: US dollar; EUR: euro; JPY: Japanese yen; CHF: Swiss franc; GBP: UK pound; AUD: Australian dollar; ZAR: South African rand; SGD: Singapore dollar; HKD: Hong Kong dollar; BRL: Brazil real; CZK: Czech koruna; SEK: Swedish krona; CNY: Chinese yuan; P: peak; T: trough

Note: percentages calculated with currencies expressed in units of domestic currency per dollar; negative sign means devaluation and no sign appreciation

Source: http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/public/page/mdc_currencies.html?mod=mdc_topnav_2_3000

http://federalreserve.gov/releases/h10/Hist/dat00_ch.htm

Table 77, updated with every blog comment, provides in the second column the yield at the close of market of the 10-year Treasury note on the date in the first column. The price in the third column is calculated with the coupon of 2.625 percent of the 10-year note current at the time of the second round of quantitative easing after Nov 3, 2010 and the final column “∆% 11/04/10” calculates the percentage change of the price on the date relative to that of 101.2573 at the close of market on Nov 4, 2010, one day after the decision on quantitative easing by the Fed on Nov 3, 2010. Prices with new coupons such as 3.63 percent in recent auctions (http://www.treasurydirect.gov/instit/annceresult/press/preanre/2011/2011.htm) are not comparable to prices in Table 77. The highest yield in the decade was 5.510 percent on May 1, 2001 that would result in a loss of principal of 22.9 percent relative to the price on Nov 4. The Fed has created a “duration trap” of bond prices. Duration is the percentage change in bond price resulting from a percentage change in yield or what economists call the yield elasticity of bond price. Duration is higher the lower the bond coupon and yield, all other things constant. This means that the price loss in a yield rise from low coupons and yields is much higher than with high coupons and yields. Intuitively, the higher coupon payments offset part of the price loss. Prices/yields of Treasury securities were affected by the combination of Fed purchases for its program of quantitative easing and also by the flight to dollar-denominated assets because of geopolitical risks in the Middle East, subsequently by the tragic Great East earthquake and tsunami in Japan and now again by the sovereign risk doubts in Europe and the growth recession in the US and the world. The yield of 2.251 percent at the close of market on Fr Oct 14, 2011 would be equivalent to price of 103.3323 in a hypothetical bond maturing in 10 years with coupon of 2.625 percent for price gain of 2.0 percent relative to the price on Nov 4, 2010, one day after the decision on the second program of quantitative easing. If inflation accelerates, yields of Treasury securities may rise sharply. Yields are not observed without special yield-lowering effects such as the flight into dollars caused by the events in the Middle East, continuing purchases of Treasury securities by the Fed, the tragic Tōhoku or Great East Earthquake and Tsunami of Mar 11, 2011 earthquake and tsunami affecting Japan, recurring fears on European sovereign credit issues and worldwide risk aversion in the week of Sep 30 caused by “let’s twist again” monetary policy. The realization of a growth standstill recession is also influencing yields. Important causes of the earlier rise in yields shown in Table 77 are expectations of rising inflation and US government debt estimated to exceed 70 percent of GDP in 2012 (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/08/united-states-gdp-growth-standstill.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/02/policy-inflation-growth-unemployment.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/04/budget-quagmire-fed-commodities_10.html), rising from 40.8 percent of GDP in 2008, 53.5 percent in 2009 (Table 2 in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/04/budget-quagmire-fed-commodities_10.html) and 69 percent in 2011. On Oct 12, 2011, the line “Reserve Bank credit” in the Fed balance sheet stood at $2843 billion, or $2.8 trillion, with portfolio of long-term securities of $2619 billion, or $2.6 trillion, consisting of $1571 billion Treasury nominal notes and bonds, $69 billion of notes and bonds inflation-indexed, $108 billion Federal agency debt securities and $871 billion mortgage-backed securities; reserve balances deposited with Federal Reserve Banks reached $1625 billion or $1.6 trillion (http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h41/current/h41.htm#h41tab1). There is no simple exit of this trap created by the highest monetary policy accommodation in US history together with the highest deficits and debt in percent of GDP since World War II. Risk aversion from various sources, discussed in section III World Financial Turbulence, has been affecting financial markets for several weeks. The risk is that in a reversal of risk aversion that has been typical in this cyclical expansion of the economy yields of Treasury securities may back up sharply.

