Recovery without Hiring, Ten Million Fewer Full-time Jobs, Record High Youth and Middle-Aged Unemployment, Financial Turbulence and World Economic Slowdown with Global Recession Risk
Carlos M. Pelaez
© Carlos M. Pelaez, 2010, 2011, 2012
Executive Summary
I Recovery without Hiring
IA Hiring Collapse
IB Labor Underutilization
IC Ten Million Fewer Full-time Jobs
ID Youth and Middle-Aged Unemployment
II United States International Trade
IIA United States International Trade Balance
IIB United States Import and Export Prices
III World Financial Turbulence
IIIA Financial Risks
IIIB Appendix on Safe Haven Currencies
IIIC Appendix on Fiscal Compact
IIID Appendix on European Central Bank Large Scale Lender of Last Resort
IIIE Appendix Euro Zone Survival Risk
IIIF Appendix on Sovereign Bond Valuation
IIIG Appendix on Deficit Financing of Growth and the Debt Crisis
IIIGA Monetary Policy with Deficit Financing of Economic Growth
IIIGB Adjustment during the Debt Crisis of the 1980s
IV Global Inflation
V World Economic Slowdown
VA United States
VB Japan
VC China
VD Euro Area
VE Germany
VF France
VG Italy
VH United Kingdom
VI Valuation of Risk Financial Assets
VII Economic Indicators
VIII Interest Rates
IX Conclusion
References
Appendix I The Great Inflation
Executive Summary
ESI Recovery without Hiring. Professor Edward P. Lazear (2012Jan19) at Stanford University finds that recovery of hiring in the US to peaks attained in 2007 requires an increase of hiring by 30 percent while hiring levels have increased by only 4 percent since Jan 2009. The high level of unemployment with low level of hiring reduces the statistical probability that the unemployed will find a job. According to Lazear (2012Jan19), the probability of finding a new job currently is about one third of the probability of finding a job in 2007. Improvements in labor markets have not increased the probability of finding a new job. Lazear (2012Jan19) quotes an essay coauthored with James R. Spletzer forthcoming in the American Economic Review on the concept of churn. A dynamic labor market occurs when a similar amount of workers is hired as those who are separated. This replacement of separated workers is called churn, which explains about two-thirds of total hiring. Typically, wage increases received in a new job are higher by 8 percent. Lazear (2012Jan19) argues that churn has declined 35 percent from the level before the recession in IVQ2007. Because of the collapse of churn there are no opportunities in escaping falling real wages by moving to another job. As this blog argues, there are meager chances of escaping unemployment because of the collapse of hiring and those employed cannot escape falling real wages by moving to another job (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/08/twenty-nine-million-unemployed-or.html ). Lazear and Spletzer (2012Mar, 1) argue that reductions of churn reduce the operational effectiveness of labor markets. Churn is part of the allocation of resources or in this case labor to occupations of higher marginal returns. The decline in churn can harm static and dynamic economic efficiency. Losses from decline of churn during recessions can affect an economy over the long-term by preventing optimal growth trajectories because resources are not used in the occupations where they provide highest marginal returns. Lazear and Spletzer (2012Mar 7-8) conclude that: “under a number of assumptions, we estimate that the loss in output during the recession [of 2007 to 2009] and its aftermath resulting from reduced churn equaled $208 billion. On an annual basis, this amounts to about .4% of GDP for a period of 3½ years.”
There are two additional facts discussed below: (1) there are about ten million fewer full-time jobs currently than before the recession of 2008 and 2009; and (2) the extremely high and rigid rate of youth unemployment is denying an early start to young people ages 16 to 24 years while unemployment of ages 45 years or over has swelled.
An important characteristic of the current fractured labor market of the US is the closing of the avenue for exiting unemployment and underemployment normally available through dynamic hiring. Another avenue that is closed is the opportunity for advancement in moving to new jobs that pay better salaries and benefits again because of the collapse of hiring in the United States. Those who are unemployed or underemployed cannot find a new job even accepting lower wages and no benefits. The employed cannot escape declining inflation-adjusted earnings because there is no hiring. The objective of this section is to analyze hiring and labor underutilization in the United States.
An appropriate measure of job stress is considered by Blanchard and Katz (1997, 53):
“The right measure of the state of the labor market is the exit rate from unemployment, defined as the number of hires divided by the number unemployed, rather than the unemployment rate itself. What matters to the unemployed is not how many of them there are, but how many of them there are in relation to the number of hires by firms.”
The natural rate of unemployment and the similar NAIRU are quite difficult to estimate in practice (Ibid; see Ball and Mankiw 2002).
The Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) created the Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey (JOLTS) with the purpose that (http://www.bls.gov/jlt/jltover.htm#purpose):
“These data serve as demand-side indicators of labor shortages at the national level. Prior to JOLTS, there was no economic indicator of the unmet demand for labor with which to assess the presence or extent of labor shortages in the United States. The availability of unfilled jobs—the jobs opening rate—is an important measure of tightness of job markets, parallel to existing measures of unemployment.”
The BLS collects data from about 16,000 US business establishments in nonagricultural industries through the 50 states and DC. The data are released monthly and constitute an important complement to other data provided by the BLS (see also Lazear and Spletzer 2012Mar, 6-7).
Hiring in the nonfarm sector (HNF) has declined from 69.4 million in 2004 to 50.1 million in 2011 or by 19.3 million while hiring in the private sector (HP) has declined from 59.5 million in 2006 to 46.9 million in 2011 or by 12.6 million, as shown in Table ESI-1. The ratio of nonfarm hiring to employment (RNF) has fallen from 47.2 in 2005 to 38.1 in 2011 and in the private sector (RHP) from 52.1 in 2006 to 42.9 in 2011. The collapse of hiring in the US has not been followed by dynamic labor markets because of the low rate of economic growth of 2.2 percent in the first twelve quarters of expansion from IIIQ2009 to IIQ2012 compared with 6.2 percent in prior cyclical expansions (see table I-5 in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/07/decelerating-united-states-recovery.html).
Table ESI-1, US, Annual Total Nonfarm Hiring (HNF) and Total Private Hiring (HP) in the US and Percentage of Total Employment
Percentage of Total Employment
HNF | Rate RNF | HP | Rate HP | |
2001 | 62,948 | 47.8 | 58,825 | 53.1 |
2002 | 58,583 | 44.9 | 54,759 | 50.3 |
2003 | 56,451 | 43.4 | 53,056 | 48.9 |
2004 | 69,367 | 45.9 | 56,617 | 51.6 |
2005 | 63,150 | 47.2 | 59,372 | 53.1 |
2006 | 63,773 | 46.9 | 59,494 | 52.1 |
2007 | 62,421 | 45.4 | 58,035 | 50.3 |
2008 | 55,166 | 40.3 | 51,606 | 45.2 |
2009 | 46,398 | 35.5 | 43,052 | 39.8 |
2010 | 48,647 | 37.5 | 44,826 | 41.7 |
2011 | 50,083 | 38.1 | 46,869 | 42.9 |
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
Total nonfarm hiring (HNF), total private hiring (HP) and their respective rates are provided for the month of Jun in the years from 2001 to 2012 in Table ESI-2. Hiring numbers are in thousands. There is some recovery in HNF from 4278 thousand (or 4.2 million) in Jun 2009 to 4869 thousand in Jun 2011 and 5057 thousand in Jun 2012 for cumulative gain of 18.2 percent. HP rose from 3925 thousand in Jun 2009 to 4513 thousand in Jun 2011 and 4663 thousand in Jun 2012 for cumulative gain of 18.8 percent. HNF has fallen from 6139 in Jun 2006 to 5057 in Jun 2012 or by 17.6 percent. HP has fallen from 5661 in Jun 2006 to 4663 in Jun 2012 or by 17.6 percent. The labor market continues to be fractured, failing to provide an opportunity to exit from unemployment/underemployment or to find an opportunity for advancement away from declining inflation-adjusted earnings.
Table ESI-2, US, Total Nonfarm Hiring (HNF) and Total Private Hiring (HP) in the US in Thousands and in Percentage of Total Employment Not Seasonally Adjusted
HNF | Rate RNF | HP | Rate HP | |
2001 Jun | 5819 | 4.4 | 5531 | 4.8 |
2002 Jun | 5471 | 4.2 | 5054 | 4.6 |
2003 Jun | 5369 | 4.1 | 4975 | 4.6 |
2004 Jun | 5703 | 4.3 | 5309 | 4.8 |
2005 Jun | 6069 | 4.5 | 5675 | 5.0 |
2006 Jun | 6139 | 4.5 | 5661 | 4.9 |
2007 Jun | 6033 | 4.3 | 5535 | 4.7 |
2008 Jun | 5501 | 4.0 | 5087 | 4.4 |
2009 Jun | 4278 | 3.3 | 3925 | 3.6 |
2010 Jun | 4717 | 3.6 | 4341 | 4.0 |
2011 Jun | 4869 | 3.7 | 4513 | 4.1 |
2012 Jun | 5057 | 3.8 | 4663 | 4.2 |
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
Chart ESI-1 provides total nonfarm hiring on a monthly basis from 2001 to 2012. Nonfarm hiring rebounded in early 2010 but then fell and stabilized at a lower level than the early peak not-seasonally adjusted (NSA) of 4786 in May 2010. Nonfarm hiring fell again in Dec 2011 to 3038 from 3844 in Nov and to revised 3633 in Feb 2012, increasing to 4127 in Mar 2012, 4490 in Apr 2012, 4926 in May 2012 and 5057 in Jun 2012. Chart ESI-1 provides seasonally-adjusted (SA) monthly data. The number of seasonally-adjusted hires in Aug 2011 was 4221 thousand, increasing to revised 4444 thousand in Feb 2012, or 5.3 percent, but falling to revised 4335 thousand in Mar 2012 and 4213 in Apr 2012, or cumulative decline of 0.2 percent relative to Aug 2011, increasing to 4361 in Jun 2012 for cumulative increase of 2.0 percent from 4276 in Sep 2012. The number of hires not seasonally adjusted was 4655 in Aug 2011, falling to 3038 in Dec but increasing to 4072 in Jan 2012, increasing to 5057 in May 2012. The number of nonfarm hiring not seasonally adjusted fell by 34.7 percent from 4655 in Aug 2011 to 3038 in Dec 2011 in a yearly-repeated seasonal pattern.
Chart ESI-1, US, Total Nonfarm Hiring (HNF), 2001-2012 Month SA
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
Similar behavior occurs in the rate of nonfarm hiring plot in Chart ESI-2 Recovery in early 2010 was followed by decline and stabilization at a lower level but with stability in monthly SA estimates of 3.2 in Sep 2011 to 3.2 in Jan 2012, increasing to 3.4 in May 2012 and 3.3 in Jun 2012. The rate not seasonally adjusted fell from 3.7 in Jun 2011 to 2.3 in Dec, climbing to 3.1 in Jan 2012 and 3.8 in Jun 2012. Rates of nonfarm hiring NSA were in the range of 2.8 (Dec) to 4.5 (Jun) in 2006.
Chart ESI-2, US, Rate Total Nonfarm Hiring, Month SA 2001-2012
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
There is only milder improvement in total private hiring shown in Chart ESI-3. Hiring private (HP) rose in 2010 followed by stability and renewed increase in 2011. The number of private hiring seasonally adjusted fell from 4002 thousand in Sep 2011 to 3889 in Dec or by 2.8 percent, increasing to 3945 in Jan 2012 or decline by 1.4 relative to the level in Sep 2011 but increasing to 4080 in Jun 2012 or by 1.9 percent relative to Sep 2011. The number of private hiring not seasonally adjusted fell from 4130 in Sep 2011 to 2856 in Dec or by 30.8 percent, reaching 3782 in Jan 2012 or decline of 8.4 percent relative to Sep 2011 but increasing to 4663 in Jun 2012 or 12.9 percent relative to Sep 2011. Companies do not hire in the latter part of the year that explains the high seasonality in year-end employment data. For example, NSA private hiring fell from 4934 in Sep 2006 to 3635 in Dec 2006 or by 26.3 percent. Private hiring NSA data are useful in showing the huge declines from the period before the global recession. In Jul 2006 private hiring NSA was 5555, declining to 4293 in Jul 2011 or by 22.7 percent. The conclusion is that private hiring in the US is more than 20 percent below the hiring before the global recession. The main problem in recovery of the US labor market has been the low rate of growth of 2.2 percent in the eleven quarters of expansion of the economy from IIIQ2009 to IIQ2012 compared with average 6.2 percent in prior expansions from contractions (see table I-5 in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/07/decelerating-united-states-recovery.html). The US missed the opportunity to recover employment as in past cyclical expansions from contractions.
Chart ESII-3, US, Total Private Hiring Month SA 2011-2012
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
Chart ESIV-4 shows similar behavior in the rate of private hiring. The rate in 2011 in monthly SA data has not risen significantly above the peak in 2010. The rate seasonally adjusted fell from 3.6 in Sep 2011 to 3.5 in Dec 2011, increasing to 3.6 in Jan 2012 and 3.7 in Jun 2012. The rate not seasonally adjusted (NSA) fell from 3.8 in Sep 2011 to 2.6 in Dec 2011, increasing to revised 3.5 in Jan 2012 and 4.2 in Jun 2012. The NSA rate of private hiring fell from 4.9 in Jun 2006 to 3.6 in Jun 2009 but recovery was insufficient to only 4.1 in Jun 2011.
Chart ESI-4, US, Rate Total Private Hiring Month SA 2011-2011
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
ESII Ten Million Fewer Full-Time Jobs. There is strong seasonality in US labor markets around the end of the year. The number employed part-time for economic reasons because they could not find full-time employment fell from 9.270 million in Sep 2011 to 8.246 million in Jun 2010, seasonally adjusted, or decline of 1.024 million in nine months, as shown in Table ESII-1. The number employed full-time increased from 112.479 million in Sep 2011 to 115.290 million in Mar 2012 or 2.811 million but then fell to 114.212 million in May 2012 or 1.078 million fewer full-time employed than in Mar 2012. There is a jump in the level of full-time SA to 114.573 million in Jun 2012 or 361,000 relative to May 2012 but then decline to 114.345 million in Jul 2012 or decline of 228,000 full time jobs from Jun 2012 into Jul 2012. The number of employed part-time for economic reasons actually increased without seasonal adjustment from 8.271 million in Nov 2011 to 8.428 million in Dec 2011 or by 157,000 and then to 8.918 million in Jan 2012 or by an additional 490,000 for cumulative increase from Nov 2011 to Jan 2012 of 647,000. The level of employed part-time for economic reasons then fell from 8.918 million in Jan 2012 to 7.867 million in Mar 2012 or by 1.0151 million and to 7.694 million in Apr 2012 or 1.224 million fewer relative to Jan 2012. In Jul, the number employed part-time for economic reasons reached 8.316 million SA or 622,000 more than in Apr 2012. The number employed full time without seasonal adjustment fell from 113.138 million in Nov 2011 to 113.050 million in Dec 2011 or by 88,000 and fell further to 111.879 in Jan 2012 for cumulative decrease of 1.259 million. The number employed full-time not seasonally adjusted fell from 113.138 million in Nov 2011 to 112.587 million in Feb 2012 or by 551.000 but increased to 116.024 million in Jun 2012 or 2.886 million more full-time jobs than in Nov 2011. Comparisons over long periods require use of NSA data. The number with full-time jobs fell from a high of 123.219 million in Jul 2007 to 108.770 million in Jan 2010 or by 14.442 million. The number with full-time jobs in Jul 2012 is 116.131 million, which is lower by 7.1 million relative to the peak of 123.219 million in Jul 2007. There appear to be around 10 million fewer full-time jobs in the US than before the global recession. Growth at 2.2 percent on average in the eleven quarters of expansion from IIIQ2009 to IIQ2012 compared with 6.2 percent on average in expansions from postwar cyclical contractions is the main culprit of the fractured US labor market (see table I-5 in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/07/decelerating-united-states-recovery.html).
Table ESII-1, US, Employed Part-time for Economic Reasons, Thousands, and Full-time, Millions
Part-time Thousands | Full-time Millions | |
Seasonally Adjusted | ||
Jul 2012 | 8,246 | 114.345 |
Jun 2012 | 8,210 | 114.573 |
May 2012 | 8,098 | 114.212 |
Apr 2012 | 7,853 | 114.478 |
Mar 2012 | 7,672 | 115.290 |
Feb 2012 | 8,119 | 114.408 |
Jan 2012 | 8,230 | 113.845 |
Dec 2011 | 8,098 | 113.765 |
Nov 2011 | 8,469 | 113.212 |
Oct 2011 | 8,790 | 112.841 |
Sep 2011 | 9,270 | 112.479 |
Aug 2011 | 8,787 | 112.406 |
Jul 2011 | 8,437 | 112.006 |
Not Seasonally Adjusted | ||
Jul 2012 | 8,316 | 116.131 |
Jun 2012 | 8,394 | 116.024 |
May 2012 | 7,837 | 114.634 |
Apr 2012 | 7,694 | 113.999 |
Mar 2012 | 7,867 | 113.916 |
Feb 2012 | 8,455 | 112.587 |
Jan 2012 | 8,918 | 111.879 |
Dec 2011 | 8,428 | 113.050 |
Nov 2011 | 8,271 | 113.138 |
Oct 2011 | 8,258 | 113.456 |
Jul 2011 | 8,514 | 113.759 |
Jun 2011 | 8,738 | 113.255 |
May 2011 | 8,270 | 112.618 |
Apr 2011 | 8,425 | 111.844 |
Mar 2011 | 8,737 | 111.186 |
Feb 2011 | 8,749 | 110.731 |
Jan 2011 | 9,187 | 110.373 |
Dec 2010 | 9,205 | 111.207 |
Nov 2010 | 8,670 | 111.348 |
Oct 2010 | 8,408 | 112.342 |
Jul 2010 | 8,737 | 113.974 |
Jun 2010 | 8,867 | 113.856 |
May 2010 | 8,513 | 112.809 |
Apr 2010 | 8,921 | 111.391 |
Mar 2010 | 9,343 | 109.877 |
Feb 2010 | 9,282 | 109.100 |
Jan 2010 | 9,290 | 108.777 (low) |
Dec 2009 | 9,354 (high) | 109.875 |
Jul 2009 | 9,103 | 114.184 |
Jun 2009 | 9,301 | 114.014 |
May 2009 | 8,785 | 113.083 |
Apr 2009 | 8,648 | 112.746 |
Mar 2009 | 9,305 | 112.215 |
Feb 2009 | 9,170 | 112.947 |
Jan 2009 | 8,829 | 113.815 |
Jul 2008 | 6,054 | 122.378 |
Jun 2008 | 5,697 | 121.845 |
May 2008 | 5,096 | 120.809 |
Apr 2008 | 5,071 | 120.027 |
Mar 2008 | 5,038 | 119.875 |
Feb 2008 | 5,114 | 119.452 |
Jan 2008 | 5,340 | 119.322 |
Jul 2007 | 4,516 | 123.219 (high) |
Jun 2007 | 4,469 | 122.150 |
May 2007 | 4,315 | 120.846 |
Apr 2007 | 4,205 | 119.609 |
Mar 2007 | 4,384 | 119.640 |
Feb 2007 | 4,417 | 119.041 |
Jan 2007 | 4,726 | 119.094 |
Sep 2006 | 3,735 (low) | 120.780 |
Jul 2006 | 4,450 | 121.951 |
Jun 2006 | 4,456 | 121.070 |
May 2006 | 3,968 | 118.925 |
Apr 2006 | 3,787 | 118.559 |
Mar 2006 | 4,097 | 117.693 |
Feb 2006 | 4,403 | 116.823 |
Jan 2006 | 4,597 | 116.395 |
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/cps/data.htm
People lose their marketable job skills after prolonged unemployment and find increasing difficulty in finding another job. Chart ESII-1 shows the sharp rise in unemployed over 27 weeks and stabilization at an extremely high level.
Chart ESII-1, US, Number Unemployed for 27 Weeks or Over, Thousands SA Month 2001-2011
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/cps/data.htm
Another segment of U6 consists of people marginally attached to the labor force who continue to seek employment but less frequently on the frustration there may not be a job for them. Chart ESII-2 shows the sharp rise in people marginally attached to the labor force after 2007 and subsequent stabilization.
Chart ESII-2, US, Marginally Attached to the Labor Force, NSA Month 2001-2012
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/cps/data.htm
Chart ESII-3 reveals the fracture in the US labor market. The number of workers with full-time jobs not-seasonally-adjusted rose with fluctuations from 2002 to a peak in 2007, collapsing during the global recession. The terrible state of the job market is shown in the segment from 2009 to 2012 with fluctuations around the typical behavior of a stationary series: there is no improvement in the United States in creating full-time jobs.
Chart ESII-3, US, Full-time Employed, Thousands, NSA, 2001-2012
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/cps/data.htm
ESIII Youth and Middle-Aged Unemployment. The United States is experiencing high youth unemployment as in European economies. Table ESIII-1 provides the employment level for ages 16 to 24 years of age estimated by the Bureau of Labor Statistics. On an annual basis, youth employment fell from 20.041 million in 2006 to 17.362 million in 2011 or 2.679 million fewer youth jobs. During the seasonal peak months of youth employment in the summer from Jun to Aug, youth employment has fallen by more than two million jobs. There are two hardships behind these data. First, young people cannot find employment after finishing high-school and college, reducing prospects for achievement in older age. Second, students with more modest means cannot find employment to keep them in college.
Table ESIII-1, US, Employment Level 16-24 Years, Thousands, NSA
Year | Apr | May | Jun | Jul | Annual |
2001 | 19778 | 19648 | 21212 | 22042 | 20088 |
2002 | 19108 | 19484 | 20828 | 21501 | 19683 |
2003 | 18873 | 19032 | 20432 | 20950 | 19351 |
2004 | 19184 | 19237 | 20587 | 21447 | 19630 |
2005 | 19071 | 19356 | 20949 | 21749 | 19770 |
2006 | 19406 | 19769 | 21268 | 21914 | 20041 |
2007 | 19368 | 19457 | 21098 | 21717 | 19875 |
2008 | 19161 | 19254 | 20466 | 21021 | 19202 |
2009 | 17739 | 17588 | 18726 | 19304 | 17601 |
2010 | 16764 | 17039 | 17920 | 18564 | 17077 |
2011 | 16970 | 17045 | 18180 | 18632 | 17362 |
2012 | 17387 | 17681 | 18907 | 19461 |
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
Chart ESIII-1 provides US employment level ages 16 to 24 years from 2002 to 2012. Employment level is sharply lower in Jun 2012 relative to the peak in 2007.
Chart ESIII-1, US, Employment Level 16-24 Years, Thousands SA, 2001-2012
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
Table ESIII-2 provides US unemployment level ages 16 to 24 years. The number unemployed ages 16 to 24 years increased from 2342 thousand in 2007 to 3634 thousand in 2011 or by 1.292 million. This situation may persist for many years.
Table ESIII-2, US, Unemployment Level 16-24 Years, Thousands NSA
Year | Apr | May | Jun | Jul | Aug | Annual |
2001 | 2095 | 2171 | 2775 | 2585 | 2461 | 2371 |
2002 | 2515 | 2568 | 3167 | 3034 | 2688 | 2683 |
2003 | 2572 | 2838 | 3542 | 3200 | 2724 | 2746 |
2004 | 2387 | 2684 | 3191 | 3018 | 2585 | 2638 |
2005 | 2398 | 2619 | 3010 | 2688 | 2519 | 2521 |
2006 | 2092 | 2254 | 2860 | 2750 | 2467 | 2353 |
2007 | 2074 | 2203 | 2883 | 2622 | 2388 | 2342 |
2008 | 2196 | 2952 | 3450 | 3408 | 2990 | 2830 |
2009 | 3321 | 3851 | 4653 | 4387 | 4004 | 3760 |
2010 | 3803 | 3854 | 4481 | 4374 | 3903 | 3857 |
2011 | 3365 | 3628 | 4248 | 4110 | 3820 | 3634 |
2012 | 3175 | 3438 | 4180 | 4011 |
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/cps/data.htm
Chart ESIII-2 provides the unemployment level ages 16 to 24 from 2002 to 2012. The level rose sharply from 2007 to 2010 with tepid improvement into 2012.
