Sunday, June 17, 2012

Destruction of Three Trillion Dollars of US Household Wealth, World Inflation Waves, United States Fiscal and Balance of Payments Imbalances, Financial Turbulence and Economic Slowdown: Part II

 

Destruction of Three Trillion Dollars of US Household Wealth, World Inflation Waves, United States Fiscal and Balance of Payments Imbalances, Financial Turbulence and Economic Slowdown

Carlos M. Pelaez

© Carlos M. Pelaez, 2010, 2011, 2012

Executive Summary

I World Inflation Waves

IA World Inflation Waves

IB United States Inflation

IB1 Long-term US Inflation

IB2 Current US Inflation

IC Import Export Prices

II Destruction of Three Trillion Dollars of Household Wealth

III World Financial Turbulence

IIIA Financial Risks

IIIB Appendix on Safe Haven Currencies

IIIC Appendix on Fiscal Compact

IIID Appendix on European Central Bank Large Scale Lender of Last Resort

IIIE Appendix Euro Zone Survival Risk

IIIF Appendix on Sovereign Bond Valuation

IIIG Appendix on Deficit Financing of Growth and the Debt Crisis

IIIGA Monetary Policy with Deficit Financing of Economic Growth

IIIGB Adjustment during the Debt Crisis of the 1980s

IV Global Inflation

V World Economic Slowdown

VA United States

VB Japan

VC China

VD Euro Area

VE Germany

VF France

VG Italy

VH United Kingdom

VI Valuation of Risk Financial Assets

VII Economic Indicators

VIII Interest Rates

IX Conclusion

References

Appendix I The Great Inflation

 

V World Economic Slowdown. Table V-1 is constructed with the database of the IMF (http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2012/01/weodata/index.aspx) to show GDP in dollars in 2010 and the growth rate of real GDP of the world and selected regional countries from 2011 to 2014. The data illustrate the concept often repeated of “two-speed recovery” of the world economy from the recession of 2007 to 2009. The IMF has lowered its forecast of the world economy to 3.5 percent in 2012 but accelerating to 4.1 percent in 2013, 4.4 percent in 2014 and 4.5 percent in 2015. Slow-speed recovery occurs in the “major advanced economies” of the G7 that account for $33,670 billion of world output of $69,660 billion, or 48.3 percent, but are projected to grow at much lower rates than world output, 2.1 percent on average from 2012 to 2015 in contrast with 4.1 percent for the world as a whole. While the world would grow 17.6 percent in the four years from 2012 to 2015, the G7 as a whole would grow 8.5 percent. The difference in dollars of 2011 is rather high: growing by 17.6 percent would add $12.3 trillion of output to the world economy, or roughly two times the output of the economy of Japan of $5,869 but growing by 8.5 percent would add $5.9 trillion of output to the world, or about the output of Japan in 2011. The “two speed” concept is in reference to the growth of the 150 countries labeled as emerging and developing economies (EMDE) with joint output in 2011 of $25,237 billion, or 36.2 percent of world output. The EMDEs would grow cumulatively 26.5 percent or at the average yearly rate of 6.1 percent, contributing $6.7 trillion from 2012 to 2015 or the equivalent of somewhat less than the GDP of $7,298 billion of China in 2011. The final four countries in Table 1 often referred as BRIC (Brazil, Russia, India, China), are large, rapidly growing emerging economies. Their combined output adds to $13,317 billion, or 19.1 percent of world output, which is equivalent to 39.6 percent of the combined output of the major advanced economies of the G7.