Table 77, Yield, Price and Percentage Change to November 4, 2010 of Ten-Year Treasury Note

Date

Yield

Price

∆% 11/04/10

05/01/01

5.510

78.0582

-22.9

06/10/03

3.112

95.8452

-5.3

06/12/07

5.297

79.4747

-21.5

12/19/08

2.213

104.4981

3.2

12/31/08

2.240

103.4295

2.1

03/19/09

2.605

100.1748

-1.1

06/09/09

3.862

89.8257

-11.3

10/07/09

3.182

95.2643

-5.9

11/27/09

3.197

95.1403

-6.0

12/31/09

3.835

90.0347

-11.1

02/09/10

3.646

91.5239

-9.6

03/04/10

3.605

91.8384

-9.3

04/05/10

3.986

88.8726

-12.2

08/31/10

2.473

101.3338

0.08

10/07/10

2.385

102.1224

0.8

10/28/10

2.658

99.7119

-1.5

11/04/10

2.481

101.2573

-

11/15/10

2.964

97.0867

-4.1

11/26/10

2.869

97.8932

-3.3

12/03/10

3.007

96.7241

-4.5

12/10/10

3.324

94.0982

-7.1

12/15/10

3.517

92.5427

-8.6

12/17/10

3.338

93.9842

-7.2

12/23/10

3.397

93.5051

-7.7

12/31/10

3.228

94.3923

-6.7

01/07/11

3.322

94.1146

-7.1

01/14/11

3.323

94.1064

-7.1

01/21/11

3.414

93.4687

-7.7

01/28/11

3.323

94.1064

-7.1

02/04/11

3.640

91.750

-9.4

02/11/11

3.643

91.5319

-9.6

02/18/11

3.582

92.0157

-9.1

02/25/11

3.414

93.3676

-7.8

03/04/11

3.494

92.7235

-8.4

03/11/11

3.401

93.4727

-7.7

03/18/11

3.273

94.5115

-6.7

03/25/11

3.435

93.1935

-7.9

04/01/11

3.445

93.1129

-8.0

04/08/11

3.576

92.0635

-9.1

04/15/11

3.411

93.3874

-7.8

04/22/11

3.402

93.4646

-7.7

04/29/11

3.290

94.3759

-6.8

05/06/11

3.147

95.5542

-5.6

05/13/11

3.173

95.3387

-5.8

05/20/11

3.146

95.5625

-5.6

05/27/11

3.068

96.2089

-4.9

06/03/11

2.990

96.8672

-4.3

06/10/11

2.973

97.0106

-4.2

06/17/11

2.937

97.3134

-3.9

06/24/11

2.872

97.8662

-3.3

07/01/11

3.186

95.2281

-5.9

07/08/11

3.022

96.5957

-4.6

07/15/11

2.905

97.5851

-3.6

07/22/11

2.964

97.0847

-4.1

07/29/11

2.795

98.5258

-2.7

08/05/11

2.566

100.5175

-0.7

08/12/11

2.249

103.3504

2.1

08/19/11

2.066

105.270

3.7

08/26/11

2.202

103.7781

2.5

09/02/11

1.992

105.7137

4.4

09/09/11

1.918

106.4055

5.1

09/16/11

2.053

101.5434

0.3

09/23/11

1.826

107.2727

5.9

09/30/11

1.912

106.4602

5.1

10/07/11

2.078

104.9161

3.6

10/14/11

2.251

103.3323

2.0

Note: price is calculated for an artificial 10-year note paying semi-annual coupon and maturing in ten years using the actual yields traded on the dates and the coupon of 2.625% on 11/04/10

Source:

http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/public/page/mdc_bonds.html?mod=mdc_topnav_2_3000