Chart ESIII-2, US, Unemployment Level 16-24 Years, Thousands SA, 2001-2012
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
Table ESIII-3 provides the rate of unemployment of young peoples in ages 16 to 24 years. The annual rate jumped from 10.5 percent in 2007 to 18.4 percent in 2010 and 17.3 percent in 2011. During the seasonal peak in Jul 2011 the rate of youth unemployed was 18.1 percent compared with 10.8 percent in Jun 2007.
Table ESIII-3, US, Unemployment Rate 16-24 Years, Thousands, NSA
Year | Apr | May | Jun | Jul | Aug | Annual |
2001 | 9.6 | 10.0 | 11.6 | 10.5 | 10.7 | 10.6 |
2002 | 11.6 | 11.6 | 13.2 | 12.4 | 11.5 | 12.0 |
2003 | 12.0 | 13.0 | 14.8 | 13.3 | 11.9 | 12.4 |
2004 | 11.1 | 12.2 | 13.4 | 12.3 | 11.1 | 11.8 |
2005 | 11.2 | 11.9 | 12.6 | 11.0 | 10.8 | 11.3 |
2006 | 9.7 | 10.2 | 11.9 | 11.2 | 10.4 | 10.5 |
2007 | 9.7 | 10.2 | 12.0 | 10.8 | 10.5 | 10.5 |
2008 | 10.3 | 13.3 | 14.4 | 14.0 | 13.0 | 12.8 |
2009 | 15.8 | 18.0 | 19.9 | 18.5 | 18.0 | 17.6 |
2010 | 18.5 | 18.4 | 20.0 | 19.1 | 17.8 | 18.4 |
2011 | 16.5 | 17.5 | 18.9 | 18.1 | 17.5 | 17.3 |
2012 | 15.4 | 16.3 | 18.1 | 17.1 |
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
Chart ESIII-3 provides the BLS estimate of the not-seasonally-adjusted rate of youth unemployment for ages 16 to 24 years from 2002 to 2012. The rate of youth unemployment increased sharply during the global recession of 2008 and 2009 but has failed to drop to earlier lower levels during the eleven quarters of expansion of the economy since IIIQ2009.
Chart ESIII-3, US, Unemployment Rate 16-24 Years, Thousands, NSA, 2001-2012
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
Chart ESIII-4 provides longer perspective with the rate of youth unemployment in ages 16 to 24 years from 1948 to 2012. The rate of youth unemployment rose to 20 percent during the contractions of the early 1980s and also during the contraction of the global recession in 2008 and 2009. The data illustrate again the claim in this blog that the contractions of the early 1980s are the valid framework for comparison with the global recession of 2008 and 2009 instead of misleading comparisons with the 1930s. During the initial phase of recovery, the rate of youth unemployment 16 to 24 years NSA fell from 18.9 percent in Jun 1983 to 14.5 percent in Jun 1984 while the rate of youth unemployment 16 to 24 years was nearly the same during the expansion after IIIQ2009: 19.9 percent in Jun 2009, 20.0 percent in Jun 2010, 18.9 percent in Jun 2011 and 18.1 percent in Jun 2012. The difference originates in the vigorous seasonally-adjusted annual equivalent average rate of GDP growth of 5.7 percent during the recovery from IQ1983 to IVQ1985 compared with 2.2 percent on average during the first eleven quarters of expansion from IIIQ2009 to IIQ2012 (see table I-5 in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/07/decelerating-united-states-recovery.html). The fractured US labor market denies an early start for young people.
Chart ESIII-4, US, Unemployment Rate 16-24 Years, Percent NSA, 1948-2012
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
It is more difficult to move to other jobs after a certain age because of fewer available opportunities for matured individuals than for new entrants into the labor force. Middle-aged unemployed are less likely to find another job. Table ESIII-4 provides the unemployment level ages 45 years and over. The number unemployed ages 45 years and over rose from 1.985 million in Jul 2006 to 4.821 million in July 2010 or by 142.9 percent. The number of unemployed ages 45 years and over declined to 4.405 million in Jul 2012 that is still higher by 121.9 percent than in Jul 2006.
Table ESIII-4, US, Unemployment Level 45 Years and Over, Thousands NSA
Year | Apr | May | Jun | Jul | Aug | Annual |
2001 | 1421 | 1259 | 1371 | 1539 | 1640 | 1576 |
2002 | 2101 | 1999 | 2190 | 2173 | 2114 | 2114 |
2003 | 2287 | 2112 | 2212 | 2281 | 2301 | 2253 |
2004 | 2160 | 2025 | 2182 | 2116 | 2082 | 2149 |
2005 | 1939 | 1844 | 1868 | 2119 | 1895 | 2009 |
2006 | 1843 | 1784 | 1813 | 1985 | 1869 | 1848 |
2007 | 1871 | 1803 | 1805 | 2053 | 1956 | 1966 |
2008 | 2104 | 2095 | 2211 | 2492 | 2695 | 2540 |
2009 | 4172 | 4175 | 4505 | 4757 | 4683 | 4500 |
2010 | 4770 | 4565 | 4564 | 4821 | 5128 | 4879 |
2011 | 4373 | 4356 | 4559 | 4772 | 4592 | 4537 |
2012 | 4037 | 4083 | 4084 | 4405 |
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
Chart ESIII-5 provides the level unemployed ages 45 years and over. There was sharp increase during the global recession and inadequate decline. There was an increase during the 2001 recession and then stability. The US is facing another challenge of reemploying middle-aged workers.
Chart ESIII-5, US, Unemployment Level Ages 45 Years and Over, Thousands, NSA, 1976-2012
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
ESIV United States Trade Deficit. Chart ESIV-1 of the US Census Bureau provides the US trade account in goods and services SA from Jan 1992 to Jun 2012. There is a long-term trend of deterioration of the US trade deficit shown vividly by Chart ESIV-1. The trend of deterioration was reversed by the global recession from IVQ2007 to IIQ2009. Deterioration resumed together with recovery and was influenced significantly by the carry trade from zero interest rates to commodity futures exposures (these arguments are elaborated in Pelaez and Pelaez, Financial Regulation after the Global Recession (2009a), 157-66, Regulation of Banks and Finance (2009b), 217-27, International Financial Architecture (2005), 15-18, The Global Recession Risk (2007), 221-5, Globalization and the State Vol. II (2008b), 197-213, Government Intervention in Globalization (2008c), 182-4 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/07/causes-of-2007-creditdollar-crisis.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/professor-mckinnons-bubble-economy.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/world-inflation-quantitative-easing.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/treasury-yields-valuation-of-risk.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2010/11/quantitative-easing-theory-evidence-and.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2010/12/is-fed-printing-money-what-are.html). Earlier research focused on the long-term external imbalance of the US in the form of trade and current account deficits (Pelaez and Pelaez, The Global Recession Risk (2007), Globalization and the State Vol. II (2008b) 183-94, Government Intervention in Globalization (2008c), 167-71). US external imbalances have not been resolved and tend to widen together with improving world economic activity and commodity price shocks.
Chart ESIV-1. US, Balance of Trade SA, Monthly Jan 1992-Jun 2012
Source: US Census Bureau
http://www.census.gov/foreign-trade/
US exports and imports of goods not seasonally adjusted in Jan-Jun 2012 and Jan-Jun 2011 are shown in Table ESIV-1. The rate of growth of exports was 7.1 percent and 6.0 percent for imports. The US has partial hedge of commodity price increases in exports of agricultural commodities that fell 4.4 percent and of mineral fuels that increased 13.3 percent both because of higher prices of raw materials and commodities that are falling again currently because of shocks of risk aversion. The US exports an insignificant amount of crude oil. US exports and imports consist mostly of manufactured products, with less rapidly increasing prices. US manufactured exports rose 8.2 percent while imports rose 8.1 percent. Significant part of the US trade imbalance originates in imports of mineral fuels declining by 0.9 percent and crude oil increasing 2.6 percent with significant decline at the margin in oil prices. The limited hedge in exports of agricultural commodities and mineral fuels compared with substantial imports of mineral fuels and crude oil results in waves of deterioration of the terms of trade of the US, or export prices relative to import prices, originating in commodity price increases caused by carry trades from zero interest rates. These waves are similar to those in worldwide inflation (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/07/world-inflation-waves-financial.html).
Table ESIV-1, US, Exports and Imports of Goods, Not Seasonally Adjusted Millions of Dollars and %
Jan-Jun 2012 $ Millions | Jan-Jun 2011 $ Millions | ∆% | |
Exports | 773,619 | 722,659 | 7.1 |
Manufactured | 513,381 | 474,655 | 8.2 |
Agricultural | 67,241 | 70,357 | -4.4 |
Mineral Fuels | 67,297 | 59,418 | 13.3 |
Crude Oil | 813 | 681 | 19.4 |
Imports | 1,132,171 | 1,068,161 | 6.0 |
Manufactured | 834,677 | 772,453 | 8.1 |
Agricultural | 53,121 | 49,944 | 6.4 |
Mineral Fuels | 223,260 | 225,413 | -0.9 |
Crude Oil | 167,829 | 163,586 | 2.6 |
Source: US Census Bureau http://www.census.gov/foreign-trade/
ESV Productivity and Costs. The Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) of the Department of Labor provides the quarterly report on productivity and costs. The operational definition of productivity used by the BLS is (http://www.bls.gov/news.release/pdf/prod2.pdf 1): “Labor productivity, or output per hour, is calculated by dividing an index of real output by an index of hours worked of all persons, including employees, proprietors, and unpaid family workers.” The BLS has revised the estimates for productivity and unit costs. Table ESV-1 provides revised data for nonfarm business sector productivity and unit labor costs for the final quarter of 2011 and the first two quarters of 2012 in seasonally adjusted annual equivalent (SAAE) rate and the percentage change from the same quarter a year earlier. Reflecting increases in output of 2.0 percent and of 0.4 percent in hours worked, nonfarm business sector labor productivity increased at a SAAE rate of 1.6 percent in IIQ2012, as shown in column 2 “IIQ2012 SAEE.” The increase of labor productivity from IIQ2011 to IIQ2012 was 1.1 percent, reflecting increases in output of 2.9 percent and of hours worked of 1.9 percent, as shown in column 3 “IIQ2012 YoY.” Hours worked decreased from 3.2 percent in IQ2011 in SAAE to 0.4 percent in IIQ2012 but output fell from 2.7 percent in IQ2011 to 2.0 percent in IIQ2012 because of the weakening economy. The BLS defines unit labor costs as (http://www.bls.gov/news.release/pdf/prod2.pdf 2): “BLS defines unit labor costs as the ratio of hourly compensation to labor productivity; increases in hourly compensation tend to increase unit labor costs and increases in output per hour tend to reduce them.” Unit labor costs increased at the SAAE rate of 1.7 percent in IIQ2012 and rose 0.8 percent in IIQ2012 relative to IIQ2011. Hourly compensation in IIQ2012 increased at the SAAE rate of 3.3 percent, which deflating by the estimated consumer price increase SAAE rate in IIQ2012 results in increase of real hourly compensation by 2.6 percent. Real hourly compensation was flat in IIQ2012 relative to IIQ2011.
Table ESV-1, US, Nonfarm Business Sector Productivity and Costs %
IIQ | IIQ | IQ 2012 SAAE | IQ 2012 YoY | IVQ 2011 SAAE | IVQ 2011 YoY | |
Productivity | 1.6 | 1.1 | -0.5 | 1.0 | 2.8 | 0.6 |
Output | 2.0 | 2.9 | 2.7 | 3.2 | 5.3 | 2.5 |
Hours | 0.4 | 1.8 | 3.2 | 2.2 | 2.4 | 1.9 |
Hourly | 3.3 | 1.9 | 5.1 | 1.0 | -0.7 | 2.0 |
Real Hourly Comp. | 2.6 | 0.0 | 2.6 | -1.7 | -1.9 | -1.3 |
Unit Labor Costs | 1.7 | 0.8 | 5.6 | 0.0 | -3.3 | 1.4 |
Unit Nonlabor Payments | 1.4 | 3.1 | -3.1 | 5.0 | 5.0 | 2.6 |
Implicit Price Deflator | 1.6 | 1.8 | 1.9 | 2.1 | 0.1 | 1.9 |
Notes: SAAE: seasonally adjusted annual equivalent; Comp.: compensation; YoY: Quarter on Same Quarter Year Earlier
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/lpc/home.htm
In 2011, productivity increased 0.7 percent in the annual average, as shown in Table ESV-2. Increases in productivity were revised to 3.1 percent in the 2010 annual average and 2.9 percent in the 2009 annual average. The contraction period and the recovery period have been characterized by savings of labor inputs. Real hourly compensation fell 0.5 percent in 2011, interrupting increases of 1.8 percent in 2009 and 0.4 percent in 2010. Unit labor costs fell 1.5 percent in 2009 and 1.0 percent in 2010 but increased 2.0 percent in 2011.
Table ESV-2, US, Revised Nonfarm Business Sector Productivity and Costs Annual Average, ∆% Annual Average
2011 ∆% | 2010 ∆% | 2009 ∆% | 2008 ∆% | 2007 ∆% | |
Productivity | 0.7 | 3.1 | 2.9 | 0.6 | 1.5 |
Real Hourly Compensation | -0.5 | 0.4 | 1.8 | -0.4 | 1.1 |
Unit Labor Costs | 2.0 | -1.0 | -1.5 | 2.8 | 2.4 |
Source: http://www.bls.gov/lpc/home.htm
Productivity jumped in the recovery after the recession from Mar IQ2001 to Nov IVQ2001 (http://www.nber.org/cycles.html). Table ESV-3 provides quarter on quarter and annual percentage changes in nonfarm business output per hour, or productivity, from 1999 to 2012. The annual average jumped from 2.9 percent in 2001 to 4.6 percent in 2002. Nonfarm business productivity increased at the SAAE rate of 8.8 percent in the first quarter after the recession in IQ2002. Productivity increases decline later in the expansion period. Productivity increases were mediocre during the recession from Dec IVQ2007 to Jun IIQ2009 (http://www.nber.org/cycles.html) and increased during the first phase of expansion from IIQ2009 to IQ2010, trended lower and collapsed in 2011 and 2012.
Table ESV-3, US, Nonfarm Business Output per Hour, Percent Change from Prior Quarter at Annual Rate, 1999-2012
Year | Qtr1 | Qtr2 | Qtr3 | Qtr4 | Annual |
1999 | 3.9 | 0.3 | 3.3 | 7.1 | 3.3 |
2000 | -1.5 | 9.4 | 0.1 | 4.0 | 3.4 |
2001 | -1.3 | 7.4 | 2.5 | 5.8 | 2.9 |
2002 | 8.8 | 0.5 | 3.8 | -0.2 | 4.6 |
2003 | 3.7 | 5.5 | 9.5 | 1.5 | 3.7 |
2004 | 0.6 | 3.3 | 0.7 | 0.5 | 2.6 |
2005 | 4.2 | -0.8 | 3.1 | -0.2 | 1.6 |
2006 | 2.5 | 0.4 | -2.2 | 2.7 | 0.9 |
2007 | -0.2 | 3.4 | 4.8 | 1.9 | 1.5 |
2008 | -2.6 | 2.4 | -0.8 | -3.4 | 0.6 |
2009 | 5.5 | 6.8 | 5.2 | 5.0 | 2.9 |
2010 | 2.7 | -0.5 | 3.3 | 1.9 | 3.1 |
2011 | -2.0 | 1.2 | 0.6 | 2.8 | 0.7 |
2012 | -0.5 | 1.6 |
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/lpc/home.htm
Chart ESV-1 of the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) provides SAAE rates of nonfarm business productivity from 1999 to 2012. There is a clear pattern in both episodes of economic cycles in 2001 and 2007 of rapid expansion of productivity in the transition from contraction to expansion followed by more subdued productivity expansion. Part of the explanation is the reduction in labor utilization resulting from adjustment of business to the sudden shock of collapse of revenue. Productivity rose briefly in the expansion after 2009 but then collapsed and moved to negative change.
Chart ESV-1, US, Nonfarm Business Output per Hour, Percent Change from Prior Quarter at Annual Rate, 1999-2012
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/lpc/home.htm
Percentage changes from prior quarter at SAAE rates and annual average percentage changes of nonfarm business unit labor costs are provided in Table ESV-4. Unit labor costs fell during the contractions with continuing negative percentage changes in the early phases of the recovery. Weak labor markets partly explain the decline in unit labor costs. As the economy moves toward full employment, labor markets tighten with increase in unit labor costs. The expansion beginning in IIIQ2009 has been characterized by high unemployment and underemployment. Table ESV-4 shows continuing subdued increases in unit labor costs in 2011 but with increase of 5.6 percent in IQ2012 and 1.7 percent in IIQ2012.
Table ESV-4, US, Nonfarm Business Unit Labor Costs, Percent Change from Prior Quarter at Annual Rate 1999-2012
Year | Qtr1 | Qtr2 | Qtr3 | Qtr4 | Annual |
1999 | 3.0 | 0.5 | 0.1 | 1.6 | 0.9 |
2000 | 17.4 | -7.4 | 8.6 | -1.6 | 3.9 |
2001 | 10.9 | -5.8 | -1.1 | -1.7 | 1.5 |
2002 | -4.1 | 3.4 | -1.6 | 2.2 | -1.3 |
2003 | 2.8 | 1.4 | -3.5 | 1.8 | 1.0 |
2004 | -2.5 | 2.4 | 5.8 | 2.7 | 0.7 |
2005 | -1.0 | 3.5 | 2.6 | 2.6 | 2.3 |
2006 | 2.9 | 1.3 | 3.6 | 6.8 | 2.8 |
2007 | 4.0 | -1.8 | -1.9 | 4.3 | 2.4 |
2008 | 8.7 | -3.4 | 4.3 | 5.7 | 2.8 |
2009 | -8.2 | -0.2 | -3.1 | -3.9 | -1.5 |
2010 | -1.3 | 3.3 | -1.4 | -1.4 | -1.0 |
2011 | 11.3 | -1.3 | -0.6 | -3.3 | 2.0 |
2012 | 5.6 | 1.7 |
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/lpc/home.htm
Chart ESV-2 provides percentage changes quarter on quarter at SAAE rates of nonfarm business unit labor costs. With the exception of 3.3 percent in IIQ2010, a jump of 11.3 percent in IQ2011, 5.6 percent in IQ2012 and 1.7 percent in IIQ2012, changes in nonfarm business unit labor costs have been negative.
Chart ESV-2, US, Nonfarm Business Unit Labor Costs, Percent Change from Prior Quarter at Annual Rate 1999-2011
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/lpc/home.htm
Table ESV-5 provides percentage change from prior quarter at annual rates for nonfarm business real hourly worker compensation. The expansion after the contraction of 2001 was followed by strong recovery of real hourly compensation. Real hourly compensation increased at the rate of 4.4 percent in IQ2011 but fell at annual rates of 4.4 percent in IIQ2011, 3.1 percent in IIIQ2011 and 1.9 percent in IVQ2011 but increased at 2.6 percent in IQ2012 and also in IIQ2012. In 2011, real hourly compensation fell 0.5 percent.
Table ESV-5, Nonfarm Business Real Hourly Compensation, Percent Change from Prior Quarter at Annual Rate 1999-2012
Year | Qtr1 | Qtr2 | Qtr3 | Qtr4 | Annual |
1999 | 5.4 | -2.0 | 0.2 | 5.6 | 2.2 |
2000 | 11.4 | -1.8 | 4.7 | -0.4 | 4.0 |
2001 | 5.4 | -1.5 | 0.2 | 4.5 | 1.6 |
2002 | 2.8 | 0.6 | 0.0 | -0.6 | 1.5 |
2003 | 2.4 | 7.7 | 2.5 | 1.8 | 2.4 |
2004 | -5.2 | 2.6 | 3.7 | -1.1 | 0.6 |
2005 | 1.3 | -0.1 | -0.3 | -1.3 | 0.6 |
2006 | 3.1 | -1.8 | -2.6 | 11.6 | 0.5 |
2007 | -0.2 | -3.0 | 0.3 | 1.3 | 1.1 |
2008 | 1.4 | -6.1 | -2.8 | 12.2 | -0.4 |
2009 | -0.7 | 4.7 | -1.6 | -2.1 | 1.8 |
2010 | 0.5 | 3.1 | 0.4 | -2.4 | 0.4 |
2011 | 4.4 | -4.4 | -3.1 | -1.9 | -0.5 |
2012 | 2.6 | 2.6 |
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/lpc/home.htm
Chart ESV-3 provides percentage change from prior quarter at annual rate of nonfarm business real hourly compensation from 1999 to 2012. There are significant fluctuations in quarterly percentage changes oscillating between positive and negative. There is no clear pattern in the two contractions in the 2000s.
Chart ESV-3, US, Nonfarm Business Real Hourly Compensation, Percent Change from Prior Quarter at Annual Rate 2001-2011
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/lpc/home.htm
ESVI World Economic Slowdown. Table ESVI-1 provides the latest available estimates of GDP for the regions and countries followed in this blog. Growth is weak throughout most of the world. Japan’s GDP increased 1.2 percent in IQ2012 and 2.8 percent relative to a year earlier but part of the jump could be the low level a year earlier because of the Tōhoku or Great East Earthquake and Tsunami of Mar 11, 2011. Japan is experiencing difficulties with the overvalued yen because of worldwide capital flight originating in zero interest rates with risk aversion in an environment of softer growth of world trade. China grew at 1.8 percent in IIQ2012, which annualizes to 7.4 percent. Xinhuanet informs that Premier Wen Jiabao considers the need for macroeconomic stimulus, arguing that “we should continue to implement proactive fiscal policy and a prudent monetary policy, while giving more priority to maintaining growth” (http://news.xinhuanet.com/english/china/2012-05/20/c_131599662.htm). Premier Wen elaborates that “the country should properly handle the relationship between maintaining growth, adjusting economic structures and managing inflationary expectations” (http://news.xinhuanet.com/english/china/2012-05/20/c_131599662.htm). China’s GDP grew 7.6 percent in IIQ2012 relative to IQ2011. Growth rates of GDP of China in a quarter relative to the same quarter a year earlier have been declining from 2011 to 2012. GDP was flat in the euro area in IQ2012 and fell 0.1 percent relative to a year earlier. Germany’s GDP increased 0.5 percent in IQ2012 and 1.7 percent relative to a year earlier. US GDP increased 0.4 percent in IIQ2012 and 2.2 percent relative to a year earlier (Section I Mediocre and Decelerating United States Economic Growth http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/07/decelerating-united-states-recovery.html) but with substantial underemployment and underemployment (Section I http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/08/twenty-nine-million-unemployed-or.html and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/07/recovery-without-jobs-stagnating-real.html) and weak hiring (Section I and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/07/recovery-without-hiring-ten-million.html). UK GDP fell 0.7 percent in IIQ2012 and fell 0.8 percent relative to IIQ2011. Italy has experienced decline of GDP in four consecutive quarters from IIIQ2011 to IIQ2012. Italy’s GDP fell 0.7 percent in IIQ2012 and declined 2.5 percent relative to IIQ2011.