Table V-1, IMF World Economic Outlook Database Projections of Real GDP Growth

 

GDP USD 2011

Real GDP ∆%
2012

Real GDP ∆%
2013

Real GDP ∆%
2014

Real GDP ∆%
2015

World

69,660

3.5

4.1

4.4

4.5

G7

33,670

1.5

1.9

2.3

2.5

Canada

1,737

2.1

2.2

2.4

2.4

France

2,776

0.5

1.1

1.9

1.9

DE

3,577

0.6

1.5

1.3

1.3

Italy

2,199

-1.9

-0.3

0.5

1.0

Japan

5,869

2.0

1.7

1.5

1.3

UK

2,418

0.8

2.0

2.5

2.6

US

15,094

2.1

2.4

2.9

3.3

Euro Area

13,115

-0.3

0.9

1.4

1.6

DE

3,577

0.6

1.5

1.3

1.3

France

2,776

0.5

1.1

1.9

1.9

Italy

2,199

-1.9

-0.3

0.5

1.0

POT

239

-3.3

0.3

2.1

1.9

Ireland

218

0.5

2.1

2.5

2.8

Greece

303

-4.7

0.0

2.5

3.1

Spain

1,494

-1.8

0.1

1.6

1.6

EMDE

25,237

5.7

6.0

6.2

6.3

Brazil

2,493

3.0

4.2

4.0

4.1

Russia

1,850

4.0

3.9

3.9

3.9

India

1,676

6.9

7.3

7.5

7.7

China

7,298

8.2

8.8

8.7

8.7

Notes; DE: Germany; EMDE: Emerging and Developing Economies (150 countries); POT: Portugal

Source: IMF World Economic Outlook databank

http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2012/01/weodata/index.aspx

Table V-2 is constructed with the WEO database to provide rates of unemployment from 2011 to 2015 for major countries and regions. In fact, unemployment rates for 2011 in Table ESV-2 are high for all countries: unusually high for countries with high rates most of the time and unusually high for countries with low rates most of the time. The rates of unemployment are particularly high for the countries with sovereign debt difficulties in Europe: 12.7 percent for Portugal (POT), 14.4 percent for Ireland, 17.3 percent for Greece, 21.6 percent for Spain and 8.4 percent for Italy, which is lower but still high. The G7 rate of unemployment is 7.7 percent. Unemployment rates are not likely to decrease substantially if slow growth persists in advanced economies.

Table V-2, IMF World Economic Outlook Database Projections of Unemployment Rate as Percent of Labor Force

 

% Labor Force 2011

% Labor Force 2012

% Labor Force 2013

% Labor Force 2014

% Labor Force 2015

World

NA

NA

NA

NA

NA

G7

7.7

7.4

7.3

7.0

6.7

Canada

7.5

7.4

7.3

7.1

6.9

France

9.7

9.9

10.1

9.8

9.4

DE

6.0

5.6

5.5

5.3

5.3

Italy

8.4

9.5

9.7

9.8

9.5

Japan

4.5

4.5

4.4

4.3

4.2

UK

8.0

8.3

8.2

7.8

7.4

US

8.9

8.2

7.9

7.5

6.9

Euro Area

10.1

10.9

10.8

10.5

10.1

DE

6.0

5.6

5.5

5.3

5.3

France

9.7

9.9

10.1

9.8

9.4

Italy

8.4

9.5

9.7

9.8

9.5

POT

12.7

14.3

13.9

13.2

12.4

Ireland

14.4

14.5

13.8

12.9

12.0

Greece

17.3

19.4

19.4

18.2

16.8

Spain

21.6

24.2

23.9

22.8

21.9

EMDE

NA

NA

NA

NA

NA

Brazil

6.0

6.0

6.5

7.0

7.0

Russia

7.5

6.5

6.0

6.0

6.0

India

NA

NA

NA

NA

NA

China

4.1

4.0

4.0

4.0

4.0

Notes: DE: Germany; EMDE: Emerging and Developing Economies (150 countries)

Source: IMF World Economic Outlook databank http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2012/01/weodata/weoselgr.aspx