VI Economic Indicators. Crude oil input in refineries fell to 15,032 thousand barrels per day on average in the four weeks ending on Oct 7 from 15,153 thousand barrels per day in the four weeks ending on Sep 30, as shown in Table 78. The rate of capacity utilization in refineries continues at a high level of 87.0 percent, which is slightly higher than on Oct 8, 2010 at 84.6 percent. Imports of crude oil rose from 8,788 thousand barrels per day on average to 8,924 thousand barrels per day. Decreasing utilization in refineries with increasing imports resulted in increase of commercial crude oil stocks by 1.3 million barrels from 336.3 million barrels on Sep 30 to 337.6 million on Oct 7. Gasoline stocks fell 4.1 million barrels and stocks of fuel oil fell 2.9 million barrels. Supply of gasoline fell from 9,008 thousand barrels per day on Oct 8, 2010, to 8,948 thousand barrels per day on Oct 7, 2011, or by 0.7 percent, while fuel oil supply rose 5.6 percent. Part of the fall in consumption of gasoline is due to higher prices and part to the growth recession. Table 78 also shows increase in the world price of crude oil by 23.9 percent from Oct 8, 2010 to Oct 7, 2011. Gasoline prices rose 21.2 percent from Oct 11, 2010 to Oct 10, 2011. Increases in prices of crude oil and gasoline relative to a year earlier are moderating because year earlier prices are already reflecting the commodity price surge and commodity prices have been declining recently during worldwide risk aversion.

Table 78, US, Energy Information Administration Weekly Petroleum Status Report

Four Weeks Ending Thousand Barrels/Day

10/07/11

09/30/11

10/08/10

Crude Oil Refineries Input

15,032

15,153

14,446

Refinery Capacity Utilization %

87.0

87.7

84.6

Motor Gasoline Production

9,139

9,250

8,919

Distillate Fuel Oil Production

4,528

4,548

4,249

Crude Oil Imports

8,924

8,788

8,812

Motor Gasoline Supplied

8,948

∆% 2011/2010=

–-0.7%

8,907

9,008

Distillate Fuel Oil Supplied

3,965

∆% 2011/2010

= 5.6%

3,863

3,754

 

010/07/11

09/30/11

10/08/10

Crude Oil Stocks
Million B

337.6
∆= 1.3 MB

336.3

360.5

Motor Gasoline Million B

209.6
∆= -4.1 MB

213.7

218.2

Distillate Fuel Oil Million B

154.0
∆= -2.9 MB

156.9

172.2

World Crude Oil Price $/B

100.28

∆% 2011/2010

23.9

103.17

80.89

 

10/10/11

10/03/11

10/11/10

Regular Motor Gasoline $/G

3.417

∆% 2011/2010
21.2

3.433

2.819

B: barrels; G: gallon

Source: http://www.eia.gov/pub/oil_gas/petroleum/data_publications/weekly_petroleum_status_report/current/pdf/highlights.pdf

Chart 43 of the US Energy Information Administration shows the commercial stocks of crude oil of the US. There have been fluctuations around an upward trend since 2005. Crude oil stocks have trended down in the past few weeks with an increase in the week of Oct 7.

clip_image075

Chart 43, US, Weekly Crude Oil Ending Stocks

Source: US Energy Information Administration

http://www.eia.gov/dnav/pet/hist/LeafHandler.ashx?n=PET&s=WCESTUS1&f=W

Chart 44 of the US Energy Information Administration provides closer view of US crude oil stocks since Dec 2009. Crude oil stocks rose in a clear trend throughout 2010 but began to drop on a downward trend since May 2011.  The last point in the curve is the increase in the week of Oct 7.

clip_image076

Chart 44, Crude Oil Futures

Source: US Energy Information Administration

http://www.eia.gov/dnav/pet/hist/LeafHandler.ashx?n=PET&s=RCLC1&f=D

Chart 45 of the US Energy Information Administration shows the price of WTI crude oil since the 1980s. Chart 45 captures commodity price shocks during the past decade. The costly mirage of deflation was caused by the decline in oil prices resulting from the recession of 2001. The upward trend after 2003 was promoted by the carry trade from near zero interest rates. The jump above $140/barrel during the global recession in 2008 can only be explained by the carry trade promoted by monetary policy collapsing to zero. After moderation of risk aversion, the carry trade returned with resulting sharp upward trend of crude prices.

clip_image045[2]

Chart 45, US, Crude Oil Stocks

Source: US Energy Information Administration

http://www.eia.gov/todayinenergy/detail.cfm?id=3371

There is significant difference between initial claims for unemployment insurance adjusted and not adjusted for seasonality provided in Table 79. Seasonally adjusted claims fell 1000 from 405,000 on Oct 1 to 404,000 on Oct 8. Claims not adjusted for seasonality rose 66,442 from 332,394 on Oct 1 to 398,836 on Oct 8. Seasonal adjustment changed increase in initial claims from 66,442 to decrease of 1000. 