Table ESVI-1, Percentage Changes of GDP Quarter on Prior Quarter and on Same Quarter Year Earlier, ∆%
IQ2012/IVQ2011 | IQ2012/IQ2011 | |
United States | QOQ: 0.5 SAAR: 2.0 | 2.4 |
Japan | 1.2 | 2.8 |
China | 1.8 | 8.1 |
Euro Area | 0.0 | -0.1 |
Germany | 0.5 | 1.7 |
France | 0.0 | 0.3 |
Italy | -0.8 | -1.4 |
United Kingdom | -0.3 | -0.2 |
IIQ2012/IQ2012 | IIQ2012/IIQ2011 | |
United States | QOQ: 0.4 SAAR: 1.5 | 2.2 |
China | 1.8 | 7.6 |
Italy | -0.7 | -2.5 |
United Kingdom | -0.7 | -0.8 |
QOQ: Quarter relative to prior quarter; SAAR: seasonally adjusted annual rate
Source: Country Statistical Agencies
http://www.bea.gov/national/index.htm#gdp http://www.esri.cao.go.jp/en/sna/sokuhou/sokuhou_top.html http://www.stats.gov.cn/enGliSH/
The JP Morgan Global All-Industry Output Index of the JP Morgan Manufacturing and Services PMI™, produced by JP Morgan and Markit in association with ISM and IFPSM, with high association with world GDP, increased from 50.3 in Jun to 51.7 in Jul, indicating expansion at a moderate rate, which is one of the lowest in the current expansion (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9928). This index has remained above the contraction territory of 50.0 during 35 months. Both global manufacturing and services have slowed down considerably with services increasing marginally because of activity in the US while manufacturing deepened its decline. The JP Morgan Global Manufacturing PMI™, produced by JP Morgan and Markit in association with ISM and IFPSM, fell to 48.4 in Jul from 49.1 in Jun, for the lowest reading in three years in two consecutive months below 50.0 (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9899). David Hensley, Director of Global Economics Coordination at JPMorgan, finds that inventory adjustment is the driver of deeper contraction in the beginning of IIIQ2012 (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9899). The HSBC Brazil Composite Output Index, compiled by Markit, fell from moderate expansion at 51.5 in Jun to moderate contraction at 48.9 in Jul, in the weakest reading in ten months (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9912). Andre Loes, Chief Economist, Brazil, at HSBC, finds that the decline of the HSBC Brazil Services Business Activity Index from 53.0 in Jun to 48.9 in Jul withdraws important support present in the first half of 2012 (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9912). The HSBC Brazil Purchasing Managers’ IndexTM (PMI™) increased slightly to 48.7 in Jul from 48.5 in Jun, indicating modest deterioration of business conditions in Brazilian manufacturing (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9876). Andre Loes, Chief Economist, Brazil at HSBC, finds that moderate improvement in the index suggests that drivers of the drop of activity are moderating (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9876).
ESVII Flight to Government Securities of the United States and Germany. Yields on sovereign debt backed up again with the yield of the ten-year government bond of Spain rising sharply to 7.224 percent on Fri Jul 20 while the yield of the ten-year government bond of Italy increased to 6.158 percent but eased again on Fri Jul 27 on the expectations of massive government support with the yield of the ten-year government bond of Spain falling to 6.731 percent and the yield of the ten-year government bond of Italy dropping to 5.956 percent. The ten-year government bond of Spain was quoted at yield of 6.827 percent on Fri Aug 3 and the ten-year government bond of Italy was quoted at 6.064 percent (http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/public/page/marketsdata.html?mod=WSJ_PRO_hps_marketdata). The ten-year government bond of Spain was quoted at 6.868 percent on Aug 10 and the ten-year government bond of Italy at 5.894 percent. Risk aversion is captured by flight of investors from risk financial assets to the government securities of the US and Germany. Diminishing aversion is captured by increase of the yield of the two- and ten-year Treasury notes and the two- and ten-year government bonds of Germany. Table ESVII-1 provides yields of US and German governments bonds and the rate of USD/EUR. Yields of US and German government bonds decline during shocks of risk aversion and the dollar strengthens in the form of fewer dollars required to buy one euro. The yield of the US ten-year Treasury note fell from 2.202 percent on Aug 26, 2011 to 1.459 percent on Jul 20, 2012, reminiscent of experience during the Treasury-Fed accord of the 1940s that placed a ceiling on long-term Treasury debt (Hetzel and Leach 2001), while the yield of the ten-year government bond of Germany fell from 2.16 percent to 1.17 percent. Under increasing risk appetite, the yield of the ten-year Treasury rose to 1.544 on Jul 27, 2012 and 1.569 percent on Aug 3, 2012, while the yield of the ten-year Government bond of Germany rose to 1.40 percent on Jul 27 and 1.42 percent on Aug 3. The US dollar strengthened significantly from USD 1.450/EUR on Aug 26, 2011, to USD 1.2158 on Jul 20, 2012, or by 16.2 percent, but depreciated to USD 1.2320/EUR on Jul 27, 2012 and 1.2387 on Aug 3, 2012 in expectation of massive support of highly indebted euro zone members. Doubts returned at the end of the week of Aug 10, 2012 with appreciation to USD 1.2290/EUR and decline of the yields of the two-year government bond of Germany to -0.07 percent and of the ten-year to 1.38 percent. Under zero interest rates for the monetary policy rate of the US, or fed funds rate, carry trades ensure devaluation of the dollar if there is no risk aversion but the dollar appreciates in flight to safe haven during episodes of risk aversion. Unconventional monetary policy induces significant global financial instability, excessive risks and low liquidity. The ten-year Treasury yield is still at a level below consumer price inflation of 1.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Jun (see subsection II United States Inflation http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/07/world-inflation-waves-financial.html) and the expectation of higher inflation if risk aversion diminishes. Treasury securities continue to be safe haven for investors fearing risk but with concentration in shorter maturities such as the two-year Treasury. The lower part of Table ESVII-1 provides the same flight to government securities of the US and Germany and the USD during the financial crisis and global recession and the beginning of the European debt crisis in the spring of 2010 with the USD trading at USD 1.192/EUR on Jun 7, 2010.
Table ESVII-1, Two- and Ten-Year Yields of Government Bonds of the US and Germany and US Dollar/EUR Exchange rate
US 2Y | US 10Y | DE 2Y | DE 10Y | USD/ EUR | |
8/10/12 | 0.267 | 1.658 | -0.07 | 1.38 | 1.2290 |
8/3/12 | 0.242 | 1.569 | -0.02 | 1.42 | 1.2387 |
7/27/12 | 0.244 | 1.544 | -0.03 | 1.40 | 1.2320 |
7/20/12 | 0.207 | 1.459 | -0.07 | 1.17 | 1.2158 |
7/13/12 | 0.24 | 1.49 | -0.04 | 1.26 | 1.2248 |
7/6/12 | 0.272 | 1.548 | -0.01 | 1.33 | 1.2288 |
6/29/12 | 0.305 | 1.648 | 0.12 | 1.58 | 1.2661 |
6/22/12 | 0.309 | 1.676 | 0.14 | 1.58 | 1.2570 |
6/15/12 | 0.272 | 1.584 | 0.07 | 1.44 | 1.2640 |
6/8/12 | 0.268 | 1.635 | 0.04 | 1.33 | 1.2517 |
6/1/12 | 0.248 | 1.454 | 0.01 | 1.17 | 1.2435 |
5/25/12 | 0.291 | 1.738 | 0.05 | 1.37 | 1.2518 |
5/18/12 | 0.292 | 1.714 | 0.05 | 1.43 | 1.2780 |
5/11/12 | 0.248 | 1.845 | 0.09 | 1.52 | 1.2917 |
5/4/12 | 0.256 | 1.876 | 0.08 | 1.58 | 1.3084 |
4/6/12 | 0.31 | 2.058 | 0.14 | 1.74 | 1.3096 |
3/30/12 | 0.335 | 2.214 | 0.21 | 1.79 | 1.3340 |
3/2/12 | 0.29 | 1.977 | 0.16 | 1.80 | 1.3190 |
2/24/12 | 0.307 | 1.977 | 0.24 | 1.88 | 1.3449 |
1/6/12 | 0.256 | 1.957 | 0.17 | 1.85 | 1.2720 |
12/30/11 | 0.239 | 1.871 | 0.14 | 1.83 | 1.2944 |
8/26/11 | 0.20 | 2.202 | 0.65 | 2.16 | 1.450 |
8/19/11 | 0.192 | 2.066 | 0.65 | 2.11 | 1.4390 |
6/7/10 | 0.74 | 3.17 | 0.49 | 2.56 | 1.192 |
3/5/09 | 0.89 | 2.83 | 1.19 | 3.01 | 1.254 |
12/17/08 | 0.73 | 2.20 | 1.94 | 3.00 | 1.442 |
10/27/08 | 1.57 | 3.79 | 2.61 | 3.76 | 1.246 |
7/14/08 | 2.47 | 3.88 | 4.38 | 4.40 | 1.5914 |
6/26/03 | 1.41 | 3.55 | NA | 3.62 | 1.1423 |
Note: DE: Germany
Source:
http://www.bloomberg.com/markets/
http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/page/marketsdata.html?mod=WSJ_hps_marketdata
http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/data.htm
http://www.ecb.int/stats/money/long/html/index.en.html
Chart ESVII-1 of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System provides the ten-year and two-year Treasury constant maturity yields. The combination of zero fed funds rate and quantitative easing caused sharp decline of the yields from 2008 and 2009. Yield declines have also occurred during periods of financial risk aversion, including the current one of stress of financial markets in Europe.
Chart ESVII-1, US, Ten-Year and Two-Year Treasury Constant Maturity Yields 2001-2012
Note: US Recessions in shaded areas
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/update/
ESVIII Exchange Rate Confrontations. The Dow Jones Newswires informs on Oct 15 that the premier of China Wen Jiabao announced that the Chinese yuan will not be further appreciated to prevent adverse effects on exports (http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052970203914304576632790881396896.html?mod=WSJ_hp_LEFTWhatsNewsCollection). Bob Davis and Lingling Wei, writing on “China shifts course, lets Yuan drop,” on Jul 25, 2012, published in the Wall Street Journal (http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10000872396390444840104577548610131107868.html?mod=WSJPRO_hpp_LEFTTopStories), find that China is depreciating the CNY relative to the USD in an effort to diminish the impact of appreciation of the CNY relative to the EUR. Table ESVIII-1 provides the CNY/USD rate from Oct 28, 2011 to Aug 3, 2012 in selected intervals. The CNY/USD revalued by 0.9 percent from Oct 28, 2012 to Apr 27, 2012. The CNY was virtually unchanged relative to the USD by Aug 10, 2012 to CNY 6.3604/USD from the rate of CNY 6.3588/USD on Oct 28, 2011. Meanwhile, the Senate of the US is proceeding with a bill on China’s trade that could create a confrontation but may not be approved by the entire Congress.
Table ESVIII-1, Renminbi Yuan US Dollar Rate
CNY/USD | ∆% from 10/28/2011 | |
8/10/12 | 6.3604 | 0.0 |
8/3/12 | 6.3726 | -0.2 |
7/27/12 | 6.3818 | -0.4 |
7/20/12 | 6.3750 | -0.3 |
7/13/12 | 6.3868 | -0.4 |
7/6/12 | 6.3658 | -0.1 |
6/29/12 | 6.3552 | 0.1 |
6/22/12 | 6.3650 | -0.1 |
6/15/12 | 6.3678 | -0.1 |
6/8/2012 | 6.3752 | -0.3 |
6/1/2012 | 6.3708 | -0.2 |
4/27/2012 | 6.3016 | 0.9 |
3/23/2012 | 6.3008 | 0.9 |
2/3/2012 | 6.3030 | 0.9 |
12/30/2011 | 6.2940 | 1.0 |
11/25/2011 | 6.3816 | -0.4 |
10/28/2011 | 6.3588 | - |
Source:
http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/public/page/mdc_currencies.html?mod=mdc_topnav_2_3000
http://federalreserve.gov/releases/h10/Hist/dat00_ch.htm
Chart ESVIII-1 of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System provides the CNY/USD exchange rate from Aug 3, 2003 to Jul 27, 2012 together with US recession dates in shaded areas. China fixed the CNY/USD date for a long period as shown in the horizontal segment from 2000 to 2005. There was systematic revaluation of 17.6 percent from CNY 8.2765 on Jul 21, 2005 to CNY 6.8211 on Jul 15, 2008. China fixed the CNY/USD rate until Jun 7, 2010, to avoid adverse effects on its economy from the global recession, which is shown as a horizontal segment from 2009 until mid 2010. China then continued the policy of appreciation of the CNY relative to the USD with oscillations until the beginning of 2012 when the rate began to move sideways followed by a final upward slope of devaluation that is measured in Table ESVIII-1 but virtually disappeared in the rate of CNY 6,3604/USD on Aug 20, 2012. Revaluation of the CNY relative to the USD by 23.2 percent by Aug 10, 2012 has not reduced the trade surplus of China but reversal of the policy of revaluation could result in international confrontation. The upward slope in the final segment on the right of Chart ESVIII-1 is measured as virtually stability in Table ESVIII-1.
Chart ESVIII-1, Chinese Yuan (CNY) per US Dollar (US), Aug 12, 2003-Aug 3, 2012
Note: US Recessions in Shaded Areas
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
http://www.federalreserve.gov/datadownload/Choose.aspx?rel=H10
ESIX Global Financial and Economic Risk. The International Monetary Fund (IMF) provides an international safety net for prevention and resolution of international financial crises. The IMF’s Financial Sector Assessment Program (FSAP) provides analysis of the economic and financial sectors of countries (see Pelaez and Pelaez, International Financial Architecture (2005), 101-62, Globalization and the State, Vol. II (2008), 114-23). Relating economic and financial sectors is a challenging task both for theory and measurement. The IMF provides surveillance of the world economy with its Global Economic Outlook (WEO) (http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2012/update/01/index.htm), of the world financial system with its Global Financial Stability Report (GFSR) (http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fmu/eng/2012/01/index.htm) and of fiscal affairs with the Fiscal Monitor (http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fm/2012/update/01/fmindex.htm). There appears to be a moment of transition in global economic and financial variables that may prove of difficult analysis and measurement. It is useful to consider a summary of global economic and financial risks, which are analyzed in detail in the comments of this blog in Section VI Valuation of Risk Financial Assets, Table VI-4.
Economic risks include the following:
1. China’s Economic Growth. China is lowering its growth target to 7.5 percent per year. The growth rate of GDP of China in the second quarter of 2012 of 1.8 percent is equivalent to 7.4 percent per year.
2. United States Economic Growth, Labor Markets and Budget/Debt Quagmire. The US is growing slowly with 28.6 million in job stress, fewer 10 million full-time jobs, high youth unemployment, historically-low hiring and declining real wages.
3. Economic Growth and Labor Markets in Advanced Economies. Advanced economies are growing slowly. There is still high unemployment in advanced economies.
4. World Inflation Waves. Inflation continues in repetitive waves globally (see http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/destruction-of-three-trillion-dollars.html).
A list of financial uncertainties includes:
1. Euro Area Survival Risk. The resilience of the euro to fiscal and financial doubts on larger member countries is still an unknown risk.
2. Foreign Exchange Wars. Exchange rate struggles continue as zero interest rates in advanced economies induce devaluation of their currencies.
3. Valuation of Risk Financial Assets. Valuations of risk financial assets have reached extremely high levels in markets with lower volumes.
4. Duration Trap of the Zero Bound. The yield of the US 10-year Treasury rose from 2.031 percent on Mar 9, 2012, to 2.294 percent on Mar 16, 2012. Considering a 10-year Treasury with coupon of 2.625 percent and maturity in exactly 10 years, the price would fall from 105.3512 corresponding to yield of 2.031 percent to 102.9428 corresponding to yield of 2.294 percent, for loss in a week of 2.3 percent but far more in a position with leverage of 10:1. Min Zeng, writing on “Treasurys fall, ending brutal quarter,” published on Mar 30, 2012, in the Wall Street Journal (http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052702303816504577313400029412564.html?mod=WSJ_hps_sections_markets), informs that Treasury bonds maturing in more than 20 years lost 5.52 percent in the first quarter of 2012.
5. Credibility and Commitment of Central Bank Policy. There is a credibility issue of the commitment of monetary policy (Sargent and Silber 2012Mar20).
6. Carry Trades. Commodity prices driven by zero interest rates have resumed their increasing path with fluctuations caused by intermittent risk aversion.
It is in this context of economic and financial uncertainties that decisions on portfolio choices of risk financial assets must be made. There is a new carry trade that learned from the losses after the crisis of 2007 or learned from the crisis how to avoid losses. The sharp rise in valuations of risk financial assets shown in Table VI-1 in the text after the first policy round of near zero fed funds and quantitative easing by the equivalent of withdrawing supply with the suspension of the 30-year Treasury auction was on a smooth trend with relatively subdued fluctuations. The credit crisis and global recession have been followed by significant fluctuations originating in sovereign risk issues in Europe, doubts of continuing high growth and accelerating inflation in China now complicated by political developments, events such as in the Middle East and Japan and legislative restructuring, regulation, insufficient growth, falling real wages, depressed hiring and high job stress of unemployment and underemployment in the US now with realization of growth standstill. The “trend is your friend” motto of traders has been replaced with a “hit and realize profit” approach of managing positions to realize profits without sitting on positions. There is a trend of valuation of risk financial assets driven by the carry trade from zero interest rates with fluctuations provoked by events of risk aversion or the “sharp shifts in risk appetite” of Blanchard (2012WEOApr, XIII). Table ESIX-1, which is updated for every comment of this blog, shows the deep contraction of valuations of risk financial assets after the Apr 2010 sovereign risk issues in the fourth column “∆% to Trough.” There was sharp recovery after around Jul 2010 in the last column “∆% Trough to 8/10/12,” which has been recently stalling or reversing amidst profound risk aversion. “Let’s twist again” monetary policy during the week of Sep 23 caused deep worldwide risk aversion and selloff of risk financial assets (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/imf-view-of-world-economy-and-finance.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/collapse-of-household-income-and-wealth.html). Monetary policy was designed to increase risk appetite but instead suffocated risk exposures. There has been rollercoaster fluctuation in risk aversion and financial risk asset valuations: surge in the week of Dec 2, 2011, mixed performance of markets in the week of Dec 9, renewed risk aversion in the week of Dec 16, end-of-the-year relaxed risk aversion in thin markets in the weeks of Dec 23 and Dec 30, mixed sentiment in the weeks of Jan 6 and Jan 13 2012 and strength in the weeks of Jan 20, Jan 27 and Feb 3 followed by weakness in the week of Feb 10 but strength in the weeks of Feb 17 and 24 followed by uncertainty on financial counterparty risk in the weeks of Mar 2 and Mar 9. All financial values have fluctuated with events such as the surge in the week of Mar 16 on favorable news of Greece’s bailout even with new risk issues arising in the week of Mar 23 but renewed risk appetite in the week of Mar 30 because of the end of the quarter and the increase in the firewall of support of sovereign debts in the euro area. New risks developed in the week of Apr 6 with increase of yields of sovereign bonds of Spain and Italy, doubts on Fed policy and weak employment report. Asia and financial entities are experiencing their own risk environments. Financial markets were under stress in the week of Apr 13 because of the large exposure of Spanish banks to lending by the European Central Bank and the annual equivalent growth rate of China’s GDP of 7.4 percent in IQ2012 [(1.018)4], which was repeated in IIQ2012. There was strength again in the week of Apr 20 because of the enhanced IMF firewall and Spain placement of debt, continuing into the week of Apr 27. Risk aversion returned in the week of May 4 because of the expectation of elections in Europe and the new trend of deterioration of job creation in the US. Europe’s sovereign debt crisis and the fractured US job market continued to influence risk aversion in the week of May 11. Politics in Greece and banking issues in Spain were important factors of sharper risk aversion in the week of May 18. Risk aversion continued during the week of May 25 and exploded in the week of Jun 1. Expectations of stimulus by central banks caused valuation of risk financial assets in the week of Jun 8 and in the week of Jun 15. Expectations of major stimulus were frustrated by minor continuance of maturity extension policy in the week of Jun 22 together with doubts on the silent bank run in highly indebted euro area member countries. There was a major rally of valuations of risk financial assets in the week of Jun 29 with the announcement of new measures on bank resolutions by the European Council. New doubts surfaced in the week of Jul 6, 2012 on the implementation of the bank resolution mechanism and on the outlook for the world economy because of interest rate reductions by the European Central, Bank of England and People’s Bank of China. Risk appetite returned in the week of July 13 in relief that economic data suggests continuing high growth in China but fiscal and banking uncertainties in Spain spread to Italy in the selloff of July 20, 2012. Mario Draghi (2012Jul26), president of the European Central Bank, stated: “But there is another message I want to tell you.
Within our mandate, the ECB is ready to do whatever it takes to preserve the euro. And believe me, it will be enough.” This statement caused return of risk appetite, driving upward valuations of risk financial assets worldwide. Buiter (2011Oct31) analyzes that the European Financial Stability Fund (EFSF) would need a “bigger bazooka” to bail out euro members in difficulties that could possibly be provided by the ECB. The dimensions of the problem may require more firepower than a bazooka perhaps that of the largest conventional bomb of all times of 44,000 pounds experimentally detonated only once by the US in 1948 (http://www.airpower.au.af.mil/airchronicles/aureview/1967/mar-apr/coker.html). Risk appetite continued in the week of Aug 3, 2012, in expectation of purchases of sovereign bonds by the ECB. Growth of China’s exports by 1.0 percent in the 12 months ending in Jul 2012 released in the week of Aug 10, 2010, together with doubts on the purchases of bonds by the ECB injected a mild dose of risk aversion. The highest valuations in column “∆% Trough to 8/10/12” are by US equities indexes: DJIA 36.4 percent and S&P 500 37.5 percent, driven by stronger earnings and economy in the US than in other advanced economies but with doubts on the relation of business revenue to the weakening economy and fractured job market. The DJIA reached 13,331.77 in intraday trading on Mar 16, which is the highest level in 52 weeks (http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/public/page/marketsdata.html?mod=WSJ_PRO_hps_marketdata). The carry trade from zero interest rates to leveraged positions in risk financial assets had proved strongest for commodity exposures but US equities have regained leadership. Before the current round of risk aversion, almost all assets in the column “∆% Trough to 8/10/12” had double digit gains relative to the trough around Jul 2, 2010 but now most valuations of equity indexes show increase of less than 10 percent: China’s Shanghai Composite is 8.9 percent below the trough; Japan’s Nikkei Average is 0.8 percent above the trough; DJ Asia Pacific TSM is 7.0 percent above the trough; Dow Global is 10.4 percent above the trough; STOXX 50 of European equities is 11.5 percent above the trough; and NYSE Financial is 6.6 percent above the trough. DJ UBS Commodities is 15.3 percent above the trough. DAX is 22.5 percent above the trough. Japan’s Nikkei Average is 0.8 percent above the trough on Aug 31, 2010 and 21.9 percent below the peak on Apr 5, 2010. The Nikkei Average closed at 8891.44 on Fri Aug 10, 2012 (http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/public/page/marketsdata.html?mod=WSJ_PRO_hps_marketdata), which is 13.3 percent lower than 10,254.43 on Mar 11, 2011, on the date of the Tōhoku or Great East Japan Earthquake/tsunami. Global risk aversion erased the earlier gains of the Nikkei. The dollar depreciated by 3.1 percent relative to the euro and even higher before the new bout of sovereign risk issues in Europe. The column “∆% week to 8/10/12” in Table ESIX-1 shows that there were increases of valuations of risk financial assets in the week of Aug 3, 2012 such as 1.1 percent for DAX, 1.3 percent for STOXX 50 of European equities, 0.8 percent for NYSE Financial, 2.9 percent DJ Asia Pacific TSM, 1.7 percent Shanghai Composite and 2.0 percent for Dow Global. DJ UBS Commodities increased 0.2 percent. No valuation decreased. The DJIA increased 0.9 percent and S&P 500 increased 1.1 percent. The USD appreciated 0.8 percent. There are still high uncertainties on European sovereign risks and banking soundness, US and world growth slowdown and China’s growth tradeoffs. Sovereign problems in the “periphery” of Europe and fears of slower growth in Asia and the US cause risk aversion with trading caution instead of more aggressive risk exposures. There is a fundamental change in Table ESIX-1 from the relatively upward trend with oscillations since the sovereign risk event of Apr-Jul 2010. Performance is best assessed in the column “∆% Peak to 8/10/12” that provides the percentage change from the peak in Apr 2010 before the sovereign risk event to Aug 10, 2012. Most risk financial assets had gained not only relative to the trough as shown in column “∆% Trough to 8/10/12” but also relative to the peak in column “∆% Peak to 8/10/12.” There are now only three equity indexes above the peak in Table ESIX-1: DJIA 17.9 percent, S&P 500 15.5 percent and DAX 9.7 percent. There are several indexes below the peak: NYSE Financial Index (http://www.nyse.com/about/listed/nykid.shtml) by 15.1 percent, Nikkei Average by 21.9 percent, Shanghai Composite by 31.5 percent, DJ Asia Pacific by 6.3 percent, STOXX 50 by 5.5 percent and Dow Global by 9.9 percent. DJ UBS Commodities Index is now 1.3 percent below the peak. The US dollar strengthened 18.8 percent relative to the peak. The factors of risk aversion have adversely affected the performance of risk financial assets. The performance relative to the peak in Apr 2010 is more important than the performance relative to the trough around early Jul 2010 because improvement could signal that conditions have returned to normal levels before European sovereign doubts in Apr 2010. An intriguing issue is the difference in performance of valuations of risk financial assets and economic growth and employment. Paul A. Samuelson (http://www.nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economics/laureates/1970/samuelson-bio.html) popularized the view of the elusive relation between stock markets and economic activity in an often-quoted phrase “the stock market has predicted nine of the last five recessions.” In the presence of zero interest rates forever, valuations of risk financial assets are likely to differ from the performance of the overall economy. The interrelations of financial and economic variables prove difficult to analyze and measure.