Table V-3 provides the latest available estimates of GDP for the regions and countries followed in this blog. Growth is weak throughout most of the world. Japan’s GDP increased 1.2 percent in IQ2012 and 2.8 percent relative to a year earlier but part of the jump could be the low level a year earlier because of the Tōhoku or Great East Earthquake and Tsunami of Mar 11, 2011. Japan is experiencing difficulties with the overvalued yen because of worldwide capital flight originating in zero interest rates with risk aversion in an environment of softer growth of world trade. China grew at 1.8 percent in IQ2012, which annualizes to 7.4 percent. Xinhuanet informs that Premier Wen Jiabao considers the need for macroeconomic stimulus, arguing that “we should continue to implement proactive fiscal policy and a prudent monetary policy, while giving more priority to maintaining growth” (http://news.xinhuanet.com/english/china/2012-05/20/c_131599662.htm). Premier Wen elaborates that “the country should properly handle the relationship between maintaining growth, adjusting economic structures and managing inflationary expectations” (http://news.xinhuanet.com/english/china/2012-05/20/c_131599662.htm). GDP was flat in the euro area in IQ2012 and fell 0.1 percent relative to a year earlier. Germany’s GDP increased 0.5 percent in IQ2012 and 1.7 percent relative to a year earlier. US GDP increased 0.5 percent in IQ2012 and 2.0 percent relative to a year earlier (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/mediocre-recovery-without-jobs.html) but with substantial underemployment and underemployment (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/mediocre-recovery-without-jobs.html) and weak hiring (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/05/recovery-without-hiring-ten-million.html).

Table V-3, Percentage Changes of GDP Quarter on Prior Quarter and on Same Quarter Year Earlier, ∆%

 

IQ2012/IVQ2011

IQ2012/IQ2011

United States

0.5

2.0

Japan

1.2

2.8

China

1.8

8.1

Euro Area

0.0

-0.1

Germany

0.5

1.7

France

0.0

0.0

Italy

-0.8

-1.4

United Kingdom

-0.3

-0.1

Source: Country Statistical Agencies

http://www.bea.gov/national/index.htm#gdp http://www.esri.cao.go.jp/en/sna/sokuhou/sokuhou_top.html http://www.stats.gov.cn/enGliSH/ http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page/portal/eurostat/home/ https://www.destatis.de/EN/FactsFigures/Indicators/ShortTermIndicators/ShortTermIndicators.html http://www.insee.fr/en/ http://www.istat.it/en/ http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/rel/naa2/second-estimate-of-gdp/q1-2012/index.html

The JP Morgan Global All-Industry Output Index of the JP Morgan Manufacturing and Services PMI, produced by JP Morgan and Markit in association with ISM and IFPSM, with high association with world GDP, was virtually unchanged at 52.1 in May relative to 52.3 in Apr, which is the lowest reading which is the lowest reading since Nov 2011 (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9664). This index has remained above the contraction territory of 50.0 during 34 months. Slower manufacturing growth was compensated by sharper activity in services. David Hensley, Director of Global Economic Coordination at JP Morgan, finds that the PMI data suggest world GDP growth easing into the middle of 2012, with manufacturing output growing at the weakest pace in five months while services activity maintaining strength (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9664). The JP Morgan Global Manufacturing PMI, produced by JP Morgan and Markit in association with ISM and IFPSM, fell marginally from 51.4 in Apr to 50.6 in Mar, for the weakest level in five months; manufacturing has been growing during six consecutive months but at the weakest pace in May even as cost inflation moderated significantly because of decline of commodity prices (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9650). David Hensley, Director of Global Economics Coordination at JPMorgan, finds weak growth in orders together decline in international trade as factors of slowdown in manufacturing growth (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9650).

The Brazil Composite Output Index of the HSBC Brazil Services PMI with Composite PMI data, compiled by Markit, fell from 52.7 in Apr to 49.6 in May, suggesting marginal decline in output of the private sector in the first reading below 50 since Sep 2011 (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9647). Andre Loes, Chief Economist, Brazil, at HSBC, finds that the HSBC Services PMI Business Activity Index dropped from 54.4 in Apr to 49.7 in May but there is need for more observations to determine if weakness in manufacturing is spreading to services (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9647). The HSBC Brazil Purchasing Managers’ IndexTM (PMI) was unchanged at 49.3 in both Apr and May, indicating modest business conditions in Brazilian manufacturing (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9631). Andre Loes, Chief Economist, Brazil at HSBC, finds that the manufacturing index fell below 50 during two consecutive months after remaining above 50.0 during IQ2012 under cost pressures and competition by imports with hopes that depreciation of the exchange rate may bring about some improvement (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9631).