Table 79, US, Initial Claims for Unemployment Insurance

2011

SA

NSA

4-week MA SA

Oct 8

404,000

398,836

408,000

Oct 1

405,000

332,394

415,000

Change

-1,000

+66,442

-7.000

Sep 24

395,000

328,073

418,000

Prior Year

463,000

462,667

456,250

Note: SA: seasonally adjusted; NSA: not seasonally adjusted; MA: moving average

Source: http://www.dol.gov/opa/media/press/eta/ui/current.htm

Table 80 provides seasonally and not seasonally adjusted claims in the comparable week for the years from 2000 to 2011. Seasonally adjusted claims typically exceed claims not adjusted for seasonality. 

Table 80, US, Unemployment Insurance Weekly Claims

 

Not Seasonally Adjusted Claims

Seasonally Adjusted Claims

Oct 7, 2000

292,784

309,000

Oct 6, 2001

441,754

476,000

Oct 5, 2002

365,613

404,000

Oct 11, 2003

368,876

376,000

Oct 9, 2004

338,711

338,000

Oct 8, 2005

380,093

383,000

Oct 10, 2006

307,646

316,000

Oct 6, 2007

298,317

317,000

Oct 11, 2008

454,100

462,000

Oct 10, 2009

513,852

515,000

Oct 9, 2010

462,667

463,000

Oct 8, 2011

398,836

404,000

Source: http://workforcesecurity.doleta.gov/unemploy/finance.asp

VII Interest Rates. It is quite difficult to measure inflationary expectations because they tend to break abruptly from past inflation. There could still be an influence of past and current inflation in the calculation of future inflation by economic agents. Table 81 provides inflation of the CPI. In Jan-Aug 2011, CPI inflation for all items seasonally adjusted was 4.1 percent in annual equivalent, that is, compounding inflation in the first eight months and assuming it would be repeated during the remainder of 2011. In the 12 months ending in Aug, CPI inflation of all items not seasonally adjusted was 3.8 percent. The second row provides the same measurements for the CPI of all items excluding food and energy: 2.6 percent annual equivalent in Jan-Aug and 2.0 percent in 12 months. Bloomberg provides the yield curve of US Treasury securities (http://www.bloomberg.com/markets/rates-bonds/government-bonds/us/). The lowest yield is 0.02 percent for three months or virtually zero, 0.05 percent for six months, 0.10 percent for 12 months, 0.27 percent for two years, 0.52 percent for three years, 1.14 percent for five years, 1.73 percent for seven years, 2.27 percent for ten years and 3.25 percent for 30 years. The Irving Fisher definition of real interest rates is approximately the difference between nominal interest rates, which are those estimated by Bloomberg, and the rate of inflation expected in the term of the security, which could behave as in Table 81. Real interest rates in the US have been negative during substantial periods in the past decade while monetary policy pursues a policy of attaining its “dual mandate” of (http://www.federalreserve.gov/aboutthefed/mission.htm):

“Conducting the nation's monetary policy by influencing the monetary and credit conditions in the economy in pursuit of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates”

Negative real rates of interest distort calculations of risk and returns from capital budgeting by firms, through lending by financial intermediaries to decisions on savings, housing and purchases of households. Inflation on near zero interest rates misallocates resources away from their most productive uses and creates uncertainty of the future path of adjustment to higher interest rates that inhibit sound decisions.

Table 81, US, Consumer Price Index Percentage Changes 12 months NSA and Annual Equivalent ∆%

 