Table ESIX-1, Stock Indexes, Commodities, Dollar and 10-Year Treasury
Peak | Trough | ∆% to Trough | ∆% Peak to 8/10/ /12 | ∆% Week 8/10/12 | ∆% Trough to 8/10/ 12 | |
DJIA | 4/26/ | 7/2/10 | -13.6 | 17.9 | 0.9 | 36.4 |
S&P 500 | 4/23/ | 7/20/ | -16.0 | 15.5 | 1.1 | 37.5 |
NYSE Finance | 4/15/ | 7/2/10 | -20.3 | -15.1 | 0.8 | 6.6 |
Dow Global | 4/15/ | 7/2/10 | -18.4 | -9.9 | 2.0 | 10.4 |
Asia Pacific | 4/15/ | 7/2/10 | -12.5 | -6.3 | 2.9 | 7.0 |
Japan Nikkei Aver. | 4/05/ | 8/31/ | -22.5 | -21.9 | 3.9 | 0.8 |
China Shang. | 4/15/ | 7/02 | -24.7 | -31.5 | 1.7 | -8.9 |
STOXX 50 | 4/15/10 | 7/2/10 | -15.3 | -5.5 | 1.3 | 11.5 |
DAX | 4/26/ | 5/25/ | -10.5 | 9.7 | 1.1 | 22.5 |
Dollar | 11/25 2009 | 6/7 | 21.2 | 18.8 | 0.8 | -3.1 |
DJ UBS Comm. | 1/6/ | 7/2/10 | -14.5 | -1.3 | 0.2 | 15.5 |
10-Year T Note | 4/5/ | 4/6/10 | 3.986 | 1.658 |
T: trough; Dollar: positive sign appreciation relative to euro (less dollars paid per euro), negative sign depreciation relative to euro (more dollars paid per euro)
Source: http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/page/marketsdata.html?mod=WSJ_hps_marketdata
I Recovery without Hiring. Professor Edward P. Lazear (2012Jan19) at Stanford University finds that recovery of hiring in the US to peaks attained in 2007 requires an increase of hiring by 30 percent while hiring levels have increased by only 4 percent since Jan 2009. The high level of unemployment with low level of hiring reduces the statistical probability that the unemployed will find a job. According to Lazear (2012Jan19), the probability of finding a new job currently is about one third of the probability of finding a job in 2007. Improvements in labor markets have not increased the probability of finding a new job. Lazear (2012Jan19) quotes an essay coauthored with James R. Spletzer forthcoming in the American Economic Review on the concept of churn. A dynamic labor market occurs when a similar amount of workers is hired as those who are separated. This replacement of separated workers is called churn, which explains about two-thirds of total hiring. Typically, wage increases received in a new job are higher by 8 percent. Lazear (2012Jan19) argues that churn has declined 35 percent from the level before the recession in IVQ2007. Because of the collapse of churn there are no opportunities in escaping falling real wages by moving to another job. As this blog argues, there are meager chances of escaping unemployment because of the collapse of hiring and those employed cannot escape falling real wages by moving to another job (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/08/twenty-nine-million-unemployed-or.html ). Lazear and Spletzer (2012Mar, 1) argue that reductions of churn reduce the operational effectiveness of labor markets. Churn is part of the allocation of resources or in this case labor to occupations of higher marginal returns. The decline in churn can harm static and dynamic economic efficiency. Losses from decline of churn during recessions can affect an economy over the long-term by preventing optimal growth trajectories because resources are not used in the occupations where they provide highest marginal returns. Lazear and Spletzer (2012Mar 7-8) conclude that: “under a number of assumptions, we estimate that the loss in output during the recession [of 2007 to 2009] and its aftermath resulting from reduced churn equaled $208 billion. On an annual basis, this amounts to about .4% of GDP for a period of 3½ years.”
There are two additional facts discussed below: (1) there are about ten million fewer full-time jobs currently than before the recession of 2008 and 2009; and (2) the extremely high and rigid rate of youth unemployment is denying an early start to young people ages 16 to 24 years while unemployment of ages 45 years or over has swelled. There are four subsections. IA Hiring Collapse provides the data and analysis on the weakness of hiring in the United States economy. IB Labor Underutilization provides the measures of labor underutilization of the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS). Statistics on the decline of full-time employment are in IC Ten Million Fewer Full-time Jobs. ID Youth and Middle-Age Unemployment provides the data on high unemployment of ages 16 to 24 years and of ages 45 years or over.
IA Hiring Collapse. An important characteristic of the current fractured labor market of the US is the closing of the avenue for exiting unemployment and underemployment normally available through dynamic hiring. Another avenue that is closed is the opportunity for advancement in moving to new jobs that pay better salaries and benefits again because of the collapse of hiring in the United States. Those who are unemployed or underemployed cannot find a new job even accepting lower wages and no benefits. The employed cannot escape declining inflation-adjusted earnings because there is no hiring. The objective of this section is to analyze hiring and labor underutilization in the United States.
An appropriate measure of job stress is considered by Blanchard and Katz (1997, 53):
“The right measure of the state of the labor market is the exit rate from unemployment, defined as the number of hires divided by the number unemployed, rather than the unemployment rate itself. What matters to the unemployed is not how many of them there are, but how many of them there are in relation to the number of hires by firms.”
The natural rate of unemployment and the similar NAIRU are quite difficult to estimate in practice (Ibid; see Ball and Mankiw 2002).
The Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) created the Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey (JOLTS) with the purpose that (http://www.bls.gov/jlt/jltover.htm#purpose):
“These data serve as demand-side indicators of labor shortages at the national level. Prior to JOLTS, there was no economic indicator of the unmet demand for labor with which to assess the presence or extent of labor shortages in the United States. The availability of unfilled jobs—the jobs opening rate—is an important measure of tightness of job markets, parallel to existing measures of unemployment.”
The BLS collects data from about 16,000 US business establishments in nonagricultural industries through the 50 states and DC. The data are released monthly and constitute an important complement to other data provided by the BLS (see also Lazear and Spletzer 2012Mar, 6-7).
Hiring in the nonfarm sector (HNF) has declined from 69.4 million in 2004 to 50.1 million in 2011 or by 19.3 million while hiring in the private sector (HP) has declined from 59.5 million in 2006 to 46.9 million in 2011 or by 12.6 million, as shown in Table I-1. The ratio of nonfarm hiring to employment (RNF) has fallen from 47.2 in 2005 to 38.1 in 2011 and in the private sector (RHP) from 52.1 in 2006 to 42.9 in 2011. The collapse of hiring in the US has not been followed by dynamic labor markets because of the low rate of economic growth of 2.2 percent in the first twelve quarters of expansion from IIIQ2009 to IIQ2012 compared with 6.2 percent in prior cyclical expansions (see table I-5 in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/07/decelerating-united-states-recovery.html).
Table I-1, US, Annual Total Nonfarm Hiring (HNF) and Total Private Hiring (HP) in the US and Percentage of Total Employment
Percentage of Total Employment
HNF | Rate RNF | HP | Rate HP | |
2001 | 62,948 | 47.8 | 58,825 | 53.1 |
2002 | 58,583 | 44.9 | 54,759 | 50.3 |
2003 | 56,451 | 43.4 | 53,056 | 48.9 |
2004 | 69,367 | 45.9 | 56,617 | 51.6 |
2005 | 63,150 | 47.2 | 59,372 | 53.1 |
2006 | 63,773 | 46.9 | 59,494 | 52.1 |
2007 | 62,421 | 45.4 | 58,035 | 50.3 |
2008 | 55,166 | 40.3 | 51,606 | 45.2 |
2009 | 46,398 | 35.5 | 43,052 | 39.8 |
2010 | 48,647 | 37.5 | 44,826 | 41.7 |
2011 | 50,083 | 38.1 | 46,869 | 42.9 |
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
Chart I-1 provides the yearly levels of total nonfarm hiring (NFH) in Table I-1. The fall of hiring during the contraction of 2007 to 2009 was much stronger than in the shallow recession of 2001 with GDP contraction of only 0.4 percent from Mar 2001 (IQ2001) to Dec 2001 (IVQ 2001) compared with 4.7 percent contraction in the much longer recession from Dec 2007 (IVQ2007) to Jun 2009 (IIQ2009) (http://www.nber.org/cycles/cyclesmain.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/07/decelerating-united-states-recovery.html). Recovery is tepid.
Chart I-1, US, Level Total Nonfarm Hiring (HNF), Annual, 2001-2011
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
Chart I-2 shows the ratio or rate of nonfarm hiring to employment (RNF) that also fell much more in the recession of 2007 to 2009 than in the shallow recession of 2001. Recovery is weak.
Chart I-2, US, Rate Total Nonfarm Hiring (HNF), Annual, 2001-2011
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
Yearly percentage changes of total nonfarm hiring (HNF) are provided in Table I-2. There were much milder declines in 2002 of 6.9 percent and 3.6 percent in 2003 followed by strong rebounds of 6.9 percent in 2004 and 4.6 percent in 2005. In contrast, the contractions of nonfarm hiring in the recession after 2007 were much sharper in percentage points: 2.1 in 2007, 11.6 in 2008 and 15.9 percent in 2009. On a yearly basis, nonfarm hiring grew 4.8 percent in 2010 relative to 2009 and 3.0 percent in 2011.
Table I-2, US, Annual Total Nonfarm Hiring (HNF), Annual Percentage Change, 2001-2011
Year | Annual |
2002 | -6.9 |
2003 | -3.6 |
2004 | 6.9 |
2005 | 4.6 |
2006 | 1.0 |
2007 | -2.1 |
2008 | -11.6 |
2009 | -15.9 |
2010 | 4.8 |
2011 | 3.0 |
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
Chart I-3 plots yearly percentage changes of nonfarm hiring. Percentage declines after 2007 were quite sharp.
Chart I-3, US, Annual Total Nonfarm Hiring (HNF), Annual Percentage Change, 2001-2011
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
Total private hiring (HP) yearly data are provided in Chart I-4. There has been sharp contraction of total private hiring in the US and only milder recovery in 2011 than in 2010.
Chart I-4, US, Total Private Hiring, Annual, 2001-2011
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
Chart I-5 plots the rate of total private hiring relative to employment (RHP). The rate collapsed during the global recession after 2007 with insufficient recovery.
Chart I-5, US, Rate Total Private Hiring, Annual, 2001-2011
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
Total nonfarm hiring (HNF), total private hiring (HP) and their respective rates are provided for the month of Jun in the years from 2001 to 2012 in Table I-3. Hiring numbers are in thousands. There is some recovery in HNF from 4278 thousand (or 4.2 million) in Jun 2009 to 4869 thousand in Jun 2011 and 5057 thousand in Jun 2012 for cumulative gain of 18.2 percent. HP rose from 3925 thousand in Jun 2009 to 4513 thousand in Jun 2011 and 4663 thousand in Jun 2012 for cumulative gain of 18.8 percent. HNF has fallen from 6139 in Jun 2006 to 5057 in Jun 2012 or by 17.6 percent. HP has fallen from 5661 in Jun 2006 to 4663 in Jun 2012 or by 17.6 percent. The labor market continues to be fractured, failing to provide an opportunity to exit from unemployment/underemployment or to find an opportunity for advancement away from declining inflation-adjusted earnings.
Table I-3, US, Total Nonfarm Hiring (HNF) and Total Private Hiring (HP) in the US in Thousands and in Percentage of Total Employment Not Seasonally Adjusted
HNF | Rate RNF | HP | Rate HP | |
2001 Jun | 5819 | 4.4 | 5531 | 4.8 |
2002 Jun | 5471 | 4.2 | 5054 | 4.6 |
2003 Jun | 5369 | 4.1 | 4975 | 4.6 |
2004 Jun | 5703 | 4.3 | 5309 | 4.8 |
2005 Jun | 6069 | 4.5 | 5675 | 5.0 |
2006 Jun | 6139 | 4.5 | 5661 | 4.9 |
2007 Jun | 6033 | 4.3 | 5535 | 4.7 |
2008 Jun | 5501 | 4.0 | 5087 | 4.4 |
2009 Jun | 4278 | 3.3 | 3925 | 3.6 |
2010 Jun | 4717 | 3.6 | 4341 | 4.0 |
2011 Jun | 4869 | 3.7 | 4513 | 4.1 |
2012 Jun | 5057 | 3.8 | 4663 | 4.2 |
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
Chart I-6 provides total nonfarm hiring on a monthly basis from 2001 to 2012. Nonfarm hiring rebounded in early 2010 but then fell and stabilized at a lower level than the early peak not-seasonally adjusted (NSA) of 4786 in May 2010. Nonfarm hiring fell again in Dec 2011 to 3038 from 3844 in Nov and to revised 3633 in Feb 2012, increasing to 4127 in Mar 2012, 4490 in Apr 2012, 4926 in May 2012 and 5057 in Jun 2012. Chart I-6 provides seasonally-adjusted (SA) monthly data. The number of seasonally-adjusted hires in Aug 2011 was 4221 thousand, increasing to revised 4444 thousand in Feb 2012, or 5.3 percent, but falling to revised 4335 thousand in Mar 2012 and 4213 in Apr 2012, or cumulative decline of 0.2 percent relative to Aug 2011, increasing to 4361 in Jun 2012 for cumulative increase of 2.0 percent from 4276 in Sep 2012. The number of hires not seasonally adjusted was 4655 in Aug 2011, falling to 3038 in Dec but increasing to 4072 in Jan 2012, increasing to 5057 in May 2012. The number of nonfarm hiring not seasonally adjusted fell by 34.7 percent from 4655 in Aug 2011 to 3038 in Dec 2011 in a yearly-repeated seasonal pattern.
Chart I-6, US, Total Nonfarm Hiring (HNF), 2001-2012 Month SA
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
Similar behavior occurs in the rate of nonfarm hiring plot in Chart I-7. Recovery in early 2010 was followed by decline and stabilization at a lower level but with stability in monthly SA estimates of 3.2 in Sep 2011 to 3.2 in Jan 2012, increasing to 3.4 in May 2012 and 3.3 in Jun 2012. The rate not seasonally adjusted fell from 3.7 in Jun 2011 to 2.3 in Dec, climbing to 3.1 in Jan 2012 and 3.8 in Jun 2012. Rates of nonfarm hiring NSA were in the range of 2.8 (Dec) to 4.5 (Jun) in 2006.
Chart I-7, US, Rate Total Nonfarm Hiring, Month SA 2001-2012
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
There is only milder improvement in total private hiring shown in Chart I-8. Hiring private (HP) rose in 2010 followed by stability and renewed increase in 2011. The number of private hiring seasonally adjusted fell from 4002 thousand in Sep 2011 to 3889 in Dec or by 2.8 percent, increasing to 3945 in Jan 2012 or decline by 1.4 relative to the level in Sep 2011 but increasing to 4080 in Jun 2012 or by 1.9 percent relative to Sep 2011. The number of private hiring not seasonally adjusted fell from 4130 in Sep 2011 to 2856 in Dec or by 30.8 percent, reaching 3782 in Jan 2012 or decline of 8.4 percent relative to Sep 2011 but increasing to 4663 in Jun 2012 or 12.9 percent relative to Sep 2011. Companies do not hire in the latter part of the year that explains the high seasonality in year-end employment data. For example, NSA private hiring fell from 4934 in Sep 2006 to 3635 in Dec 2006 or by 26.3 percent. Private hiring NSA data are useful in showing the huge declines from the period before the global recession. In Jul 2006 private hiring NSA was 5555, declining to 4293 in Jul 2011 or by 22.7 percent. The conclusion is that private hiring in the US is more than 20 percent below the hiring before the global recession. The main problem in recovery of the US labor market has been the low rate of growth of 2.2 percent in the eleven quarters of expansion of the economy from IIIQ2009 to IIQ2012 compared with average 6.2 percent in prior expansions from contractions (see table I-5 in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/07/decelerating-united-states-recovery.html). The US missed the opportunity to recover employment as in past cyclical expansions from contractions.
Chart I-8, US, Total Private Hiring Month SA 2011-2012
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
Chart I-9 shows similar behavior in the rate of private hiring. The rate in 2011 in monthly SA data has not risen significantly above the peak in 2010. The rate seasonally adjusted fell from 3.6 in Sep 2011 to 3.5 in Dec 2011, increasing to 3.6 in Jan 2012 and 3.7 in Jun 2012. The rate not seasonally adjusted (NSA) fell from 3.8 in Sep 2011 to 2.6 in Dec 2011, increasing to revised 3.5 in Jan 2012 and 4.2 in Jun 2012. The NSA rate of private hiring fell from 4.9 in Jun 2006 to 3.6 in Jun 2009 but recovery was insufficient to only 4.1 in Jun 2011.
Chart I-9, US, Rate Total Private Hiring Month SA 2011-2011
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
The JOLTS report of the Bureau of Labor Statistics also provides total nonfarm job openings (TNF JOB), TNF JOB rate and TNF LD (layoffs and discharges) shown in Table I-4 for the month of Jun from 2001 to 2012. The final column provides annual TNF LD for the years from 2001 to 2011. Nonfarm job openings fell from a peak of 4595 in Jun 2007 to 3723 in Jun 2012 or by 19.0 percent while the rate dropped from 3.2 to 2.7. Nonfarm layoffs and discharges (TNF LD) rose from 1687 in Jun 2006 to 2014 in Jun 2009 or by 19.4 percent. The annual data show layoffs and discharges rising from 21.2 million in 2006 to 26.8 million in 2009 or by 26.4 percent.
Table I-4, US, Job Openings and Total Separations, Thousands NSA
TNF JOB | TNF JOB | TNF LD | TNF LD | |
Jun 2001 | 4243 | 3.1 | 1821 | 24499 |
Jun 2002 | 3191 | 2.4 | 1725 | 22922 |
Jun 2003 | 3133 | 2.3 | 1925 | 23294 |
Jun 2004 | 3322 | 2.4 | 1728 | 22802 |
Jun 2005 | 3926 | 2.8 | 1811 | 22185 |
Jun 2006 | 4230 | 3.0 | 1687 | 21157 |
Jun 2007 | 4595 | 3.2 | 1727 | 22142 |
Jun 2008 | 3718 | 2.6 | 1868 | 24166 |
Jun 2009 | 2356 | 1.8 | 2014 | 26783 |
Jun 2010 | 2616 | 2.0 | 1936 | 21784 |
Jun 2011 | 3158 | 2.3 | 1759 | 20718 |
Jun 2012 | 3723 | 2.7 | 1721 |
Notes: TNF JOB: Total Nonfarm Job Openings; LD: Layoffs and Discharges
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
Chart I-10 shows monthly job openings rising from the trough in 2009 to a high in the beginning of 2010. Job openings then stabilized into 2011 but have surpassed the peak of 3057 seasonally adjusted in Nov 2010 with 3762 seasonally adjusted in Jun 2012, which is higher by 7.5 percent than 3501 in Sep 2011 and higher by 2.9 percent relative to 3657 in May 2012. The high of job openings not seasonally adjusted in 2010 was 3221 in Oct 2010 that was surpassed by 3659 in Oct 2011, increasing to 3723 in Jun 2012. The level of job openings not seasonally adjusted fell to 2912 in Nov 2011 or by 17.9 percent relative to 3546 in Sep 2011. There is here again the strong seasonality of year-end labor data. Job openings NSA fell from 4678 in Oct 2006 to 2547 in Oct 2009 or by 45.6 percent, recovering to 3221 in Oct 2010 or by 26.5 percent, which is still 21.8 percent lower at 3659 in Oct 2011 relative to Oct 2006. The level of job openings of 3723 in Jun 2011 NSA is lower by 12.0 percent relative to 4230 in Jun 2006. Again, the main problem in recovery of the US labor market has been the low rate of growth of 2.2 percent in the eleven quarters of expansion of the economy since IIIQ2009 compared with average 6.2 percent in prior expansions from contractions (see table I-5 in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/07/decelerating-united-states-recovery.html). The US missed the opportunity to recover employment as in past cyclical expansions from contractions.
Chart I-10, US Job Openings, Thousands NSA, 2001-2012
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
The rate of job openings in Chart I-11 shows similar behavior. The rate seasonally adjusted rose from 2.1 percent in Jan 2011 to 2.6 percent in Dec 2011 and 2.7 in Jun 2012. The rate not seasonally adjusted rose from the high of 2.6 in Apr 2010 to 2.7 in Jul 2011 and 2.7 in all months from Jan to Jun 2012 with exception of 2.5 in Feb 2012. The rate of job openings NSA fell from 3.2 in Jun 2007 to 1.8 in Jun 2009, recovering insufficiently to 2.7 in Jun 2012.
Chart I-11, US, Rate of Job Openings, NSA, 2001-2012
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
Total separations are shown in Chart I-12. Separations are much lower in 2012 than before the global recession.
Chart I-12, US, Total Separations, Month SA, 2001-2012
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
Yearly total separations are shown in Chart I-13. Separations are much lower in 2011 than before the global recession.
Chart I-13, US, Total Separations, Annual, 2001-2011
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
Table I-5 provides total nonfarm total separations from 2001 to 2011. Separations fell from 61.6 million in 2006 to 47.6 million in 2010 or by 14.0 million and 48.2 million in 2011 or by 13.4 million.
Table I-5, US, Total Nonfarm Total Separations, Thousands, 2001-2011
Year | Annual |
2001 | 64765 |
2002 | 59190 |
2003 | 56487 |
2004 | 58340 |
2005 | 60733 |
2006 | 61565 |
2007 | 61162 |
2008 | 58601 |
2009 | 51527 |
2010 | 47641 |
2011 | 48242 |
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
Monthly data of layoffs and discharges reach a peak in early 2009, as shown in Chart I-14. Layoffs and discharges dropped sharply with the recovery of the economy in 2010 and 2011 once employers reduced their job count to what was required for cost reductions and loss of business.
Chart I-14, US, Total Nonfarm Layoffs and Discharges, Monthly SA, 2011-2012
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
Layoffs and discharges in Chart I-15 rose sharply to a peak in 2009. There was pronounced drop into 2010 and 2011.