VA United States. The purchasing managers’ index (PMI) of the Institute for Supply Management (ISM) Report on Business® fell 1.3 percentage points from 54.8 in Apr to 53.5 in May, indicating slower growth in 34 months of expansion (http://www.ism.ws/ISMReport/MfgROB.cfm). The index of new orders increased 1.9 percentage points from 58.2 in Apr to 60.1 in May, indicating growth in 37 months at a faster rate. The Non-Manufacturing ISM Report on Business® PMI increased 0.2 percentage points from 53.5 in Apr to 53.7 in May while the index of new orders increased 2.0 percentage points from 53.5 in Apr to 55.5 in May (http://www.ism.ws/ISMReport/NonMfgROB.cfm). Table USA provides the data table for the US.

Table USA, US Economic Indicators

Consumer Price Index

May 12 months NSA ∆%: 1.7; ex food and energy ∆%: 2.3 May month ∆%: -0.3; ex food and energy ∆%: 0.2
Blog 6/17/12

Producer Price Index

May 12-month NSA ∆%: 0.7; ex food and energy ∆% 2.7
May month SA ∆% = -1.0; ex food and energy ∆%: 0.2
Blog 6/17/12

PCE Inflation

Apr 12-month NSA ∆%: headline 1.8; ex food and energy ∆% 1.9
Blog 6/3/12

Employment Situation

Household Survey: May Unemployment Rate SA 8.2%
Blog calculation People in Job Stress May: 28.4 million NSA
Establishment Survey:
May Nonfarm Jobs +69,000; Private +82,000 jobs created 
Apr 12-month Average Hourly Earnings Inflation Adjusted ∆%: 0.5%
Blog 6/3/12

Nonfarm Hiring

Nonfarm Hiring fell from 69.4 million in 2004 to 50.1 million in 2011 or by 19.3 million
Private-Sector Hiring Mar 2012 3.900 million lower by 0.873 million than 4.773 million in Mar 2006
Blog 5/13/12

GDP Growth

BEA Revised National Income Accounts back to 2003
IQ2011 SAAR ∆%: 0.4
IIQ2011 SAAR ∆%: 1.3

IIIQ2011 SAAR ∆%: 1.8

IVQ2011 ∆%: 3.0

IQ2012 SAAR ∆%: 1.9

IQ2012/IQ2011 ∆%: 2.0
Blog 6/3/12

Personal Income and Consumption

Apr month ∆% SA Real Disposable Personal Income (RDPI) 0.2 Mar month SA ∆% 0.2
Real Personal Consumption Expenditures (RPCE): 0.3
12-month Apr NSA ∆%:
RDPI: 0.6; RPCE ∆%: 2.1
Blog 6/3/2012

Quarterly Services Report

IQ12/IQ11 SA ∆%:
Information 3.8
Professional 10.3
Administrative 4.9
Hospitals 5.2
Blog 6/10/12

Employment Cost Index

IQ2012 SA ∆%: 0.4
Mar 12 months ∆%: 1.9
Blog 4/29/12

Industrial Production

May month SA ∆%: -0.1
May 12 months SA ∆%: 4.7

Manufacturing May SA ∆% -0.4 May 12 months SA ∆% 5.2, NSA 5.4
Capacity Utilization: 79.0
Blog 6/17/12

Productivity and Costs

Nonfarm Business Productivity IQ2012∆% SAAE -0.9; IQ2012/IQ2011 ∆% 0.4; Unit Labor Costs SAAE IQ2012 ∆% 1.3; IQ2012/IQ2011 ∆%: 0.9