∆% 12 Months Aug 2011/Aug
2010 NSA

∆% Annual Equivalent Jan-Aug 2011 SA

CPI All Items

3.8

4.1

CPI ex Food and Energy

2.0

2.6

Source: http://www.bls.gov/news.release/pdf/cpi.pdf

IX Conclusion. The US economy is in growth standstill at an annual equivalent rate in the first half of 0.8 percent. Real disposable income has stagnated. Nominal personal income fell in Aug. There are around 29 million people in the US unemployed or underemployed. Real wages are falling. There is no exit from unemployment, underemployment and falling real wages because of the collapse of hiring. The euro is fighting for survival. The crucial issue of “let’s twist again “monetary policy is if lowering the yields of long-term Treasury securities would have any impact on investment and consumption or aggregate demand. The decline of long-term yields of Treasury securities would have to cause decline of yields of asset-backed securities used to securitize loans for investment by firms and purchase of durable goods by consumers. The decline in costs of investment and consumption of durable goods would ultimately have to result in higher investment and consumption. It is possible that the decline in yields captured by event studies is ephemeral. The decline in yields just after “let’s twist again” monetary policy was caused by the flight out of risk financial assets into Treasury securities, which is the opposite of the desired effect of encouraging risk-taking in asset-backed securities and lending. The yield curve has edged upwardly in spite of “let’s twist again monetary policy” (Go to http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/ http://sites.google.com/site/economicregulation/carlos-m-pelaez)

http://www.amazon.com/Carlos-Manuel-Pel%C3%A1ez/e/B001HCUT10 ).

References

Ball, Laurence and N. Gregory Mankiw. 2002. The NAIRU in theory and practice. Journal of Economic Perspectives 16 (4, Autumn): 115-36.

Batini, Nicoletta and Edward Nelson. 2002. The lag from monetary policy actions to inflation: Friedman revisited. London, Bank of England, External MPC Unit Discussion Paper No. 6, Jan.

Bernanke, Ben S. 2010WP. What the Fed did and why: supporting the recovery and sustaining price stability. Washington Post, Nov 4. http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/article/2010/11/03/AR2010110307372_pf.html

Bernanke, Ben S. 2011Oct4JEC. Statement. Washington, DC, Joint Economic Committee, US Congress, Oct 4 http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/bernanke20111004a.pdf

Blanchard, Olivier and Lawrence F. Katz. 1997. What we know and do not know about the natural rate of unemployment. Journal of Economic Perspectives 11 (1, Winter): 51-72.

Blinder, Alan S. 2011Sep28. Ben Bernanke deserves a break. Wall Street Journal Sep 28 http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052970204422404576594682273860392.html?mod=WSJ_hps_sections_opinion

Cochrane, John H. 2011Jan. Understanding policy in the great recession: some unpleasant fiscal arithmetic. European Economic Review 55 (1, Jan): 2-30.

Cochrane, John H. 2011Sep28. Last chance to save the euro. Wall Street Journal, Sep 28 http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052970204422404576594971418554358.html?mod=WSJ_hps_sections_opinion

Cochrane, John H. and Luigi Zingales. 2009. Lehman and the financial crisis. Wall Street Journal, Sep 15.

Culbertson, J. M. 1960. Friedman on the lag in effect of monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy 68 (6, Dec): 617-21.

Culbertson, J. M. 1961. The lag in effect of monetary policy: reply. Journal of Political Economy 69 (5, Oct): 467-77.

Darity, Jr. William and Dania Frank. 2003. The economics of reparations. American Economic Review 93 (2, May): 326-39.

Davies, Gavyn. 2011Sep28. Leveraging the EFSF is attractive but risky. Financial Times, Sep 28 http://blogs.ft.com/gavyndavies/2011/09/28/leveraging-the-efsf-is-attractive-but-risky/#axzz1ZFHhDQkK

De Long, J. Bradford. 1997. America’s peacetime inflation: the 1970s. In Christina D. Romer and David H. Romer, eds. Reducing inflation: motivation and strategy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1997.

Friedman, Milton. 1961. The lag in effect of monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy 69 (5, Oct): 447-66.

Hicks, John R. 1975. The scope and status of welfare economics. Oxford Economic Papers 27 (3): 307.

Johnson, Harry G. 1975. The classical transfer problem: an alternative formulation. Economica 42 (165, Feb): 20-31.

Keynes, John Maynard. 1929. The German transfer problem. Economic Journal 39 (153, Mar): 1-7.

Keynes, John Maynard. 1929R. A rejoinder. Economic Journal 39 (154, Jun): 179-182.

Lane, Philip R. and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti. 2004. Review of Economics and Statistics 86 (4, Nov): 841-57.

McKinnon, Ronald. 2011Sep30. Where are the bond vigilantes? Wall Street Journal, Sep 30 http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424053111904332804576538363789127084.html?mod=WSJ_hps_sections_opinion

Meltzer, Allan H. 2005. Origins of the Great Inflation. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 87 (2, Part 2, Mar/Apr): 145-72.