Chart I-15, US, Total Nonfarm Layoffs and Discharges, Annual, 2001-2011
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
Table I-6 provides annual nonfarm layoffs and discharges from 2001 to 2011. Layoffs and discharges peaked at 26.8 million in 2009 and then fell to 20.7 million in 2011, by 6.1 million, or 22.8 percent.
Table I-6, US, Total Nonfarm Layoffs and Discharges, 2001-2011
Year | Annual |
2001 | 24499 |
2002 | 22922 |
2003 | 23294 |
2004 | 22802 |
2005 | 22185 |
2006 | 21157 |
2007 | 22142 |
2008 | 24166 |
2009 | 26783 |
2010 | 21784 |
2011 | 20718 |
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/jlt/data.htm
IB Labor Underutilization. The Bureau of Labor Statistics also provides alternative measures of labor underutilization shown in Table I-7. The most comprehensive measure is U6 that consists of total unemployed plus total employed part time for economic reasons plus all marginally attached workers as percent of the labor force. U6 not seasonally annualized has risen from 8.2 percent in 2006 to 15.2 in Jul 2012.
Table I-7, US, Alternative Measures of Labor Underutilization NSA %
U1 | U2 | U3 | U4 | U5 | U6 | |
2012 | ||||||
Jul | 4.3 | 4.6 | 8.6 | 9.1 | 10.0 | 15.2 |
Jun | 4.5 | 4.4 | 8.4 | 8.9 | 9.9 | 15.1 |
May | 4.7 | 4.3 | 7.9 | 8.4 | 9.3 | 14.3 |
Apr | 4.8 | 4.3 | 7.7 | 8.3 | 9.1 | 14.1 |
Mar | 4.9 | 4.8 | 8.4 | 8.9 | 9.7 | 14.8 |
Feb | 4.9 | 5.1 | 8.7 | 9.3 | 10.2 | 15.6 |
Jan | 4.9 | 5.4 | 8.8 | 9.4 | 10.5 | 16.2 |
2011 | ||||||
Dec | 4.8 | 5.0 | 8.3 | 8.8 | 9.8 | 15.2 |
Nov | 4.9 | 4.7 | 8.2 | 8.9 | 9.7 | 15.0 |
Oct | 5.0 | 4.8 | 8.5 | 9.1 | 10.0 | 15.3 |
Sep | 5.2 | 5.0 | 8.8 | 9.4 | 10.2 | 15.7 |
Aug | 5.2 | 5.1 | 9.1 | 9.6 | 10.6 | 16.1 |
Jul | 5.2 | 5.2 | 9.3 | 10.0 | 10.9 | 16.3 |
Jun | 5.1 | 5.1 | 9.3 | 9.9 | 10.9 | 16.4 |
May | 5.5 | 5.1 | 8.7 | 9.2 | 10.0 | 15.4 |
Apr | 5.5 | 5.2 | 8.7 | 9.2 | 10.1 | 15.5 |
Mar | 5.7 | 5.8 | 9.2 | 9.7 | 10.6 | 16.2 |
Feb | 5.6 | 6.0 | 9.5 | 10.1 | 11.1 | 16.7 |
Jan | 5.6 | 6.2 | 9.8 | 10.4 | 11.4 | 17.3 |
Dec 2010 | 5.4 | 5.9 | 9.1 | 9.9 | 10.7 | 16.6 |
2011 | 5.3 | 5.3 | 8.9 | 9.5 | 10.4 | 15.9 |
2010 | 5.7 | 6.0 | 9.6 | 10.3 | 11.1 | 16.7 |
2009 | 4.7 | 5.9 | 9.3 | 9.7 | 10.5 | 16.2 |
2008 | 2.1 | 3.1 | 5.8 | 6.1 | 6.8 | 10.5 |
2007 | 1.5 | 2.3 | 4.6 | 4.9 | 5.5 | 8.3 |
2006 | 1.5 | 2.2 | 4.6 | 4.9 | 5.5 | 8.2 |
2005 | 1.8 | 2.5 | 5.1 | 5.4 | 6.1 | 8.9 |
2004 | 2.1 | 2.8 | 5.5 | 5.8 | 6.5 | 9.6 |
2003 | 2.3 | 3.3 | 6.0 | 6.3 | 7.0 | 10.1 |
2002 | 2.0 | 3.2 | 5.8 | 6.0 | 6.7 | 9.6 |
2001 | 1.2 | 2.4 | 4.7 | 4.9 | 5.6 | 8.1 |
2000 | 0.9 | 1.8 | 4.0 | 4.2 | 4.8 | 7.0 |
Note: LF: labor force; U1, persons unemployed 15 weeks % LF; U2, job losers and persons who completed temporary jobs %LF; U3, total unemployed % LF; U4, total unemployed plus discouraged workers, plus all other marginally attached workers; % LF plus discouraged workers; U5, total unemployed, plus discouraged workers, plus all other marginally attached workers % LF plus all marginally attached workers; U6, total unemployed, plus all marginally attached workers, plus total employed part time for economic reasons % LF plus all marginally attached workers
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/cps/data.htm
Monthly seasonally adjusted measures of labor underutilization are provided in Table I-8. U6 climbed from 16.2 percent in Aug 2011 to 16.4 percent in Sep 2011 and then fell to 14.5 percent in Apr 2012, increasing to 15.0 percent in Jul 2012. Unemployment is an incomplete measure of the stress in US job markets. A different calculation in this blog is provided by using the participation rate in the labor force before the global recession. This calculation shows 28.8 million in job stress of unemployment/underemployment in Jul 2012, not seasonally adjusted, corresponding to 17.9 percent of the labor force (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/08/twenty-nine-million-unemployed-or.html Table I-4).
Table I-8, US, Alternative Measures of Labor Underutilization SA %
U1 | U2 | U3 | U4 | U5 | U6 | |
Jul 2012 | 4.5 | 4.6 | 8.3 | 8.8 | 9.7 | 15.0 |
Jun | 4.6 | 4.6 | 8.2 | 8.7 | 9.7 | 14.9 |
May | 4.6 | 4.5 | 8.2 | 8.7 | 9.6 | 14.8 |
Apr | 4.5 | 4.4 | 8.1 | 8.7 | 9.5 | 14.5 |
Mar | 4.6 | 4.5 | 8.2 | 8.7 | 9.6 | 14.5 |
Feb | 4.8 | 4.7 | 8.3 | 8.9 | 9.8 | 14.9 |
Jan | 4.9 | 4.7 | 8.3 | 8.9 | 9.9 | 15.1 |
Dec 2011 | 5.0 | 4.9 | 8.5 | 9.1 | 10.0 | 15.2 |
Nov | 5.0 | 4.9 | 8.7 | 9.3 | 10.2 | 15.6 |
Oct | 5.1 | 5.1 | 8.9 | 9.5 | 10.4 | 16.0 |
Sep | 5.3 | 5.2 | 9.0 | 9.6 | 10.5 | 16.4 |
Aug | 5.3 | 5.3 | 9.1 | 9.6 | 10.6 | 16.2 |
Jul | 5.3 | 5.3 | 9.1 | 9.7 | 10.7 | 16.1 |
Jun | 5.3 | 5.4 | 9.1 | 9.7 | 10.7 | 16.2 |
May | 5.3 | 5.4 | 9.0 | 9.5 | 10.3 | 15.8 |
Apr | 5.2 | 5.3 | 9.0 | 9.6 | 10.4 | 15.9 |
Mar | 5.3 | 5.4 | 8.9 | 9.4 | 10.3 | 15.7 |
Feb | 5.4 | 5.4 | 9.0 | 9.6 | 10.6 | 15.9 |
Jan | 5.5 | 5.5 | 9.1 | 9.7 | 10.7 | 16.1 |
Note: LF: labor force; U1, persons unemployed 15 weeks % LF; U2, job losers and persons who completed temporary jobs %LF; U3, total unemployed % LF; U4, total unemployed plus discouraged workers, plus all other marginally attached workers; % LF plus discouraged workers; U5, total unemployed, plus discouraged workers, plus all other marginally attached workers % LF plus all marginally attached workers; U6, total unemployed, plus all marginally attached workers, plus total employed part time for economic reasons % LF plus all marginally attached workers
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/cps/data.htm
Chart I-16 provides U6 on a monthly basis from 2001 to 2012. There was a steep climb from 2007 into 2009 and then this measure of unemployment and underemployment stabilized at that high level but declined into 2012. The low of U16 SA was 7.9 percent in Dec 2006 and the peak was 17.2 percent in Oct 2009. The low NSA was 7.6 percent in Oct 2006 and the peak was 18.0 percent in Jan 2010.
Chart I-16, US, U6, total unemployed, plus all marginally attached workers, plus total employed part time for economic reasons % LF plus all marginally attached workers as % of Labor Force, Month, SA, 2001-2012
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/cps/data.htm
Chart I-17 provides the number employed part-time for economic reasons or who cannot find full-time employment. There are sharp declines at the end of 2009, 2010 and 2011 but an increase in 2012.
Chart I-17, US, Working Part-time for Economic Reasons
Thousands, Month SA 2001-2012
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/cps/data.htm
There is strong seasonality in US labor markets around the end of the year. The number employed part-time for economic reasons because they could not find full-time employment fell from 9.270 million in Sep 2011 to 8.246 million in Jun 2010, seasonally adjusted, or decline of 1.024 million in nine months, as shown in Table I-9. The number employed full-time increased from 112.479 million in Sep 2011 to 115.290 million in Mar 2012 or 2.811 million but then fell to 114.212 million in May 2012 or 1.078 million fewer full-time employed than in Mar 2012. There is a jump in the level of full-time SA to 114.573 million in Jun 2012 or 361,000 relative to May 2012 but then decline to 114.345 million in Jul 2012 or decline of 228,000 full time jobs from Jun 2012 into Jul 2012. The number of employed part-time for economic reasons actually increased without seasonal adjustment from 8.271 million in Nov 2011 to 8.428 million in Dec 2011 or by 157,000 and then to 8.918 million in Jan 2012 or by an additional 490,000 for cumulative increase from Nov 2011 to Jan 2012 of 647,000. The level of employed part-time for economic reasons then fell from 8.918 million in Jan 2012 to 7.867 million in Mar 2012 or by 1.0151 million and to 7.694 million in Apr 2012 or 1.224 million fewer relative to Jan 2012. In Jul, the number employed part-time for economic reasons reached 8.316 million SA or 622,000 more than in Apr 2012. The number employed full time without seasonal adjustment fell from 113.138 million in Nov 2011 to 113.050 million in Dec 2011 or by 88,000 and fell further to 111.879 in Jan 2012 for cumulative decrease of 1.259 million. The number employed full-time not seasonally adjusted fell from 113.138 million in Nov 2011 to 112.587 million in Feb 2012 or by 551.000 but increased to 116.024 million in Jun 2012 or 2.886 million more full-time jobs than in Nov 2011. Comparisons over long periods require use of NSA data. The number with full-time jobs fell from a high of 123.219 million in Jul 2007 to 108.770 million in Jan 2010 or by 14.442 million. The number with full-time jobs in Jul 2012 is 116.131 million, which is lower by 7.1 million relative to the peak of 123.219 million in Jul 2007. There appear to be around 10 million fewer full-time jobs in the US than before the global recession. Growth at 2.2 percent on average in the eleven quarters of expansion from IIIQ2009 to IIQ2012 compared with 6.2 percent on average in expansions from postwar cyclical contractions is the main culprit of the fractured US labor market (see table I-5 in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/07/decelerating-united-states-recovery.html).
Table I-9, US, Employed Part-time for Economic Reasons, Thousands, and Full-time, Millions
Part-time Thousands | Full-time Millions | |
Seasonally Adjusted | ||
Jul 2012 | 8,246 | 114.345 |
Jun 2012 | 8,210 | 114.573 |
May 2012 | 8,098 | 114.212 |
Apr 2012 | 7,853 | 114.478 |
Mar 2012 | 7,672 | 115.290 |
Feb 2012 | 8,119 | 114.408 |
Jan 2012 | 8,230 | 113.845 |
Dec 2011 | 8,098 | 113.765 |
Nov 2011 | 8,469 | 113.212 |
Oct 2011 | 8,790 | 112.841 |
Sep 2011 | 9,270 | 112.479 |
Aug 2011 | 8,787 | 112.406 |
Jul 2011 | 8,437 | 112.006 |
Not Seasonally Adjusted | ||
Jul 2012 | 8,316 | 116.131 |
Jun 2012 | 8,394 | 116.024 |
May 2012 | 7,837 | 114.634 |
Apr 2012 | 7,694 | 113.999 |
Mar 2012 | 7,867 | 113.916 |
Feb 2012 | 8,455 | 112.587 |
Jan 2012 | 8,918 | 111.879 |
Dec 2011 | 8,428 | 113.050 |
Nov 2011 | 8,271 | 113.138 |
Oct 2011 | 8,258 | 113.456 |
Jul 2011 | 8,514 | 113.759 |
Jun 2011 | 8,738 | 113.255 |
May 2011 | 8,270 | 112.618 |
Apr 2011 | 8,425 | 111.844 |
Mar 2011 | 8,737 | 111.186 |
Feb 2011 | 8,749 | 110.731 |
Jan 2011 | 9,187 | 110.373 |
Dec 2010 | 9,205 | 111.207 |
Nov 2010 | 8,670 | 111.348 |
Oct 2010 | 8,408 | 112.342 |
Jul 2010 | 8,737 | 113.974 |
Jun 2010 | 8,867 | 113.856 |
May 2010 | 8,513 | 112.809 |
Apr 2010 | 8,921 | 111.391 |
Mar 2010 | 9,343 | 109.877 |
Feb 2010 | 9,282 | 109.100 |
Jan 2010 | 9,290 | 108.777 (low) |
Dec 2009 | 9,354 (high) | 109.875 |
Jul 2009 | 9,103 | 114.184 |
Jun 2009 | 9,301 | 114.014 |
May 2009 | 8,785 | 113.083 |
Apr 2009 | 8,648 | 112.746 |
Mar 2009 | 9,305 | 112.215 |
Feb 2009 | 9,170 | 112.947 |
Jan 2009 | 8,829 | 113.815 |
Jul 2008 | 6,054 | 122.378 |
Jun 2008 | 5,697 | 121.845 |
May 2008 | 5,096 | 120.809 |
Apr 2008 | 5,071 | 120.027 |
Mar 2008 | 5,038 | 119.875 |
Feb 2008 | 5,114 | 119.452 |
Jan 2008 | 5,340 | 119.322 |
Jul 2007 | 4,516 | 123.219 (high) |
Jun 2007 | 4,469 | 122.150 |
May 2007 | 4,315 | 120.846 |
Apr 2007 | 4,205 | 119.609 |
Mar 2007 | 4,384 | 119.640 |
Feb 2007 | 4,417 | 119.041 |
Jan 2007 | 4,726 | 119.094 |
Sep 2006 | 3,735 (low) | 120.780 |
Jul 2006 | 4,450 | 121.951 |
Jun 2006 | 4,456 | 121.070 |
May 2006 | 3,968 | 118.925 |
Apr 2006 | 3,787 | 118.559 |
Mar 2006 | 4,097 | 117.693 |
Feb 2006 | 4,403 | 116.823 |
Jan 2006 | 4,597 | 116.395 |
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/cps/data.htm
People lose their marketable job skills after prolonged unemployment and find increasing difficulty in finding another job. Chart I-18 shows the sharp rise in unemployed over 27 weeks and stabilization at an extremely high level.
Chart I-18, US, Number Unemployed for 27 Weeks or Over, Thousands SA Month 2001-2011
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/cps/data.htm
Another segment of U6 consists of people marginally attached to the labor force who continue to seek employment but less frequently on the frustration there may not be a job for them. Chart I-19 shows the sharp rise in people marginally attached to the labor force after 2007 and subsequent stabilization.
Chart I-19, US, Marginally Attached to the Labor Force, NSA Month 2001-2012
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/cps/data.htm
IC Ten Million Fewer Full-time Jobs. Chart I-20 reveals the fracture in the US labor market. The number of workers with full-time jobs not-seasonally-adjusted rose with fluctuations from 2002 to a peak in 2007, collapsing during the global recession. The terrible state of the job market is shown in the segment from 2009 to 2012 with fluctuations around the typical behavior of a stationary series: there is no improvement in the United States in creating full-time jobs.
Chart I-20, US, Full-time Employed, Thousands, NSA, 2001-2012
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/cps/data.htm
ID Youth Unemployment. The United States is experiencing high youth unemployment as in European economies. Table I-10 provides the employment level for ages 16 to 24 years of age estimated by the Bureau of Labor Statistics. On an annual basis, youth employment fell from 20.041 million in 2006 to 17.362 million in 2011 or 2.679 million fewer youth jobs. During the seasonal peak months of youth employment in the summer from Jun to Aug, youth employment has fallen by more than two million jobs. There are two hardships behind these data. First, young people cannot find employment after finishing high-school and college, reducing prospects for achievement in older age. Second, students with more modest means cannot find employment to keep them in college.
Table I-10, US, Employment Level 16-24 Years, Thousands, NSA
Year | Apr | May | Jun | Jul | Annual |
2001 | 19778 | 19648 | 21212 | 22042 | 20088 |
2002 | 19108 | 19484 | 20828 | 21501 | 19683 |
2003 | 18873 | 19032 | 20432 | 20950 | 19351 |
2004 | 19184 | 19237 | 20587 | 21447 | 19630 |
2005 | 19071 | 19356 | 20949 | 21749 | 19770 |
2006 | 19406 | 19769 | 21268 | 21914 | 20041 |
2007 | 19368 | 19457 | 21098 | 21717 | 19875 |
2008 | 19161 | 19254 | 20466 | 21021 | 19202 |
2009 | 17739 | 17588 | 18726 | 19304 | 17601 |
2010 | 16764 | 17039 | 17920 | 18564 | 17077 |
2011 | 16970 | 17045 | 18180 | 18632 | 17362 |
2012 | 17387 | 17681 | 18907 | 19461 |
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
Chart I-21 provides US employment level ages 16 to 24 years from 2002 to 2012. Employment level is sharply lower in Jun 2012 relative to the peak in 2007.
Chart I-21, US, Employment Level 16-24 Years, Thousands SA, 2001-2012
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
Table I-11 provides US unemployment level ages 16 to 24 years. The number unemployed ages 16 to 24 years increased from 2342 thousand in 2007 to 3634 thousand in 2011 or by 1.292 million. This situation may persist for many years.
Table I-11, US, Unemployment Level 16-24 Years, Thousands NSA
Year | Apr | May | Jun | Jul | Aug | Annual |
2001 | 2095 | 2171 | 2775 | 2585 | 2461 | 2371 |
2002 | 2515 | 2568 | 3167 | 3034 | 2688 | 2683 |
2003 | 2572 | 2838 | 3542 | 3200 | 2724 | 2746 |
2004 | 2387 | 2684 | 3191 | 3018 | 2585 | 2638 |
2005 | 2398 | 2619 | 3010 | 2688 | 2519 | 2521 |
2006 | 2092 | 2254 | 2860 | 2750 | 2467 | 2353 |
2007 | 2074 | 2203 | 2883 | 2622 | 2388 | 2342 |
2008 | 2196 | 2952 | 3450 | 3408 | 2990 | 2830 |
2009 | 3321 | 3851 | 4653 | 4387 | 4004 | 3760 |
2010 | 3803 | 3854 | 4481 | 4374 | 3903 | 3857 |
2011 | 3365 | 3628 | 4248 | 4110 | 3820 | 3634 |
2012 | 3175 | 3438 | 4180 | 4011 |
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/cps/data.htm
Chart I-22 provides the unemployment level ages 16 to 24 from 2002 to 2012. The level rose sharply from 2007 to 2010 with tepid improvement into 2012.
Chart I-22, US, Unemployment Level 16-24 Years, Thousands SA, 2001-2012
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
Table I-12 provides the rate of unemployment of young peoples in ages 16 to 24 years. The annual rate jumped from 10.5 percent in 2007 to 18.4 percent in 2010 and 17.3 percent in 2011. During the seasonal peak in Jul 2011 the rate of youth unemployed was 18.1 percent compared with 10.8 percent in Jun 2007.
Table I-12, US, Unemployment Rate 16-24 Years, Thousands, NSA
Year | Apr | May | Jun | Jul | Aug | Annual |
2001 | 9.6 | 10.0 | 11.6 | 10.5 | 10.7 | 10.6 |
2002 | 11.6 | 11.6 | 13.2 | 12.4 | 11.5 | 12.0 |
2003 | 12.0 | 13.0 | 14.8 | 13.3 | 11.9 | 12.4 |
2004 | 11.1 | 12.2 | 13.4 | 12.3 | 11.1 | 11.8 |
2005 | 11.2 | 11.9 | 12.6 | 11.0 | 10.8 | 11.3 |
2006 | 9.7 | 10.2 | 11.9 | 11.2 | 10.4 | 10.5 |
2007 | 9.7 | 10.2 | 12.0 | 10.8 | 10.5 | 10.5 |
2008 | 10.3 | 13.3 | 14.4 | 14.0 | 13.0 | 12.8 |
2009 | 15.8 | 18.0 | 19.9 | 18.5 | 18.0 | 17.6 |
2010 | 18.5 | 18.4 | 20.0 | 19.1 | 17.8 | 18.4 |
2011 | 16.5 | 17.5 | 18.9 | 18.1 | 17.5 | 17.3 |
2012 | 15.4 | 16.3 | 18.1 | 17.1 |
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
Chart I-23 provides the BLS estimate of the not-seasonally-adjusted rate of youth unemployment for ages 16 to 24 years from 2002 to 2012. The rate of youth unemployment increased sharply during the global recession of 2008 and 2009 but has failed to drop to earlier lower levels during the eleven quarters of expansion of the economy since IIIQ2009.
Chart I-23, US, Unemployment Rate 16-24 Years, Thousands, NSA, 2001-2012
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
Chart I-24 provides longer perspective with the rate of youth unemployment in ages 16 to 24 years from 1948 to 2012. The rate of youth unemployment rose to 20 percent during the contractions of the early 1980s and also during the contraction of the global recession in 2008 and 2009. The data illustrate again the claim in this blog that the contractions of the early 1980s are the valid framework for comparison with the global recession of 2008 and 2009 instead of misleading comparisons with the 1930s. During the initial phase of recovery, the rate of youth unemployment 16 to 24 years NSA fell from 18.9 percent in Jun 1983 to 14.5 percent in Jun 1984 while the rate of youth unemployment 16 to 24 years was nearly the same during the expansion after IIIQ2009: 19.9 percent in Jun 2009, 20.0 percent in Jun 2010, 18.9 percent in Jun 2011 and 18.1 percent in Jun 2012. The difference originates in the vigorous seasonally-adjusted annual equivalent average rate of GDP growth of 5.7 percent during the recovery from IQ1983 to IVQ1985 compared with 2.2 percent on average during the first eleven quarters of expansion from IIIQ2009 to IIQ2012 (see table I-5 in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/07/decelerating-united-states-recovery.html). The fractured US labor market denies an early start for young people.
Chart I-24, US, Unemployment Rate 16-24 Years, Percent NSA, 1948-2012
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
It is more difficult to move to other jobs after a certain age because of fewer available opportunities for matured individuals than for new entrants into the labor force. Middle-aged unemployed are less likely to find another job. Table I-13 provides the unemployment level ages 45 years and over. The number unemployed ages 45 years and over rose from 1.985 million in Jul 2006 to 4.821 million in July 2010 or by 142.9 percent. The number of unemployed ages 45 years and over declined to 4.405 million in Jul 2012 that is still higher by 121.9 percent than in Jul 2006.