Blog 6/10/2012

New York Fed Manufacturing Index

General Business Conditions From May 17.09 to Jun 2.29
New Orders: From May 8.32 to Jun 2.18
Blog 6/17/12

Philadelphia Fed Business Outlook Index

General Index from Apr 8.5 to May minus 5.8
New Orders from Apr 2.7 to May minus 1.2
Blog 5/20/12

Manufacturing Shipments and Orders

Apr New Orders SA ∆%: -0.6; ex transport ∆%: -1.1
Jan-Apr New Orders NSA ∆%: 6.6; ex transport ∆% 6.2
Blog 6/10/12

Durable Goods

Apr New Orders SA ∆%: 0.2; ex transport ∆%: minus 0.6
Jan-Apr 12/Jan-Apr 11 NSA New Orders ∆%: 8.6; ex transport ∆% : 8.3
Blog 5/27/12

Sales of New Motor Vehicles

May 2012 5,986,605; May 2011 5,279,318. May SAAR 13.78 million, Apr SAAR 14.42 million, May 2011 SAAR 11.73 million

Blog 6/3/12

Sales of Merchant Wholesalers

Jan-Apr 2012/Jan-Apr 2011 NSA ∆%: Total 8.4; Durable Goods: 10.3; Nondurable
Goods 7.0
Blog 6/10/12

Sales and Inventories of Manufacturers, Retailers and Merchant Wholesalers

Apr 12/Apr 11 NSA ∆%: Sales Total Business 4.9; Manufacturers 4.3
Retailers 3.3; Merchant Wholesalers 6.8
Blog 6/17/12

Sales for Retail and Food Services

Jan-May 2012/Jan-May 2011 ∆%: Retail and Food Services 7.0; Retail ∆% 6.8
Blog 6/17/12

Value of Construction Put in Place

Apr SAAR month SA ∆%: 0.3 Apr 12-month NSA: 6,8
Blog 6/3/12

Case-Shiller Home Prices

Mar 2012/Mar 2011 ∆% NSA: 10 Cities minus 2.8; 20 Cities: minus 2.6
∆% Mar SA: 10 Cities 0.1 ; 20 Cities: 0.1
Blog 6/3/12

FHFA House Price Index Purchases Only

Mar SA ∆% 1.8;
12 month ∆%: 2.7
Blog 5/27/12

New House Sales

Apr 2012 month SAAR ∆%:
+3.3
Jan-Apr 2012/Jan-Apr 2011 NSA ∆%: 15.8
Blog 5/27/12

Housing Starts and Permits

Apr Starts month SA ∆%:

2.6; Permits ∆%: minus 7.0
Jan-Apr 2012/Jan-Apr 2011 NSA ∆% Starts 25.2; Permits  ∆% 29.6
Blog 5/20/12

Trade Balance

Balance Apr SA -$50,062 million versus Mar -$52617 million
Exports Mar SA ∆%: 0.8 Imports Mar SA ∆%: -1.7
Goods Exports Jan-Apr 2012/2011 NSA ∆%: 7.0
Goods Imports Jan-Apr 2011/2011 NSA ∆%: 7.9
Blog 6/10/12

Export and Import Prices

May 12-month NSA ∆%: Imports -0.3; Exports -0.1
Blog 6/17/12

Consumer Credit

Apr ∆% annual rate: 3.1
Blog 6/10/12

Net Foreign Purchases of Long-term Treasury Securities

Apr Net Foreign Purchases of Long-term Treasury Securities: $25.6 billion
Major Holders of Treasury Securities: China $1145 billion; Japan $1066 billion; Total Foreign US Treasury Holdings Apr $5156 billion
Blog 6/17/12

Treasury Budget

Fiscal Year Oct-May 2012/2011 ∆%: Receipts 5.4; Outlays -0.1; Individual Income Taxes 4.2
Deficit Fiscal Year 2011 $1,300 billion