Meltzer, Allan H. 2010a. A history of the Federal Reserve, Volume 2, Book 1, 1951-1969. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Meltzer, Allan H. 2010b. A history of the Federal Reserve, Volume 2, Book 2, 1970-1986. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Metzler, Lloyd A. The nature and stability of inventory cycles. 1941. Review of Economics and Statistics 23 (3, Aug): 113-29.

Pelaez, Carlos M. and Carlos A. Pelaez. 2005. International Financial Architecture. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. http://us.macmillan.com/QuickSearchResults.aspx?search=pelaez%2C+carlos&ctl00%24ctl00%24cphContent%24ucAdvSearch%24imgGo.x=26&ctl00%24ctl00%24cphContent%24ucAdvSearch%24imgGo.y=14 http://www.amazon.com/Carlos-Manuel-Pel%C3%A1ez/e/B001HCUT10

Pelaez, Carlos M. and Carlos A. Pelaez. 2007. The Global Recession Risk. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. http://www.amazon.com/Carlos-Manuel-Pel%C3%A1ez/e/B001HCUT10

Pelaez, Carlos M. and Carlos A. Pelaez. 2008a. Globalization and the State: Vol. I. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. http://www.amazon.com/Carlos-Manuel-Pel%C3%A1ez/e/B001HCUT10

Pelaez, Carlos M. and Carlos A. Pelaez. 2008b. Globalization and the State: Vol. II. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

Pelaez, Carlos M. and Carlos A. Pelaez. 2008c. Government Intervention in Globalization. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. http://www.amazon.com/Carlos-Manuel-Pel%C3%A1ez/e/B001HCUT10

Pelaez, Carlos M. and Carlos A. Pelaez. 2009a. Financial Regulation after the Global Recession. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. http://www.amazon.com/Carlos-Manuel-Pel%C3%A1ez/e/B001HCUT10

Pelaez, Carlos M. and Carlos A. Pelaez. 2009b. Regulation of Banks and Finance. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.http://www.amazon.com/Carlos-Manuel-Pel%C3%A1ez/e/B001HCUT10

Pelaez, Carlos Manuel. 1986. O Cruzado e o Austral. São Paulo: Editora Atlas.

Plosser, Charles I. 2011Sep29. Economic outlook. Villanova, PA: Villanova School of Business, Sep 29 http://www.philadelphiafed.org/publications/speeches/plosser/2011/09-29-11_business-leaders-forum-villanova.pdf

Reinhart, Carmen M. and Kenneth Rogoff. 2010GTD. Growth in a time of debt. American Economic Review 100 (2): 1-9.

Robinson, Joan. 1947. Beggar-my-neighbour remedies for unemployment. In Joan Robinson, Essays in the Theory of Employment, Oxford, Basil Blackwell, 1947.

Romer, Christina D. and David H. Romer. 2004. A new measure of monetary shocks: derivation and implications. American Economic Review 94 (4, Sep): 1055-84.

Samuelson, Paul A. 1952. The transfer problem and transport costs: the terms of trade when impediments are absent. Economic Journal 62 (246, Jun): 278-304.

Samuelson, Paul A. 1974. Lessons from the current economic expansion. American Economic Review 64 (2, May): 75-7.

Taylor, John B. 1997. Comment. In Christina Romer and David Romer, eds. Reducing inflation: motivation and strategy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Wriston, Walter B. 1982. Banking against disaster. New York Times, Sep 14.

Yellen, Janet L. 2011AS. The Federal’s Reserve’s asset purchase program. Denver, Colorado, Allied Social Science Association Annual Meeting, Jan 8 http://federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20110108a.pdf