Table I-13, US, Unemployment Level 45 Years and Over, Thousands NSA
Year | Apr | May | Jun | Jul | Aug | Annual |
2001 | 1421 | 1259 | 1371 | 1539 | 1640 | 1576 |
2002 | 2101 | 1999 | 2190 | 2173 | 2114 | 2114 |
2003 | 2287 | 2112 | 2212 | 2281 | 2301 | 2253 |
2004 | 2160 | 2025 | 2182 | 2116 | 2082 | 2149 |
2005 | 1939 | 1844 | 1868 | 2119 | 1895 | 2009 |
2006 | 1843 | 1784 | 1813 | 1985 | 1869 | 1848 |
2007 | 1871 | 1803 | 1805 | 2053 | 1956 | 1966 |
2008 | 2104 | 2095 | 2211 | 2492 | 2695 | 2540 |
2009 | 4172 | 4175 | 4505 | 4757 | 4683 | 4500 |
2010 | 4770 | 4565 | 4564 | 4821 | 5128 | 4879 |
2011 | 4373 | 4356 | 4559 | 4772 | 4592 | 4537 |
2012 | 4037 | 4083 | 4084 | 4405 |
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
Chart I-25 provides the level unemployed ages 45 years and over. There was sharp increase during the global recession and inadequate decline. There was an increase during the 2001 recession and then stability. The US is facing another challenge of reemploying middle-aged workers.
Chart I-25, US, Unemployment Level Ages 45 Years and Over, Thousands, NSA, 1976-2012
Sources: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
II United States International Trade. There are two subsections: IIA United States International Trade Balance and IIB United States Import and Export Prices.
IIA United States International Trade Balance. The United States Census Bureau has released revisions of trade statistics from Jan 2009 to Mar 2012 (http://www.census.gov/foreign-trade/Press-Release/2011pr/final_revisions/). Table IIA-1 provides the trade balance of the US and monthly growth of exports and imports seasonally adjusted with the latest release and revisions (http://www.census.gov/foreign-trade/). Because of heavy dependence on imported oil, fluctuations in the US trade account originate largely in fluctuations of commodity futures prices caused by carry trades from zero interest rates into commodity futures exposures in a process similar to world inflation waves (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/07/world-inflation-waves-financial.html). The US trade balance improved from deficit of $52,617 million in Mar 2012 to deficit of $50,597 million in Apr 2012 and lower deficits of $48,044 million in May and $42,294 million in Jun. Growth of exports in Jun of 0.9 percent was higher than growth of imports of minus 1.5 percent. The deterioration of the trade deficit from $45,433 million in Feb to $52,617 million in Mar resulted from growth of exports of 2.5 percent while imports jumped 5.2 percent. The US trade balance had improved from deficit of $52,947 million in Jan 2012 to lower deficit of $45,433 million in Feb 2012 mostly because of decline of imports by 2.6 percent while exports increased 0.8 percent. The US trade balance deteriorated sharply from Nov 2011 to Jan 2012 with growth of imports by cumulative 3.2 percent and cumulative decline of exports of 0.1 percent, resulting in deficits of $48,835 million in Nov, $51,748 million in Dec and $52,947 million in Jan, which are the highest since $50,234 million in Jun 2011. In the months of Jun to Oct 2011, exports increased 1.8 percent while imports increased 0.5 percent, resulting in improvement of the trade deficit from $50,234 million in Jun to $45,703 million in Oct. The trade balance deteriorated from cumulative deficit of $493,737 million in Jan-Dec 2010 to deficit of $559,880 million in Jan-Dec 2011.
Table IIA-1, US, Trade Balance of Goods and Services Seasonally Adjusted Millions of Dollars and ∆%
Trade Balance | Exports | Month ∆% | Imports | Month ∆% | |
Jun 2012 | -42,294 | 184,972 | 0.9 | 227,896 | -1.5 |
May | -48,044 | 183,306 | 0.3 | 231,350 | -0.8 |
Apr | -50,597 | 182,733 | -0.9 | 233,330 | -1.6 |
Mar | -52,617 | 184,443 | 2.5 | 237,061 | 5.2 |
Feb | -45,433 | 179,969 | 0.8 | 225,402 | -2.6 |
Jan | -52,947 | 178,509 | 0.4 | 231,455 | 0.9 |
Dec 2011 | -51,748 | 177,751 | 0.6 | 229,499 | 1.8 |
Nov | -48,835 | 176,710 | -1.1 | 225,545 | 0.5 |
Oct | -45,703 | 178,742 | -1.0 | 224,445 | -0.3 |
Sep | -44,467 | 180,629 | 1.3 | 225,096 | 0.9 |
Aug | -44,775 | 178,382 | 0.0 | 223,157 | -0.3 |
Jul | -45,580 | 178,339 | 3.3 | 223,919 | 0.4 |
Jun | -50,234 | 172,664 | -1.7 | 222,988 | -0.2 |
May | -47,669 | 175,673 | 0.0 | 223,343 | 1.9 |
Apr | -43,556 | 175,662 | 0.9 | 219,218 | 0.1 |
Mar | -44,902 | 174,169 | 4.6 | 219,071 | 3.7 |
Feb | -44,801 | 166,545 | -0.9 | 211,346 | -2.0 |
Jan | -47,523 | 168,098 | 1.6 | 215,621 | 4.6 |
Dec 2010 | -40,677 | 165,499 | 1.7 | 206,176 | 2.2 |
Jan-Dec | -559,880 | 2,103,367 | 2,663,247 | ||
Jan-Dec | -494,737 | 1,842,485 | 2,337,222 |
Note: Trade Balance of Goods and Services = Exports of Goods and Services less Imports of Goods and Services. Trade balance may not add exactly because of errors of rounding and seasonality. Source: US Census Bureau http://www.census.gov/foreign-trade/
Table IIA-2 provides the US international trade balance, exports and imports on an annual basis from 1992 to 2011. The trade balance deteriorated sharply over the long term. The US has a large deficit in goods or exports less imports of goods but it has a surplus in services that helps to reduce the trade account deficit or exports less imports of goods and services. The current account deficit of the US increased from $119.9 billion in IQ2011, or 3.2 percent of GDP to $137.3 billion in IQ2012, or 3.6 percent of GDP (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/destruction-of-three-trillion-dollars_17.html). The ratio of the current account deficit to GDP has stabilized around 3 percent of GDP compared with much higher percentages before the recession (see Pelaez and Pelaez, The Global Recession Risk (2007), Globalization and the State, Vol. II (2008b), 183-94, Government Intervention in Globalization (2008c), 167-71).
Table IIA-2, US, International Trade Balance, Exports and Imports SA, Millions of Dollars
Period | Balance | Exports | Imports |
Total | |||
Annual | |||
1992 | -39,212 | 616,882 | 656,094 |
1993 | -70,311 | 642,863 | 713,174 |
1994 | -98,493 | 703,254 | 801,747 |
1995 | -96,384 | 794,387 | 890,771 |
1996 | -104,065 | 851,602 | 955,667 |
1997 | -108,273 | 934,453 | 1,042,726 |
1998 | -166,140 | 933,174 | 1,099,314 |
1999 | -263,160 | 967,008 | 1,230,168 |
2000 | -376,749 | 1,072,783 | 1,449,532 |
2001 | -361,771 | 1,007,726 | 1,369,496 |
2002 | -417,432 | 980,879 | 1,398,311 |
2003 | -490,984 | 1,023,519 | 1,514,503 |
2004 | -605,357 | 1,163,146 | 1,768,502 |
2005 | -708,624 | 1,287,441 | 1,996,065 |
2006 | -753,288 | 1,459,823 | 2,213,111 |
2007 | -696,728 | 1,654,561 | 2,351,289 |
2008 | -698,338 | 1,842,682 | 2,541,020 |
2009 | -379,154 | 1,578,945 | 1,958,099 |
2010 | -494,737 | 1,842,485 | 2,337,222 |
2011 | -559,880 | 2,103,367 | 2,663,247 |
Source: http://www.census.gov/foreign-trade/
Chart IIA-1 of the US Census Bureau of the Department of Commerce shows that the trade deficit (gap between exports and imports) fell during the economic contraction after 2007 but has grown again during the expansion. There was slight improvement at the margin from Jul to Oct 2011 but new increase in the gap from Nov 2011 to Jan 2012 and again in Mar as exports grow less rapidly than imports. There is improvement in Apr 2012 with imports declining at a faster rate of 1.6 percent than decline of exports by 0.9 percent and growth of exports of 0.3 percent in May 2012 with imports declining 0.8 percent. Further improvement occurred in Jun with importing increasing 0.9 percent and exports declining 1.5 percent. Weaker world and internal demand and fluctuating commodity price increases explain the declining or less dynamic changes in exports and imports in Chart IIA-1.
Chart IIA-1, US Balance, Exports and Imports of Goods and Services $ Billions
Source: US Census Bureau
http://www.census.gov/briefrm/esbr/www/esbr042.html
Chart IIA-2 of the US Census Bureau provides the US trade account in goods and services SA from Jan 1992 to Jun 2012. There is a long-term trend of deterioration of the US trade deficit shown vividly by Chart IIA-2. The trend of deterioration was reversed by the global recession from IVQ2007 to IIQ2009. Deterioration resumed together with recovery and was influenced significantly by the carry trade from zero interest rates to commodity futures exposures (these arguments are elaborated in Pelaez and Pelaez, Financial Regulation after the Global Recession (2009a), 157-66, Regulation of Banks and Finance (2009b), 217-27, International Financial Architecture (2005), 15-18, The Global Recession Risk (2007), 221-5, Globalization and the State Vol. II (2008b), 197-213, Government Intervention in Globalization (2008c), 182-4 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/07/causes-of-2007-creditdollar-crisis.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/professor-mckinnons-bubble-economy.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/world-inflation-quantitative-easing.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/treasury-yields-valuation-of-risk.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2010/11/quantitative-easing-theory-evidence-and.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2010/12/is-fed-printing-money-what-are.html). Earlier research focused on the long-term external imbalance of the US in the form of trade and current account deficits (Pelaez and Pelaez, The Global Recession Risk (2007), Globalization and the State Vol. II (2008b) 183-94, Government Intervention in Globalization (2008c), 167-71). US external imbalances have not been resolved and tend to widen together with improving world economic activity and commodity price shocks.
Chart IIA-2. US, Balance of Trade SA, Monthly Jan 1992-Jun 2012
Source: US Census Bureau
http://www.census.gov/foreign-trade/
The balance of international trade in goods of the US seasonally-adjusted is shown in Table IIA-3. The US has a dynamic surplus in services that reduces the large deficit in goods for a still very sizeable deficit in international trade of goods and services. The balance in international trade of goods improved from $65.6 billion in Jun 2011 to $57.5 billion in Jun 2012. Improvement of the goods balance in Jun 2012 relative to Jun 2011 occurred mostly in the petroleum balance, exports less imports of goods other than petroleum, in the magnitude of reducing the deficit by $6.8 billion, while there was moderate improvement in the nonpetroleum balance, exports less imports of petroleum goods, in the magnitude of reducing the deficit by $1.0 billion. US terms of trade, export prices relative to import prices, and the US trade account fluctuate in accordance with the carry trade from zero interest rates to commodity futures exposures, especially oil futures. Exports rose 9.1 percent with non-petroleum exports growing 8.8 percent. Total imports rose 1.6 percent with petroleum imports declining 13.0 percent and non-petroleum imports increasing 5.8 percent.
Table IIA-3, US, International Trade in Goods Balance, Exports and Imports $ Millions and ∆% SA
Jun 2012 | Jun 2011 | ∆% | |
Total Balance | -57,535 | -65,588 | |
Petroleum | -22,356 | -29,131 | |
Non Petroleum | -34,389 | -35,408 | |
Total Exports | 132,785 | 121,664 | 9.1 |
Petroleum | 10,371 | 8,701 | 19.2 |
Non Petroleum | 121,016 | 111,252 | 8.8 |
Total Imports | 190,320 | 187,253 | 1.6 |
Petroleum | 32,908 | 37,833 | -13.0 |
Non Petroleum | 155,405 | 146,940 | 5.8 |
Details may not add because of rounding and seasonal adjustment
Source: US Census Bureau http://www.census.gov/foreign-trade/
http://www.eia.gov/dnav/pet/hist/LeafHandler.ashx?n=PET&s=RCLC1&f=D
US exports and imports of goods not seasonally adjusted in Jan-Jun 2012 and Jan-Jun 2011 are shown in Table IIA-4. The rate of growth of exports was 7.1 percent and 6.0 percent for imports. The US has partial hedge of commodity price increases in exports of agricultural commodities that fell 4.4 percent and of mineral fuels that increased 13.3 percent both because of higher prices of raw materials and commodities that are falling again currently because of shocks of risk aversion. The US exports an insignificant amount of crude oil. US exports and imports consist mostly of manufactured products, with less rapidly increasing prices. US manufactured exports rose 8.2 percent while imports rose 8.1 percent. Significant part of the US trade imbalance originates in imports of mineral fuels declining by 0.9 percent and crude oil increasing 2.6 percent with significant decline at the margin in oil prices. The limited hedge in exports of agricultural commodities and mineral fuels compared with substantial imports of mineral fuels and crude oil results in waves of deterioration of the terms of trade of the US, or export prices relative to import prices, originating in commodity price increases caused by carry trades from zero interest rates. These waves are similar to those in worldwide inflation (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/07/world-inflation-waves-financial.html).
Table IIA-4, US, Exports and Imports of Goods, Not Seasonally Adjusted Millions of Dollars and %
Jan-Jun 2012 $ Millions | Jan-Jun 2011 $ Millions | ∆% | |
Exports | 773,619 | 722,659 | 7.1 |
Manufactured | 513,381 | 474,655 | 8.2 |
Agricultural | 67,241 | 70,357 | -4.4 |
Mineral Fuels | 67,297 | 59,418 | 13.3 |
Crude Oil | 813 | 681 | 19.4 |
Imports | 1,132,171 | 1,068,161 | 6.0 |
Manufactured | 834,677 | 772,453 | 8.1 |
Agricultural | 53,121 | 49,944 | 6.4 |
Mineral Fuels | 223,260 | 225,413 | -0.9 |
Crude Oil | 167,829 | 163,586 | 2.6 |
Source: US Census Bureau http://www.census.gov/foreign-trade/
IIB Import Export Prices. Chart IIB-1 provides prices of total US imports 2001-2012. Prices fell during the contraction of 2001. Import price inflation accelerated after unconventional monetary policy of near zero interest rates in 2003-2004 and quantitative easing by withdrawing supply with the suspension of 30-year Treasury bond auctions. Slow pace of adjusting fed funds rates from 1 percent by increments of 25 basis points in 17 consecutive meetings of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) between Jun 2004 and Jun 2006 continued to give impetus to carry trades. The reduction of fed funds rates toward zero in 2008 fueled a spectacular global hunt for yields that caused commodity price inflation in the middle of a global recession. After risk aversion in 2009 because of the announcement of TARP (Troubled Asset Relief Program) creating anxiety on “toxic assets” in bank balance sheets (see Cochrane and Zingales 2009), prices collapsed because of unwinding carry trades. Renewed price increases returned with zero interest rates and quantitative easing. Monetary policy impulses in massive doses have driven inflation and valuation of risk financial assets in wide fluctuations over a decade.
Chart IIB-1, US, Prices of Total US Imports 2001=100, 2001-2012
Source: http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm
Chart IIB-2 provides 12-month percentage changes of prices of total US imports from 2001 to 2012. The only plausible explanation for the wide oscillations is by the carry trade originating in unconventional monetary policy. Import prices jumped in 2008 during deep and protracted global recession driven by carry trades from zero interest rates to long, leveraged positions in commodity futures. Carry trades were unwound during the financial panic in the final quarter of 2008 that resulted in flight to government obligations. Import prices jumped again in 2009 with subdued risk aversion because US banks did not have unsustainable toxic assets. Import prices then fluctuated as carry trades were resumed during periods of risk appetite and unwound during risk aversion resulting from the European debt crisis.
Chart IIB-2, US, Prices of Total US Imports, 12-Month Percentage Changes, 2001-2012
Source: http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm
Chart IIB-3 provides prices of US imports from 1982 to 2012. There is no similar episode to that of the increase of commodity prices in 2008 during a protracted and deep global recession with subsequent collapse during a flight into government obligations. Trade prices have been driven by carry trades created by unconventional monetary policy in the past decade.
Chart IIB-3, US, Prices of Total US Imports, 2001=100, 1982-2012
Source: http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm
Chart IIB-4 provides 12-month percentage changes of US total imports from 1982 to 2012. There have not been wide consecutive oscillations as the ones during the global recession of IVQ2007 to IIQ2009.
Chart IIB-4, US, Prices of Total US Imports, 12-Month Percentage Changes, 1982-2012
Source: http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm
Chart IIB-5 provides the index of US export prices from 2001 to 2012. Import and export prices have been driven by impulses of unconventional monetary policy in massive doses. The most recent segment in Chart IIB-5 shows declining trend resulting from a combination of the world economic slowdown and the decline of commodity prices as carry trade exposures are unwound because of risk aversion to the sovereign debt crisis in Europe.
Chart IIB-5, US, Prices of Total US Exports, 2001=100, 2001-2012
Source: http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm
Chart IIB-6 provides prices of US total exports from 1982 to 2012. The rise before the global recession from 2003 to 2008, driven by carry trades, is also unique in the series and is followed by another steep increase after risk aversion moderated in IQ2009.
Chart IIB-6, US, Prices of Total US Exports, 2001=100, 1982-2012
Source: http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm
Chart IIB-7 provides 12-month percentage changes of total US exports from 1982 to 2012. The uniqueness of the oscillations around the global recession of IVQ2007 to IIQ2009 is clearly revealed.
Chart IIB-7, US, Prices of Total US Exports, 12-Month Percentage Changes, 1982-2012
Source: http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm
Twelve-month percentage changes of US prices of exports and imports are provided in Table IIB-1. Import prices have been driven since 2003 by unconventional monetary policy of near zero interest rates influencing commodity prices according to moods of risk aversion. In a global recession without risk aversion until the panic of Sep 2008 with flight to government obligations, import prices rose 21.4 percent in the twelve months ending in Jul 2008 and fell 19.1 percent in the 12 months ending in Jul 2009 when risk aversion developed in 2008 until mid 2009. Import prices rose again sharply in Jul 2010 by 4.9 percent and in Jul 2011 by 13.7 percent in the presence of zero interest rates with relaxed mood of risk aversion until carry trades were unwound in May 2011 and following months as shown by decline of import prices by 3.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Jul 2012 and of 1.2 percent in exports. Fluctuations are much sharper in imports because of the high content of oil that as all futures contracts increases sharply with zero interest rates and risk appetite, contracting under risk aversion. There is similar behavior of prices of imports ex fuels, exports and exports ex agricultural goods but less pronounced than for commodity-rich prices dominated by carry trades from zero interest rates. A critical event resulting from unconventional monetary policy driving higher commodity prices by carry trades is the deterioration of the terms of trade, or export prices relative to import prices, that has adversely affected US real income growth relative to what it would have been in the absence of unconventional monetary policy. Europe, Japan and other advanced economies have experienced similar deterioration of their terms of trade. Because of unwinding carry trades of commodity futures as a result of risk aversion, import prices fell 3.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Jul 2012, export prices fell 1.2 percent and prices of nonagricultural exports fell 1.9 percent. Imports excluding fuel were flat in the 12 months ending in Jul 2012.
Table IIB-1, US, Twelve-Month Percentage Rates of Change of Prices of Exports and Imports
Imports | Imports Ex Fuels | Exports | Exports Non-Ag | |
Jul 2012 | -3.2 | 0.0 | -1.2 | -1.9 |
Jul 2011 | 13.7 | 5.4 | 9.8 | 8.2 |
Jul 2010 | 4.9 | 2.8 | 3.9 | 4.1 |
Jul 2009 | -19.1 | -5.3 | -8.3 | -6.6 |
Jul 2008 | 21.4 | 6.7 | 10.2 | 7.6 |
Jul 2007 | 2.8 | 2.4 | 4.0 | 2.9 |
Jul 2006 | 7.0 | 2.5 | 4.5 | 4.7 |
Jul 2005 | 8.2 | 1.8 | 2.8 | 3.2 |
Jul 2004 | 5.6 | 2.3 | 4.5 | 3.7 |
Jul 2003 | 2.3 | 0.5 | 1.1 | 0.7 |
Jul 2002 | -1.7 | NA | -0.7 | -0.9 |
Jul 2001 | -4.1 | NA | -1.0 | -1.4 |
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm
Chart IIB-8 shows the US monthly import price index of all commodities excluding fuels from 2001 to 2012. All curves of nominal values follow the same behavior under the influence of unconventional monetary policy. Zero interest rates without risk aversion result in jumps of nominal values while under strong risk aversion even with zero interest rates there are declines of nominal values.
Chart IIB-8, US, Import Price Index All Commodities Excluding Fuels, 2001=100, 2001-2012
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm
Chart IB-9 provides 12-month percentage changes of the US import price index excluding fuels between 2001 and 2012. There is the same behavior of carry trades driving up without risk aversion and down with risk aversion prices of raw materials, commodities and food in international trade during the global recession of IVQ2007 to IIQ2009 and in previous and subsequent periods.
Chart IIB-9, US, Import Price Index All Commodities Excluding Fuels, 12-Month Percentage Changes, 2002-2012
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm
Chart IIB-10 provides the monthly US import price index ex petroleum from 2001 to 2012. Prices including or excluding commodities follow the same fluctuations and trends originating in impulses of unconventional monetary policy of zero interest rates.
Chart IIB-10, US, Import Price Index ex Petroleum, 2001=100, 2001-2012
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm
Chart IIB-11 provides the US import price index ex petroleum from 1982 to 2012. There is the same unique hump in 2008 caused by carry trades from zero interest rates to prices of commodities and raw materials.
Chart IIB-11, US, Import Price Index ex Petroleum, 2001=100, 1982-2012
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm
Chart IIB-12 provides 12-month percentage changes of the import price index ex petroleum from 1986 to 2012. The oscillations caused by the carry trade in increasing prices of commodities and raw materials without risk aversion and subsequently decreasing them during risk aversion are quite unique.
Chart IIB-12, US, Import Price Index ex Petroleum, 12-Month Percentage Changes, 1986-2012
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm
Chart IIB-13 of the US Energy Information Administration provides the price of the crude oil futures contract from 1985 to 2012. There is the same hump in 2008 as in all charts caused by the common factor of carry trades from zero interest rates to commodity futures positions with risk appetite and subsequent decline when carry trades were unwound during shocks of risk aversion.
Chart IIB-13, US, Crude Oil Futures Contract
Source: US Energy Information Administration
http://www.eia.gov/dnav/pet/hist/LeafHandler.ashx?n=PET&s=RCLC1&f=D
The price index of US imports of petroleum and petroleum products in shown in Chart IIB-14. There is similar behavior of the curves all driven by the same impulses of monetary policy.
Chart IIB-14, US, Import Price Index of Petroleum and Petroleum Products, 2001=100, 2001-2012
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm
Chart IIB-15 provides the price index of petroleum and petroleum products from 1982 to 2012. The rise in prices during the global recession in 2008 and the decline after the flight to government obligations is unique in the history of the series. Increases in prices of trade in petroleum and petroleum products were induced by carry trades and declines by unwinding carry trades in flight to government obligations.
Chart IIB-15, US, Import Price Index of Petroleum and Petroleum Products, 2001=100, 1982-2012
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm
Chart IIB-16 provides 12-month percentage changes of the price index of US imports of petroleum and petroleum products from 1982 to 2012. There were wider oscillations in this index from 1999 to 2001 (see Barsky and Killian 2004 for an explanation).
Chart IIB-16, US, Import Price Index of Petroleum and Petroleum Products, 12-Month Percentage Changes, 1982-2012
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm
The price index of US exports of agricultural commodities is in Chart IIB-17 from 2001 to 2012. There are similar fluctuations and trends as in all other price index originating in unconventional monetary policy repeated over a decade. The most recent segment in 2011 has declining trend in a new flight from risk resulting from the sovereign debt crisis in Europe followed by another decline in Jun 2012.
Chart IIB-17, US, Exports Price Index of Agricultural Commodities, 2001=100, 2001-2012
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm
Chart IIB-18 provides the price index of US exports of agricultural commodities from 1982 to 2012. The increase in 2008 in the middle of deep, protracted contraction was induced by unconventional monetary policy. The decline from 2008 into 2009 was caused by unwinding carry trades in a flight to government obligations. The increase into 2011 and current pause were also induced by unconventional monetary policy in waves of increases during relaxed risk aversion and declines during unwinding of positions because of aversion to financial risk.
Chart IIB-18, US, Exports Price Index of Agricultural Commodities, 2001=100, 1982-2012
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm
Chart IIB-19 provides 12-month percentage changes of the index of US exports of agricultural commodities from 1986 to 2012. The wide swings in 2008, 2009 and 2011 are only explained by unconventional monetary policy inducing carry trades from zero interest rates to commodity futures and reversals during risk aversion.
Chart IIB-19, US, Exports Price Index of Agricultural Commodities, 12-Month Percentage Changes, 1986-2012
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm
Chart IIB-20 shows the export price index of nonagricultural commodities from 2001 to 2012. Unconventional monetary policy of zero interest rates drove price behavior during the past decade. Policy has been based on the myth of stimulating the economy by climbing the negative slope of an imaginary short-term Phillips curve.
Chart IIB-20, US, Exports Price Index of Nonagricultural Commodities, 2001=100, 2001-2012
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm
Chart IIB-21 provides a longer perspective of the price index of US nonagricultural commodities from 1982 to 2012. Increases and decreases around the global contraction after 2007 were caused by carry trade induced by unconventional monetary policy.
Chart IIB-21, US, Exports Price Index of Nonagricultural Commodities, 2001=100, 1982-2012
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm
Finally, Chart IIB-22 provides 12-month percentage changes of the price index of US exports of nonagricultural commodities from 1986 to 2012. The wide swings before, during and after the global recession beginning in 2007 were caused by carry trades induced by unconventional monetary policy.
Chart IIB-22, US, Exports Price Index of Nonagricultural Commodities, 12-Month Percentage Changes, 1986-2012
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics
http://www.bls.gov/mxp/data.htm
III World Financial Turbulence. Financial markets are being shocked by multiple factors including (1) world economic slowdown; (2) slowing growth in China with political development and slowing growth in Japan and world trade; (3) slow growth propelled by savings reduction in the US with high unemployment/underemployment, falling wages and hiring collapse; and (3) the outcome of the sovereign debt crisis in Europe. This section provides current data and analysis. Subsection IIIA Financial Risks provides analysis of the evolution of valuations of risk assets during the week. There are various appendixes at the end of this section for convenience of reference of material related to the euro area debt crisis. Some of this material is updated in Subsection IIIA when new data are available and then maintained in the appendixes for future reference until updated again in Subsection IIIA. Subsection IIIB Appendix on Safe Haven Currencies discusses arguments and measures of currency intervention. Subsection IIIC Appendix on Fiscal Compact provides analysis of the restructuring of the fiscal affairs of the European Union in the agreement of European leaders reached on Dec 9, 2011. Subsection IIID Appendix on European Central Bank Large Scale Lender of Last Resort considers the policies of the European Central Bank. Appendix IIIE Euro Zone Survival Risk analyzes the threats to survival of the European Monetary Union. Subsection IIIF Appendix on Sovereign Bond Valuation provides more technical analysis. Subsection IIIG Appendix on Deficit Financing of Growth and the Debt Crisis provides analysis of proposals to finance growth with budget deficits together with experience of the economic history of Brazil.
IIIA Financial Risks. The past half year has been characterized by financial turbulence, attaining unusual magnitude in recent months. Table III-1, updated with every comment in this blog, provides beginning values on Fr Aug 3 and daily values throughout the week ending on Aug 10 of various financial assets. Section VI Valuation of Risk Financial Assets provides a set of more complete values. All data are for New York time at 5 PM. The first column provides the value on Fri Aug 3 and the percentage change in that prior week below the label of the financial risk asset. For example, the first column “Fri Aug 3, 2012”, first row “USD/EUR 1.2387 -0.5%,” provides the information that the US dollar (USD) depreciated 1.3 percent to USD 1.2387/EUR in the week ending on Fri Aug 3 relative to the exchange rate on Fri Jul 27. The first five asset rows provide five key exchange rates versus the dollar and the percentage cumulative appreciation (positive change or no sign) or depreciation (negative change or negative sign). Positive changes constitute appreciation of the relevant exchange rate and negative changes depreciation. Financial turbulence has been dominated by reactions to the new program for Greece (see section IB in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/07/debt-and-financial-risk-aversion-and.html), modifications and new approach adopted in the Euro Summit of Oct 26 (European Commission 2011Oct26SS, 2011Oct26MRES), doubts on the larger countries in the euro zone with sovereign risks such as Spain and Italy but expanding into possibly France and Germany, the growth standstill recession and long-term unsustainable government debt in the US, worldwide deceleration of economic growth and continuing waves of inflation. The most important current shock is that resulting from the agreement by European leaders at their meeting on Dec 9 (European Council 2911Dec9), which is analyzed in IIIC Appendix on Fiscal Compact. European leaders reached a new agreement on Jan 30 (http://www.consilium.europa.eu/uedocs/cms_data/docs/pressdata/en/ec/127631.pdf) and another agreement on Jun 29, 2012 (http://www.consilium.europa.eu/uedocs/cms_data/docs/pressdata/en/ec/131388.pdf).
The dollar/euro rate is quoted as number of US dollars USD per one euro EUR, USD 1.2387/EUR in the first row, first column in the block for currencies in Table III-1 for Fri Aug 3, depreciating to USD 1.2394/EUR on Mon Aug 6, or by 0.1 percent. The dollar depreciated because more dollars, $1.2394, were required on Mon Aug 6 to buy one euro than $1.2387 on Aug 3. Table III-1 defines a country’s exchange rate as number of units of domestic currency per unit of foreign currency. USD/EUR would be the definition of the exchange rate of the US and the inverse [1/(USD/EUR)] is the definition in this convention of the rate of exchange of the euro zone, EUR/USD. A convention used throughout this blog is required to maintain consistency in characterizing movements of the exchange rate such as in Table III-1 as appreciation and depreciation. The first row for each of the currencies shows the exchange rate at 5 PM New York time, such as USD 1.2394/EUR on Aug 6; the second row provides the cumulative percentage appreciation or depreciation of the exchange rate from the rate on the last business day of the prior week, in this case Fri Aug 3, to the last business day of the current week, in this case Fri Aug 10, such as appreciation by 0.8 percent to USD 1.2290/EUR by Aug 10; and the third row provides the percentage change from the prior business day to the current business day. For example, the USD appreciated (denoted by positive sign) by 0.8 percent from the rate of USD 1.2387/EUR on Fri Aug 3 to the rate of USD 1.2290/EUR on Fri Aug 10 {[(1.2290/1.2387) – 1]100 = -0.8%} and appreciated (denoted by positive sign) by 0.1 percent from the rate of USD 1.2304 on Thu Aug 9 to USD 1.2290/EUR on Fri Aug 10 {[(1.2290/1.2304) -1]100 = -0.1%}. Other factors constant, appreciation of the dollar relative to the euro is caused by increasing risk aversion, with rising uncertainty on European sovereign risks increasing dollar-denominated assets with sales of risk financial investments. Funds move away from higher yielding risk financial assets to the safety of dollar investments. When risk aversion declines, funds have been moving away from safe assets in dollars to risk financial assets, depreciating the dollar.
Table III-I, Weekly Financial Risk Assets Aug 6 to Aug 10, 2012
Fri Aug 3, 2012 | M 6 | Tue 7 | W 8 | Thu 9 | Fr 10 |
USD/EUR 1.2387 -0.5% | 1.2394 -0.1% -0.1% | 1.2391 0.0% 0.0% | 1.2363 0.2% 0.2% | 1.2304 0.7% 0.5% | 1.2290 0.8% 0.1% |
JPY/ USD 78.47 0.0% | 78.24 0.3% 0.3% | 78.62 -0.2% -0.5% | 78.45 0.0% 0.2% | 78.60 -0.2% -0.2% | 78.27 0.3% 0.4% |
CHF/ USD 0.9702 0.5% | 0.9692 0.1% 0.1% | 0.9695 0.1% 0.0% | 0.9717 -0.2% -0.2% | 0.9762 -0.6% -0.5% | 0.9771 -0.7% -0.1% |
CHF/ EUR 1.2017 0.0% | 1.2012 0.0% 0.0% | 1.2013 0.0% 0.0% | 1.2013 0.0% 0.0% | 1.2010 0.1% 0.0% | 1.2008 0.1% 0.0% |
USD/ AUD 1.0568 0.9463 0.8% | 1.0565 0.9465 0.0% 0.0% | 1.0547 0.9481 -0.2% -0.2% | 1.0574 0.9457 0.1% 0.3% | 1.0574 0.9457 0.1% 0.0% | 1.0577 0.9454 0.1% 0.0% |
10 Year T Note 1.569 | 1.57 | 1.63 | 1.65 | 1.69 | 1.658 |
2 Year T Note 0.242 | 0.24 | 0.26 | 0.27 | 0.27 | 0.267 |
German Bond 2Y -0.02 10Y 1.42 | 2Y -0.06 10Y 1.40 | 2Y -0.03 10Y 1.48 | 2Y -0.05% 10Y 1.42 | 2Y -0.06 10Y 1.43 | 2Y -0.07 10Y 1.38 |
Spain Bond 2Y 4.06 10Y 6.91 | 2Y 3.73 10Y 6.80 | 2Y 4.00 10Y 6.91 | 2Y 4.13 10Y 6.92 | 2Y 4.23 10Y 6.92 | |
DJIA 13096.17 0.2% | 13117.51 0.2% 0.2% | 13168.60 0.6% 0.4% | 13175.64 0.6% 0.1% | 13165.19 0.5% -0.1% | 13207.95 0.9% 0.3% |
DJ Global 1843.53 0.8% | 1862.76 1.0% 1.0% | 1878.42 1.9% 0.8% | 1878.88 1.9% 0.0% | 1880.25 2.0% 0.1% | 1880.18 2.0% 0.0% |
DJ Asia Pacific 1190.35 0.8% | 1210.96 1.7% 1.7% | 1215.67 2.1% 0.4% | 1220.63 2.5% 0.4% | 1228.41 3.2% 0.6% | 1225.22 2.9% -0.3% |
Nikkei 8555.11 -0.1% | 8726.29 2.0% 2.0% | 8803.31 2.9% 0.9% | 8881.16 3.8% 0.9% | 8978.60 4.9% 1.1% | 8891.44 3.9% -1.0% |
Shanghai 2132.80 0.2% | 2154.92 1.0% 1.0% | 2157.62 1.2% 0.1% | 2160.99 1.3% 0.2% | 2174.10 1.9% 0.6% | 2168.81 1.7% -0.2% |
DAX 6865.66 2.6% | 6918.72 0.8% 0.8% | 6967.95 1.5% 0.7% | 6966.15 1.5% 0.0 | 6964.99 1.4% 0.0 | 6944.56 1.1% -0.3% |
DJ UBS Comm. 142.92 -0.4% | 143.02 0.1% | 143.66 0.5% 0.4% | 143.99 0.7% 0.2% | 144.74 1.3% 0.5% | 143.20 0.2% -1.1% |
WTI $ B 91.40 1.4% | 91.86 0.5% 0.5% | 93.47 2.3% 1.8% | 93.42 2.2% -0.1% | 93.46 2.3% 0.0% | 92.87 1.6% -0.6% |
Brent $/B 108.94 2.3% | 109.55 0.6% 0.6% | 112.00 2.8% 2.2% | 111.98 2.8% 0.0% | 113.22 3.9% 1.1% | 112.95 3.7% -0.2% |
Gold $/OZ 1609.3 -0.8% | 1613.6 0.3% 0.3% | 1615.3 0.4% 0.1% | 1614.9 0.3% 0.0% | 1620.3 0.7% 0.3% | 1622.8 0.8% 0.2% |
Note: USD: US dollar; JPY: Japanese Yen; CHF: Swiss
Franc; AUD: Australian dollar; Comm.: commodities; OZ: ounce
Sources: http://www.bloomberg.com/markets/
http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/page/marketsdata.html?mod=WSJ_hps_marketdata
III World Financial Turbulence. Financial markets are being shocked by multiple factors including (1) world economic slowdown; (2) slowing growth in China with political development and slowing growth in Japan and world trade; (3) slow growth propelled by savings reduction in the US with high unemployment/underemployment, falling wages and hiring collapse; and (3) the outcome of the sovereign debt crisis in Europe. This section provides current data and analysis. Subsection IIIA Financial Risks provides analysis of the evolution of valuations of risk assets during the week. There are various appendixes at the end of this section for convenience of reference of material related to the euro area debt crisis. Some of this material is updated in Subsection IIIA when new data are available and then maintained in the appendixes for future reference until updated again in Subsection IIIA. Subsection IIIB Appendix on Safe Haven Currencies discusses arguments and measures of currency intervention. Subsection IIIC Appendix on Fiscal Compact provides analysis of the restructuring of the fiscal affairs of the European Union in the agreement of European leaders reached on Dec 9, 2011. Subsection IIID Appendix on European Central Bank Large Scale Lender of Last Resort considers the policies of the European Central Bank. Appendix IIIE Euro Zone Survival Risk analyzes the threats to survival of the European Monetary Union. Subsection IIIF Appendix on Sovereign Bond Valuation provides more technical analysis. Subsection IIIG Appendix on Deficit Financing of Growth and the Debt Crisis provides analysis of proposals to finance growth with budget deficits together with experience of the economic history of Brazil.
IIIA Financial Risks. The past half year has been characterized by financial turbulence, attaining unusual magnitude in recent months. Table III-1, updated with every comment in this blog, provides beginning values on Fr Aug 3 and daily values throughout the week ending on Aug 10 of various financial assets. Section VI Valuation of Risk Financial Assets provides a set of more complete values. All data are for New York time at 5 PM. The first column provides the value on Fri Aug 3 and the percentage change in that prior week below the label of the financial risk asset. For example, the first column “Fri Aug 3, 2012”, first row “USD/EUR 1.2387 -0.5%,” provides the information that the US dollar (USD) depreciated 1.3 percent to USD 1.2387/EUR in the week ending on Fri Aug 3 relative to the exchange rate on Fri Jul 27. The first five asset rows provide five key exchange rates versus the dollar and the percentage cumulative appreciation (positive change or no sign) or depreciation (negative change or negative sign). Positive changes constitute appreciation of the relevant exchange rate and negative changes depreciation. Financial turbulence has been dominated by reactions to the new program for Greece (see section IB in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/07/debt-and-financial-risk-aversion-and.html), modifications and new approach adopted in the Euro Summit of Oct 26 (European Commission 2011Oct26SS, 2011Oct26MRES), doubts on the larger countries in the euro zone with sovereign risks such as Spain and Italy but expanding into possibly France and Germany, the growth standstill recession and long-term unsustainable government debt in the US, worldwide deceleration of economic growth and continuing waves of inflation. The most important current shock is that resulting from the agreement by European leaders at their meeting on Dec 9 (European Council 2911Dec9), which is analyzed in IIIC Appendix on Fiscal Compact. European leaders reached a new agreement on Jan 30 (http://www.consilium.europa.eu/uedocs/cms_data/docs/pressdata/en/ec/127631.pdf) and another agreement on Jun 29, 2012 (http://www.consilium.europa.eu/uedocs/cms_data/docs/pressdata/en/ec/131388.pdf).
The dollar/euro rate is quoted as number of US dollars USD per one euro EUR, USD 1.2387/EUR in the first row, first column in the block for currencies in Table III-1 for Fri Aug 3, depreciating to USD 1.2394/EUR on Mon Aug 6, or by 0.1 percent. The dollar depreciated because more dollars, $1.2394, were required on Mon Aug 6 to buy one euro than $1.2387 on Aug 3. Table III-1 defines a country’s exchange rate as number of units of domestic currency per unit of foreign currency. USD/EUR would be the definition of the exchange rate of the US and the inverse [1/(USD/EUR)] is the definition in this convention of the rate of exchange of the euro zone, EUR/USD. A convention used throughout this blog is required to maintain consistency in characterizing movements of the exchange rate such as in Table III-1 as appreciation and depreciation. The first row for each of the currencies shows the exchange rate at 5 PM New York time, such as USD 1.2394/EUR on Aug 6; the second row provides the cumulative percentage appreciation or depreciation of the exchange rate from the rate on the last business day of the prior week, in this case Fri Aug 3, to the last business day of the current week, in this case Fri Aug 10, such as appreciation by 0.8 percent to USD 1.2290/EUR by Aug 10; and the third row provides the percentage change from the prior business day to the current business day. For example, the USD appreciated (denoted by positive sign) by 0.8 percent from the rate of USD 1.2387/EUR on Fri Aug 3 to the rate of USD 1.2290/EUR on Fri Aug 10 {[(1.2290/1.2387) – 1]100 = -0.8%} and appreciated (denoted by positive sign) by 0.1 percent from the rate of USD 1.2304 on Thu Aug 9 to USD 1.2290/EUR on Fri Aug 10 {[(1.2290/1.2304) -1]100 = -0.1%}. Other factors constant, appreciation of the dollar relative to the euro is caused by increasing risk aversion, with rising uncertainty on European sovereign risks increasing dollar-denominated assets with sales of risk financial investments. Funds move away from higher yielding risk financial assets to the safety of dollar investments. When risk aversion declines, funds have been moving away from safe assets in dollars to risk financial assets, depreciating the dollar.
http://www.ecb.int/press/pr/wfs/2012/html/fs120807.en.html
International financial risk continues to be dominated by whether the European Central Bank (ECB) can rescue sovereign debts of highly-indebted euro zone member countries. The first approach of the ECB was by the program of long-term refinancing operations (LRTO) that swelled its balance sheet risk assets consisting of loans to member banks and purchases of sovereign bonds of member countries from €1.0 trillion in the balance sheet of Dec 31, 2010 to €1.8 trillion in the latest consolidated financial statement on Aug 3, 2012 (http://www.ecb.int/press/pr/wfs/2012/html/fs120807.en.html). The capita of the ECB is €85.7 billion or 4.7 percent of risk assets mostly in banks and sovereigns with high probability of default. It is not possible to measure accurately by how much the ECB would have to increase its holdings of debt of sovereigns with high risk of default that would “resolve” or at least push forward the sovereign debt crisis of the euro zone. There is a sort of chicken game to the edge of the abysm similar in US debt and deficit negotiations (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/07/growth-recession-debt-financial-risk.html) between financial markets and the ECB that created the impasse during the past few weeks.
There were no changes of interest rate policy at the meeting of the European Central Bank (ECB) on Aug 2, 2012 (http://www.ecb.int/press/pr/date/2012/html/pr120802.en.html):
“2 August 2012 - Monetary policy decisions
At today’s meeting the Governing Council of the ECB decided that the interest rate on the main refinancing operations and the interest rates on the marginal lending facility and the deposit facility will remain unchanged at 0.75%, 1.50% and 0.00% respectively.
The President of the ECB will comment on the considerations underlying these decisions at a press conference starting at 2.30 p.m. CET today.”
At the press conference following the announcement, Mario Draghi, President of the ECB, answered the question of whether there would be a program of buying sovereign bonds of euro zone members by the EFSF/ESM (European Financial Stability Fund/European Stability Mechanism) jointly with a program by the ECB (http://www.ecb.int/press/pressconf/2012/html/is120802.en.html):
“Draghi: Let me reread the related passage of my Introductory Statement, because that basically answers your question. It says: “The adherence of governments to their commitments”, namely fiscal reforms, structural reforms and so on, “and the fulfilment by the EFSF/ESM of their role are necessary conditions” for some actions on the ECB’s side. So, the first thing is that governments have to go to the EFSF, because, as I said several times, the ECB cannot replace governments, or cannot replace the action that other institutions have to take on the fiscal side. “The Governing Council, within its mandate to maintain price stability over the medium term and in observance of its independence in determining monetary policy” – which means that to go to the EFSF is a necessary condition, but not a sufficient one, because the monetary policy is independent – “may undertake outright open market operations of a size adequate to reach its objective. In this context, the concerns of private investors about seniority will be addressed.” That gives you the answer to the question. I should add that “over the coming weeks, we will design the appropriate modalities for such policy measures”. So, many of the details will be worked out by the relevant committees within the ECB.”
Further doubts were raised on the “reservations” by the Bundesbank (Central Bank of Germany) concerning sovereign bond purchases by the ECB as revealed by Mario Draghi in an answer to a question at the press conference (http://www.ecb.int/press/pressconf/2012/html/is120802.en.html):
“Draghi: And fourth, the endorsement to do whatever it takes – again, to use the same words – whatever it takes to preserve the euro as a stable currency has been unanimous. But, it’s clear and it’s known that Mr Weidmann and the Bundesbank – although we are here in a personal capacity and we should never forget that – have their reservations about programmes that envisage buying bonds, so the idea is now we have given guidance, the Monetary Policy Committee, the Risk Management Committee and the Market Operations Committee will work on this guidance and then we’ll take a final decision where the votes will be counted. But so far that’s the situation; I think that’s a fair representation of our discussion today.”
Participants in financial markets began to believe in further purchases of sovereign bonds of euro zone members by the ECB.
Returning risk appetite on European assets was largely caused by expectations of a different turn in the bailout of highly indebted countries. The enthusiasm of markets was caused by the following remarks of Mario Draghi (2012Jul26), President of the European Central Bank (ECB), at the Global Investment Conference in London (http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2012/html/sp120726.en.html):
“But there is another message I want to tell you.
Within our mandate, the ECB is ready to do whatever it takes to preserve the euro. And believe me, it will be enough.”
These remarks encouraged market participants that the ECB would resume its program of purchasing sovereign bonds of highly indebted members of the euro zone. Valuations of risk financial assets climbed sharply while yields of sovereign bonds of highly indebted members of the euro zone fell substantially. Charles Forelle and Tom Fairless, writing on “Europe’s leaders move to show resolve,” on Jul 27, 2012, published in the WSJ (http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10000872396390443931404577552920809640442.html?mod=WSJ_hp_LEFTWhatsNewsCollection), analyze remarks by various European leaders on the intention to support Spain and Italy with strong measures that also contributed to the jump in valuations of risk financial assets. Brian Blackstone, writing on “ECB to discuss rescue plan with Bundesbank,” on Jul 27, 2012, published in the WSJ (http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10000872396390444840104577553234196518556.html), inform of a future meeting between the chief executives of the ECB and the Bundesbank to discuss the rescue program. Earlier in the week, Jon Hilsenrath, writing on “Fed moves closer to action,” on Jul 24, 2012, published in the WSJ (http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10000872396390444025204577547173267325402.html?mod=WSJ_hp_LEFTWhatsNewsCollection), analyzed economic and financial data and statements by officials that raise the possibility of further easing policies by the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC). Buiter (2011Oct31) analyzes that the European Financial Stability Fund (EFSF) would need a “bigger bazooka” to bail out euro members in difficulties that could possibly be provided by the ECB. Table III-7 in IIIE Appendix Euro Zone Survival Risk below provides the combined GDP in 2012 of the highly indebted euro zone members estimated in the latest World Economic Outlook of the IMF at $4167 billion or 33.1 percent of total euro zone GDP of $12,586 billion. Using the WEO of the IMF, Table III-8 in IIIE Appendix Euro Zone Survival Risk below provides debt of the highly indebted euro zone members at $3927.8 billion in 2012 that increases to $5809.9 billion when adding Germany’s debt, corresponding to 167.0 percent of Germany’s GDP. There are additional sources of debt in bailing out banks. The dimensions of the problem may require more firepower than a bazooka perhaps that of the largest conventional bomb of all times of 44,000 pounds experimentally detonated only once by the US in 1948 (http://www.airpower.au.af.mil/airchronicles/aureview/1967/mar-apr/coker.html).