© Carlos M. Pelaez, 2010, 2011

Appendix I. The Great Inflation

Inflation and unemployment in the period 1966 to 1985 is analyzed by Cochrane (2011Jan, 23) by means of a Phillips circuit joining points of inflation and unemployment. Chart I1 for Brazil in Pelaez (1986, 94-5) was reprinted in The Economist in the issue of Jan 17-23, 1987 as updated by the author. Cochrane (2011Jan, 23) argues that the Phillips circuit shows the weakness in Phillips curve correlation. The explanation is by a shift in aggregate supply, rise in inflation expectations or loss of anchoring. The case of Brazil in Chart I1 cannot be explained without taking into account the increase in the fed funds rate that reached 22.36 percent on Jul 22, 1981 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/data.htm) in the Volcker Fed that precipitated the stress on a foreign debt bloated by financing balance of payments deficits with bank loans in the 1970s; the loans were used in projects, many of state-owned enterprises with low present value in long gestation. The combination of the insolvency of the country because of debt higher than its ability of repayment and the huge government deficit with declining revenue as the economy contracted caused adverse expectations on inflation and the economy.  This interpretation is consistent with the case of the 24 emerging market economies analyzed by Reinhart and Rogoff (2010GTD, 4), concluding that “higher debt levels are associated with significantly higher levels of inflation in emerging markets. Median inflation more than doubles (from less than seven percent to 16 percent) as debt rises from the low (0 to 30 percent) range to above 90 percent. Fiscal dominance is a plausible interpretation of this pattern.”

The reading of the Phillips circuits of the 1970s by Cochrane (2011Jan, 25) is doubtful about the output gap and inflation expectations:

“So, inflation is caused by ‘tightness’ and deflation by ‘slack’ in the economy. This is not just a cause and forecasting variable, it is the cause, because given ‘slack’ we apparently do not have to worry about inflation from other sources, notwithstanding the weak correlation of [Phillips circuits]. These statements [by the Fed] do mention ‘stable inflation expectations. How does the Fed know expectations are ‘stable’ and would not come unglued once people look at deficit numbers? As I read Fed statements, almost all confidence in ‘stable’ or ‘anchored’ expectations comes from the fact that we have experienced a long period of low inflation (adaptive expectations). All these analyses ignore the stagflation experience in the 1970s, in which inflation was high even with ‘slack’ markets and little ‘demand, and ‘expectations’ moved quickly. They ignore the experience of hyperinflations and currency collapses, which happen in economies well below potential.”

Chart I1, Brazil, Phillips Circuit 1963-1987

clip_image077

©Carlos Manuel Pelaez, O cruzado e o austral. São Paulo: Editora Atlas, 1986, pages 94-5. Reprinted in: Brazil. Tomorrow’s Italy, The Economist, 17-23 January 1987, page 25.

DeLong (1997, 247-8) shows that the 1970s were the only peacetime period of inflation in the US without parallel in the prior century. The price level in the US drifted upward since 1896 with jumps resulting from the two world wars: “on this scale, the inflation of the 1970s was as large an increase in the price level relative to drift as either of this century’s major wars” (DeLong, 1997, 248). Monetary policy focused on accommodating higher inflation, with emphasis solely on the mandate of promoting employment, has been blamed as deliberate or because of model error or imperfect measurement for creating the Great Inflation (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/05/slowing-growth-global-inflation-great.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/04/new-economics-of-rose-garden-turned.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/03/is-there-second-act-of-us-great.html). As DeLong (1997) shows, the Great Inflation began in the mid 1960s, well before the oil shocks of the 1970s (see also the comment to DeLong 1997 by Taylor 1997, 276-7). TableI1 provides the change in GDP, CPI and the rate of unemployment from 1960 to 1990. There are three waves of inflation (1) in the second half of the 1960s; (2) from 1973 to 1975; and (3) from 1978 to 1981. In one of his multiple important contributions to understanding the Great Inflation, Meltzer (2005) distinguishes between one-time price jumps, such as by oil shocks, and a “maintained” inflation rate. Meltzer (2005) uses a dummy variable to extract the one-time oil price changes, resulting in a maintained inflation rate that was never higher than 8 to 10 percent in the 1970s. There is revealing analysis of the Great Inflation and its reversal by Meltzer (2005, 2010a, 2010b).

Table I1, US Annual Rate of Growth of GDP and CPI and Unemployment Rate 1960-1982

 

∆% GDP

∆% CPI

UNE

1960

2.5

1.4

6.6

1961

2.3

0.7

6.0

1962

6.1

1.3

5.5

1963

4.4

1.6

5.5

1964

5.8

1.0

5.0

1965

6.4

1.9

4.0

1966

6.5

3.5

3.8

1967

2.5

3.0

3.8

1968

4.8

4.7

3.4

1969

3.1

6.2

3.5

1970

0.2

5.6

6.1

1971

3.4

3.3

6.0

1972

5.3

3.4

5.2

1973

5.8

8.7

4.9

1974

-0.6

12.3

7.2

1975

-0.2

6.9

8.2

1976

5.4

4.9

7.8

1977

4.6

6.7

6.4

1978

5.6

9.0

6.0

1979

3.1

13.3

6.0

1980

-0.3

12.5

7.2

1981

2.5

8.9

8.5

1982

-1.9

3.8

10.8

1983

4.5

3.8

8.3

1984

7.2

3.9

7.3

1985

4.1

3.8

7.0

1986

3.5

1.1

6.6

1987

3.2

4.4

5.7

1988

4.1

4.4

5,3

1989

3.6

4.6

5.4

1990

1.9

6.1

6.3

Note: GDP: Gross Domestic Product; CPI: consumer price index; UNE: rate of unemployment; CPI and UNE are at year end instead of average to obtain a complete series

Source: ftp://ftp.bls.gov/pub/special.requests/cpi/cpiai.txt

http://www.bea.gov/national/nipaweb/TableView.asp?SelectedTable=2&ViewSeries=NO&Java=no&Request3Place=N&3Place=N&FromView=YES&Freq=Year&FirstYear=2009&LastYear=2010&3Place=N&Update=Update&JavaBox=no

http://www.bls.gov/web/empsit/cpseea01.htm

http://data.bls.gov/pdq/SurveyOutputServlet

There is a false impression of the existence of a monetary policy “science,” measurements and forecasting with which to steer the economy into “prosperity without inflation.” Market participants are remembering the Great Bond Crash of 1994 shown in Table I2 when monetary policy pursued nonexistent inflation, causing trillions of dollars of losses in fixed income worldwide while increasing the fed funds rate from 3 percent in Jan 1994 to 6 percent in Dec. The exercise in Table I2 shows a drop of the price of the 30-year bond by 18.1 percent and of the 10-year bond by 14.1 percent. CPI inflation remained almost the same and there is no valid counterfactual that inflation would have been higher without monetary policy tightening because of the long lag in effect of monetary policy on inflation (see Culbertson 1960, 1961, Friedman 1961, Batini and Nelson 2002, Romer and Romer 2004). The pursuit of nonexistent deflation during the past ten years has resulted in the largest monetary policy accommodation in history that created the 2007 financial market crash and global recession and is currently preventing smoother recovery while creating another financial crash in the future. The issue is not whether there should be a central bank and monetary policy but rather whether policy accommodation in doses from zero interest rates to trillions of dollars in the fed balance sheet endangers economic stability.

Table I2, Fed Funds Rates, Thirty and Ten Year Treasury Yields and Prices, 30-Year Mortgage Rates and 12-month CPI Inflation 1994

1994

FF

30Y

30P

10Y

10P

MOR

CPI

Jan

3.00

6.29

100

5.75

100

7.06

2.52

Feb

3.25

6.49

97.37

5.97

98.36

7.15

2.51

Mar

3.50

6.91

92.19

6.48

94.69

7.68

2.51

Apr

3.75

7.27

88.10

6.97

91.32

8.32

2.36

May

4.25

7.41

86.59

7.18

88.93

8.60

2.29

Jun

4.25

7.40

86.69

7.10

90.45

8.40

2.49

Jul

4.25

7.58

84.81

7.30

89.14

8.61

2.77

Aug

4.75

7.49

85.74

7.24

89.53

8.51

2.69

Sep

4.75

7.71

83.49

7.46

88.10

8.64

2.96

Oct

4.75

7.94

81.23

7.74

86.33

8.93

2.61

Nov

5.50

8.08

79.90

7.96

84.96

9.17

2.67

Dec

6.00

7.87

81.91

7.81

85.89

9.20

2.67

Notes: FF: fed funds rate; 30Y: yield of 30-year Treasury; 30P: price of 30-year Treasury assuming coupon equal to 6.29 percent and maturity in exactly 30 years; 10Y: yield of 10-year Treasury; 10P: price of 10-year Treasury assuming coupon equal to 5.75 percent and maturity in exactly 10 years; MOR: 30-year mortgage; CPI: percent change of CPI in 12 months

Sources: yields and mortgage rates http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/data.htm CPI ftp://ftp.bls.gov/pub/special.requests/cpi/cpiai.t

© Carlos M. Pelaez, 2010, 2011

No comments:

Post a Comment