The selloff in world financial market on Fri Jul 20 was largely caused by doubts on the success of Spain resolution of its banks. Ilan Brat, David Román and Charles Forelle, writing on “Spanish worries feed global fears,” on Jul 20, 2012, published in the Wall Street Journal (http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10000872396390444464304577538613391486808.html?mod=WSJ_hp_LEFTWhatsNewsCollection), analyze the selloff in financial markets by the warning by the Spanish government of prolonged weak economic conditions with decline of GDP of 0.5 percent in 2013 while the government of the province of Valencia will require €18 billion from the central government. Other provincial governments are in need of cash. Spain intends to lower its deficit from 8.9 percent of GDP in 2011 to 2.8 percent by 2014. The yield of the ten-year government bond of Spain rose sharply to 7.224 percent on Fri Jul 20 while the yield of the ten-year government bond of Italy increased to 6.158 percent (http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/public/page/marketsdata.html?mod=WSJ_PRO_hps_marketdata). The FTSE MIB index of Italian equities dropped 4.38 percent on Fri Jul 20 while the IBEX 35 index of Spanish equities fell 5.82 percent (http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/public/page/marketsdata.html?mod=WSJ_PRO_hps_marketdata).
Charles Forelle and David Enrich, writing on “Euro-zone banks cut back lending,” on Jul 13, 2012, published in the Wall Street Journal (http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052702303919504577524482252510066.html?mod=WSJ_hp_LEFTWhatsNewsCollection), analyze the new mechanics of interbank lending in the euro zone. In the older regime, the deficits of households, corporations and governments of highly-indebted members of the euro zone were financed by banks in their jurisdictions that received interbank loans from banks in the less indebted or financially-stronger countries. The increase of perceptions of default risk in counterparties in transactions among financial institutions constituted an important disruption of the international financial system during the financial crisis (see Pelaez and Pelaez, Regulation of Banks and Finance (2009b), 217-24, 60, Pelaez and Pelaez, Financial Regulation after the Global Recession (2009a), 155-7). Counterparty risk perceptions rose significantly in sale and repurchase agreements (SRP) in which the financing counterparty doubted the credit quality of the collateral and of the financed counterparty to repurchase the security. Another form of counterparty risk was the sharp increase in the LIBOR-OIS in which lending banks doubted the balance sheet of borrowing counterparty banks in uncollateralized interbank loans. The sovereign debt crisis in the euro zone caused sharp increases in the perception of counterparty risk evaluation by lending banks in financially-stronger jurisdictions of balance sheets and repayment capacity of borrowing banks in highly-indebted countries. Forelle and Enrich, “Euro zone banks cut back lending,” use central bank information showing that long-term financing by the European Central Bank (ECB) is filling the financing gap of banks in highly indebted countries with significant part of ECB lending simply returning as deposits in countries in stronger jurisdictions and also as deposits at the ECB. As a result, risk spreads of interest rates in highly indebted countries have increased relative to interest rates in stronger countries, which is a movement in opposite direction of what would be desired to resolve the euro zone financial crisis. Crisis resolution has moved to preventing banking instability that could accentuate the financial crisis and fiscal standing of highly-indebted countries.
Current financial risk is dominated by interest rate decisions of major central banks and the new program of rescue of banks and countries in the sovereign risk event in the euro zone. At the meeting of its Governing Council on Jul 5, 2010, the European Central Bank took the following policy measures (http://www.ecb.int/press/pr/date/2012/html/pr120705.en.html):
“5 July 2012 - Monetary policy decisions
At today’s meeting the Governing Council of the ECB took the following monetary policy decisions:
1. The interest rate on the main refinancing operations of the Eurosystem will be decreased by 25 basis points to 0.75%, starting from the operation to be settled on 11 July 2012.
2. The interest rate on the marginal lending facility will be decreased by 25 basis points to 1.50%, with effect from 11 July 2012.
3. The interest rate on the deposit facility will be decreased by 25 basis points to 0.00%, with effect from 11 July 2012.
The President of the ECB will comment on the considerations underlying these decisions at a press conference starting at 2.30 p.m. CET today.”
The President of the ECB Mario Draghi summarized the reasons for the policy measures as follows (http://www.ecb.int/press/pressconf/2012/html/is120705.en.html):
“Based on our regular economic and monetary analyses, we decided to cut the key ECB interest rates by 25 basis points. Inflationary pressure over the policy-relevant horizon has been dampened further as some of the previously identified downside risks to the euro area growth outlook have materialised. Consistent with this picture, the underlying pace of monetary expansion remains subdued. Inflation expectations for the euro area economy continue to be firmly anchored in line with our aim of maintaining inflation rates below, but close to, 2% over the medium term. At the same time, economic growth in the euro area continues to remain weak, with heightened uncertainty weighing on confidence and sentiment.”
The Bank of England decided on Jul 5, 2012 to increase its policy of quantitative easing (http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Pages/news/2012/066.aspx ):
“The Bank of England’s Monetary Policy Committee today voted to maintain the official Bank Rate paid on commercial bank reserves at 0.5%. The Committee also voted to increase the size of its asset purchase programme, financed by the issuance of central bank reserves, by £50 billion to a total of £375 billion.
UK output has barely grown for a year and a half and is estimated to have fallen in both of the past two quarters. The pace of expansion in most of the United Kingdom’s main export markets also appears to have slowed. Business indicators point to a continuation of that weakness in the near term, both at home and abroad. In spite of the progress made at the latest European Council, concerns remain about the indebtedness and competitiveness of several euro-area economies, and that is weighing on confidence here. The correspondingly weaker outlook for UK output growth means that the margin of economic slack is likely to be greater and more persistent.”
The People’s Bank of China (PBC) also cut interest rates simultaneously with the other major central banks (http://www.pbc.gov.cn/publish/english/955/2012/20120608171005950734495/20120608171005950734495_.html):
“The PBC has decided to cut RMB benchmark deposit and loan interest rates for financial institutions as of June 8, 2012. The one-year RMB benchmark deposit and loan interest rates will be lowered both by 0.25 percentage points. Adjustments are made correspondingly to benchmark interest rates on deposits and loans of other maturities and to deposit and loan interest rates on personal housing provident fund.”
Monetary authorities worldwide are assessing higher risks to the economy.
The key decisions of the summit of European Leaders with regards to resolving the sovereign debt issues are (http://www.european-council.europa.eu/home-page/highlights/summit-impact-on-the-eurozone?lang=en):
“Euro area summit statement
Eurozone heads of state or government decided:
- to establish a single banking supervisory mechanism run the by the ECB, and, once this mechanism has been created,
- to provide the European Stability Mechanism (ESM) with the possibility to inject funds into banks directly.
Spain's bank recapitalisation will begin under current rules, i.e. with assistance provided by the European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF) until the ESM becomes available. The funds will then be transferred to the ESM without gaining seniority status.
It was also agreed that EFSF/ESM funds can be used flexibly to buy bonds for member states that comply with common rules, recommendations and timetables.
The Eurogroup has been asked to implement these decisions by 9 July 2012.”
Valuations of risk financial assets increased sharply after the announcement of these decisions. The details will be crafted at a meeting on finance ministries of the European Union on Jul 9, 2012.
The definition of “banking panic” by Calomiris and Gorton (1991, 112) during the Great Depression in the US is:
“A banking panic occurs when bank debt holders at all or many banks in the banking system suddenly demand that banks convert their debt claims into cash (at par) to such an extent that the banks suspend convertibility of their debt into cash, or in the case of the United States, act collectively to avoid suspension of convertibility by issuing clearing house loan certificates.”
The financial panic during the credit crisis and global recession consisted of a run on the sale and repurchase agreements (SRP) of structured investment products (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/07/causes-of-2007-creditdollar-crisis.html). Cochrane and Zingales (2009) argue that the initial proposal for the Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP) instead of the failure of Lehman Bros caused the flight into the dollar and Treasury securities. Washington Mutual experienced a silent run in the form of internet withdrawals. The current silent run in the euro area is from banks with challenged balance sheets in highly indebted member countries to banks and government securities in countries with stronger fiscal affairs. The analysis of the IMF 2012 Article IV Consultation focuses on this key policy priority of reversing the silent run on challenged euro area banks.
Jonathan House, writing on “Spanish banks need as much as €62 billion in new capital,” on Jun 21, 2012, published in the Wall Street Journal (http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052702304765304577480062972372858.html?mod=WSJ_hp_LEFTWhatsNewsCollection), informs that two independent studies estimate the needs new capital of Spain’s banks at €62, billion, around $78.8 billion, which will be used by the government of Spain in the request for financial assistance from the European Union during the meeting with finance ministers.
The European Central Bank (ECB) announced changes in acceptable collateral for refinancing (http://www.ecb.int/press/pr/date/2012/html/pr120622.en.html):
“On 20 June 2012 the Governing Council of the European Central Bank (ECB) decided on additional measures to improve the access of the banking sector to Eurosystem operations in order to further support the provision of credit to households and non-financial corporations.
The Governing Council has reduced the rating threshold and amended the eligibility requirements for certain asset-backed securities (ABSs). It has thus broadened the scope of the measures to increase collateral availability which were introduced on 8 December 2011 and which remain applicable.
In addition to the ABSs that are already eligible for use as collateral in Eurosystem operations, the Eurosystem will consider the following ABSs as eligible:
1. Auto loan, leasing and consumer finance ABSs and ABSs backed by commercial mortgages (CMBSs) which have a second-best rating of at least “single A” in the Eurosystem’s harmonised credit scale, at issuance and at all times subsequently. These ABSs will be subject to a valuation haircut of 16%.
2. Residential mortgage-backed securities (RMBSs), securities backed by loans to small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs), auto loan, leasing and consumer finance ABSs and CMBSs which have a second-best rating of at least “triple B” in the Eurosystem’s harmonised credit scale, at issuance and at all times subsequently. RMBSs, securities backed by loans to SMEs, and auto loan, leasing and consumer finance ABSs would be subject to a valuation haircut of 26%, while CMBSs would be subject to a valuation haircut of 32%.
The risk control framework with higher haircuts applicable to the newly eligible ABS aims at ensuring risk equalisation across asset classes and maintaining the risk profile of the Eurosystem.
The newly eligible ABSs must also satisfy additional requirements which will be specified in the legal act to be adopted Thursday, 28 June 2012. The measures will take effect as soon as the relevant legal act enters into force.”
Yields on sovereign debt backed up again with the yield of the ten-year government bond of Spain rising sharply to 7.224 percent on Fri Jul 20 while the yield of the ten-year government bond of Italy increased to 6.158 percent but eased again on Fri Jul 27 on the expectations of massive government support with the yield of the ten-year government bond of Spain falling to 6.731 percent and the yield of the ten-year government bond of Italy dropping to 5.956 percent. The ten-year government bond of Spain was quoted at yield of 6.827 percent on Fri Aug 3 and the ten-year government bond of Italy was quoted at 6.064 percent (http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/public/page/marketsdata.html?mod=WSJ_PRO_hps_marketdata). The ten-year government bond of Spain was quoted at 6.868 percent on Aug 10 and the ten-year government bond of Italy at 5.894 percent. Risk aversion is captured by flight of investors from risk financial assets to the government securities of the US and Germany. Diminishing aversion is captured by increase of the yield of the two- and ten-year Treasury notes and the two- and ten-year government bonds of Germany. Table III-1A provides yields of US and German governments bonds and the rate of USD/EUR. Yields of US and German government bonds decline during shocks of risk aversion and the dollar strengthens in the form of fewer dollars required to buy one euro. The yield of the US ten-year Treasury note fell from 2.202 percent on Aug 26, 2011 to 1.459 percent on Jul 20, 2012, reminiscent of experience during the Treasury-Fed accord of the 1940s that placed a ceiling on long-term Treasury debt (Hetzel and Leach 2001), while the yield of the ten-year government bond of Germany fell from 2.16 percent to 1.17 percent. Under increasing risk appetite, the yield of the ten-year Treasury rose to 1.544 on Jul 27, 2012 and 1.569 percent on Aug 3, 2012, while the yield of the ten-year Government bond of Germany rose to 1.40 percent on Jul 27 and 1.42 percent on Aug 3. The US dollar strengthened significantly from USD 1.450/EUR on Aug 26, 2011, to USD 1.2158 on Jul 20, 2012, or by 16.2 percent, but depreciated to USD 1.2320/EUR on Jul 27, 2012 and 1.2387 on Aug 3, 2012 in expectation of massive support of highly indebted euro zone members. Doubts returned at the end of the week of Aug 10, 2012 with appreciation to USD 1.2290/EUR and decline of the yields of the two-year government bond of Germany to -0.07 percent and of the ten-year to 1.38 percent. Under zero interest rates for the monetary policy rate of the US, or fed funds rate, carry trades ensure devaluation of the dollar if there is no risk aversion but the dollar appreciates in flight to safe haven during episodes of risk aversion. Unconventional monetary policy induces significant global financial instability, excessive risks and low liquidity. The ten-year Treasury yield is still at a level below consumer price inflation of 1.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Jun (see subsection II United States Inflation http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/07/world-inflation-waves-financial.html) and the expectation of higher inflation if risk aversion diminishes. Treasury securities continue to be safe haven for investors fearing risk but with concentration in shorter maturities such as the two-year Treasury. The lower part of Table III-1A provides the same flight to government securities of the US and Germany and the USD during the financial crisis and global recession and the beginning of the European debt crisis in the spring of 2010 with the USD trading at USD 1.192/EUR on Jun 7, 2010.
Table III-1A, Two- and Ten-Year Yields of Government Bonds of the US and Germany and US Dollar/EUR Exchange rate
US 2Y | US 10Y | DE 2Y | DE 10Y | USD/ EUR | |
8/10/12 | 0.267 | 1.658 | -0.07 | 1.38 | 1.2290 |
8/3/12 | 0.242 | 1.569 | -0.02 | 1.42 | 1.2387 |
7/27/12 | 0.244 | 1.544 | -0.03 | 1.40 | 1.2320 |
7/20/12 | 0.207 | 1.459 | -0.07 | 1.17 | 1.2158 |
7/13/12 | 0.24 | 1.49 | -0.04 | 1.26 | 1.2248 |
7/6/12 | 0.272 | 1.548 | -0.01 | 1.33 | 1.2288 |
6/29/12 | 0.305 | 1.648 | 0.12 | 1.58 | 1.2661 |
6/22/12 | 0.309 | 1.676 | 0.14 | 1.58 | 1.2570 |
6/15/12 | 0.272 | 1.584 | 0.07 | 1.44 | 1.2640 |
6/8/12 | 0.268 | 1.635 | 0.04 | 1.33 | 1.2517 |
6/1/12 | 0.248 | 1.454 | 0.01 | 1.17 | 1.2435 |
5/25/12 | 0.291 | 1.738 | 0.05 | 1.37 | 1.2518 |
5/18/12 | 0.292 | 1.714 | 0.05 | 1.43 | 1.2780 |
5/11/12 | 0.248 | 1.845 | 0.09 | 1.52 | 1.2917 |
5/4/12 | 0.256 | 1.876 | 0.08 | 1.58 | 1.3084 |
4/6/12 | 0.31 | 2.058 | 0.14 | 1.74 | 1.3096 |
3/30/12 | 0.335 | 2.214 | 0.21 | 1.79 | 1.3340 |
3/2/12 | 0.29 | 1.977 | 0.16 | 1.80 | 1.3190 |
2/24/12 | 0.307 | 1.977 | 0.24 | 1.88 | 1.3449 |
1/6/12 | 0.256 | 1.957 | 0.17 | 1.85 | 1.2720 |
12/30/11 | 0.239 | 1.871 | 0.14 | 1.83 | 1.2944 |
8/26/11 | 0.20 | 2.202 | 0.65 | 2.16 | 1.450 |
8/19/11 | 0.192 | 2.066 | 0.65 | 2.11 | 1.4390 |
6/7/10 | 0.74 | 3.17 | 0.49 | 2.56 | 1.192 |
3/5/09 | 0.89 | 2.83 | 1.19 | 3.01 | 1.254 |
12/17/08 | 0.73 | 2.20 | 1.94 | 3.00 | 1.442 |
10/27/08 | 1.57 | 3.79 | 2.61 | 3.76 | 1.246 |
7/14/08 | 2.47 | 3.88 | 4.38 | 4.40 | 1.5914 |
6/26/03 | 1.41 | 3.55 | NA | 3.62 | 1.1423 |
Note: DE: Germany
Source:
http://www.bloomberg.com/markets/
http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/page/marketsdata.html?mod=WSJ_hps_marketdata
http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/data.htm
http://www.ecb.int/stats/money/long/html/index.en.html
Chart III-1A of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System provides the ten-year and two-year Treasury constant maturity yields. The combination of zero fed funds rate and quantitative easing caused sharp decline of the yields from 2008 and 2009. Yield declines have also occurred during periods of financial risk aversion, including the current one of stress of financial markets in Europe.
Chart III-1A, US, Ten-Year and Two-Year Treasury Constant Maturity Yields 2001-2012
Note: US Recessions in shaded areas
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/update/
Equity indexes in Table III-1 were mostly higher in the week ending on Aug 10, 2012, because of enthusiasm on resolution of fiscal and banking issues in Spain and Italy but weaker on Fri Aug 10 when doubts resurfaced partly because of growth of only 1.0 percent of China’s exports in the 12 months ending in Jul 2012 (see Section VC). DJIA increased 0.3 percent on Aug 10 and 0.9 percent in the week. Germany’s Dax decreased 0.3 percent on Fri Aug 10, gaining 1.1 percent in the week. Dow Global was flat on Aug 10 and increased 2.0 percent in the week. Japan’s Nikkei Average fell 1.0 percent on Fri Aug 10 and increased 3.9 percent in the week. Dow Asia Pacific TSM fell 0.3 percent on Aug 10 but increased 2.9 percent in the week while Shanghai Composite increased 1.7 percent in the week but fell 0.2 percent on Fri Aug 10.
Commodities were higher in the week of Aug 10, 2012 with weakness on Fri Aug 10. The DJ UBS Commodities Index fell 1.1 percent on Fri Aug 10 but increased 0.2 percent in the week, as shown in Table III-1. WTI decreased 0.6 percent on Fri Aug 10 but increased 1.6 percent in the week while Brent fell 0.2 percent on Fri Aug 10 but gained 3.7 percent in the week. Gold increased 0.8 percent in the week of Aug 10.
Risk aversion during the week of Mar 2, 2012, was dominated by the long-term refinancing operations (LTRO) of the European Central Bank. LTROs and related principles are analyzed in subsection IIID Appendix on European Central Bank Large Scale Lender of Last Resort. First, as analyzed by David Enrich, writing on “ECB allots €529.5 billion in long-term refinancing operations,” published on Feb 29, 2012 by the Wall Street Journal (http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052970203986604577252803223310964.html?mod=WSJ_hp_LEFTWhatsNewsCollection), the ECB provided a second round of three-year loans at 1.0 percent to about 800 banks. The earlier round provided €489 billion to more than 500 banks. Second, the ECB sets the fixed-rate for main refinancing operations at 1.00 percent and the overnight deposit facility at 0.25 percent (http://www.ecb.int/home/html/index.en.html) for negative spread of 75 basis points. That is, if a bank borrows at 1.0 percent for three years through the LTRO and deposits overnight at the ECB, it incurs negative spread of 75 basis points. An alternative allocation could be to lend for a positive spread to other banks. Richard Milne, writing on “Banks deposit record cash with ECB,” on Mar 2, 2012, published in the Financial Times (http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/9798fd36-644a-11e1-b30e-00144feabdc0.html#axzz1nxeicB6H), provides important information and analysis that banks deposited a record €776.9 billion at the ECB on Fri Mar 2 at interest receipt of 0.25 percent, just two days after receiving €529.5 billion of LTRO loans at interest cost of 1.0 percent. The main issue here is whether there is ongoing perceptions of high risks in counterparties in financial transactions that froze credit markets in 2008 (see Pelaez and Pelaez, Regulation of Banks and Finance (2009a), 57-60, 217-27, Financial Regulation after the Global Recession (2009b), 155-67). Richard Milne and Mary Watkins, writing on “European finance: the leaning tower of perils,” on Mar 27, 2012, published in the Financial Times (http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/82205f6e-7735-11e1-baf3-00144feab49a.html#axzz1qOqWaqF2), raise concerns that the large volume of LTROs can create future problems for banks and the euro area. An important issue is if the cheap loans at 1 percent for three-year terms finance the carry trade into securities of the governments of banks. Balance sheets of banks may be stressed during future sovereign-credit events. Sam Jones, writing on “ECB liquidity fuels high stakes hedging,” on Apr 4, 2012, published in the Financial Times (http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/cb74d63a-7e75-11e1-b009-00144feab49a.html#axzz1qyDYxLjS), analyzes unusually high spreads in government bond markets in Europe that could have been caused by LTROs. There has been active relative value arbitrage of these spreads similar to the strategies of Long-Term Capital Management (LTCM) of capturing high spreads in mortgage-backed securities jointly with hedges in Treasury securities (on LTCM see Pelaez and Pelaez, International Financial Architecture (2005), 108-12, 87-9, The Global Recession Risk (2007) 12-3, 102, 176, Globalization and the State, Vol. I (2008a), 59-64).
Table III-1B provides an update of the consolidated financial statement of the Eurosystem. The balance sheet has swollen with the LTROs. Line 5 “Lending to Euro Area Credit Institutions Related to Monetary Policy” increased from €546,747 million on Dec 31, 2010, to €870,130 million on Dec 28, 2011 and €1,209,403 million on Aug 3, 2012. The sum of line 5 and line 7 (“Securities of Euro Area Residents Denominated in Euro”) has increased to €1,811,911 million in the statement of Aug 3.
Table III-1B, Consolidated Financial Statement of the Eurosystem, Million EUR
Dec 31, 2010 | Dec 28, 2011 | Aug 3, 2012 | |
1 Gold and other Receivables | 367,402 | 419,822 | 433,778 |
2 Claims on Non Euro Area Residents Denominated in Foreign Currency | 223,995 | 236,826 | 260,768 |
3 Claims on Euro Area Residents Denominated in Foreign Currency | 26,941 | 95,355 | 56,405 |
4 Claims on Non-Euro Area Residents Denominated in Euro | 22,592 | 25,982 | 15,779 |
5 Lending to Euro Area Credit Institutions Related to Monetary Policy Operations Denominated in Euro | 546,747 | 879,130 | 1,209,403 |
6 Other Claims on Euro Area Credit Institutions Denominated in Euro | 45,654 | 94,989 | 215,403 |
7 Securities of Euro Area Residents Denominated in Euro | 457,427 | 610,629 | 602,508 |
8 General Government Debt Denominated in Euro | 34,954 | 33,928 | 30,041 |
9 Other Assets | 278,719 | 336,574 | 261,130 |
TOTAL ASSETS | 2,004, 432 | 2,733,235 | 3,085,214 |
Memo Items | |||
Sum of 5 and 7 | 1,004,174 | 1,489,759 | 1,811,911 |
Capital and Reserves | 78,143 | 85,748 | 85,749 |
Source: European Central Bank
http://www.ecb.int/press/pr/wfs/2011/html/fs110105.en.html
http://www.ecb.int/press/pr/wfs/2011/html/fs111228.en.html
http://www.ecb.int/press/pr/wfs/2012/html/fs120807.en.html
© Carlos M. Pelaez, 2010, 2011, 2012
No comments:
Post a Comment