Deficit Fiscal Year 2012 Oct-May $844,494 million

CBO Forecast 2012FY Deficit $1.171 trillion

Blog 6/17/2012

Flow of Funds

IQ2012 ∆ since 2007

Assets -$4113B

Real estate -$4916B

Financial $367.3MM

Net Worth -$3300B

Blog 6/17/12

Current Account Balance of Payments

IQ2012 -$137B

%GDP 3.6

Blog 06/17/12

Links to blog comments in Table USA:

6/10/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/rules-versus-discretionary-authorities_10.html

6/3/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/mediocre-recovery-without-jobs_04.html

5/27/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/05/world-financial-turbulence-global_27.html

5/20/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/05/world-inflation-waves-monetary-policy_20.html

5/13/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/05/recovery-without-hiring-ten-million_13.html

4/29/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/04/mediocre-growth-with-high-unemployment_29.html

Industrial production fell 0.1 percent in May after increasing 1.0 percent in Apr and falling 0.5 percent in Mar, as shown in Table VA-1, with all data seasonally adjusted. In the six months ending in May, industrial production accumulated growth of 2.3 percent at the annual equivalent rate of 4.7 percent, which coincidentally is equal to 4.7 percent in 12 months. Business equipment increased 0.3 percent in May, growing 11.3 percent in the 12 months ending in May and at the annual equivalent rate of 13.8 percent in the six months ending in May. Capacity utilization of total industry is analyzed by the Fed in its report (http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/g17/Current/): “Capacity utilization for total industry declined 0.2 percentage points to 79.0 percent, a rate 1.3 percentage points below its long-run (1972-2011) average.” Manufacturing contributed $1,318.2 billion to US national income of $13,267.5 billion without capital consumption adjustment in IVQ2011, or 10.0 percent of the total, according to data of the Bureau of Economic Analysis (http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm see Table II-13 at http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/mediocre-recovery-without-jobs.html).

Table VA-1, US, Industrial Production and Capacity Utilization, SA, ∆%, % 

2011-2012

May

Apr

Mar

Feb

Jan

Dec

May 

12/

May 

11

Total

-0.1

1.0

-0.5

0.4

0.6

0.9

4.7

Market
Groups

             

Final Products

-0.2

1.3

-0.7

0.7

0.8

0.5

4.5

Consumer Goods

-0.2

1.4

-1.0

0.4

0.4

0.4

2.3

Business Equipment

0.3

1.5

0.3

1.4

2.0

1.0

11.3

Non
Industrial Supplies

-0.4

1.3

-0.8

1.3

0.3

1.3

3.6

Construction

-1.2

0.7

-1.0

2.1

0.2

2.4

5.1

Materials

0.1

0.6

-0.4

0.0

0.6

1.1

5.1

Industry Groups

             

Manufacturing

-0.4

0.7

-0.6

0.8

1.0

1.5

5.2

Mining

0.9

-0.6

0.0

-2.0

0.2

0.7

4.6

Utilities

0.8

5.3

-0.6

1.1

-1.9

-3.6

1.0

Capacity

79.0

79.2

78.5

79.0

78.7

78.3

1.1

Sources: http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/g17/current/

Manufacturing fell 0.4 percent in May seasonally adjusted, increasing 5.4 percent not seasonally adjusted in 12 months, and grew 3.3 percent in the six months ending in May or at the annual equivalent rate of 6.1 percent. A longer perspective of manufacturing in the US is provided by Table VA-2. There has been evident deceleration of manufacturing growth in the US from 2010 and the first three months of 2011 as shown by 12 months rates of growth but growth rates may be increasing again closer to 6 percent. The rates of decline of manufacturing in 2009 are quite high with a drop of 18.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr 2009. Manufacturing recovered from this decline and led the recovery from the recession. Rates of growth appear to be returning to the levels at 3 percent or higher in the annual rates before the recession.

Table VA-2, US, Monthly and 12-Month Rates of Growth of Manufacturing ∆%

 

Month SA ∆%

12-Month NSA ∆%

May 2012

-0.4

5.4

Apr

0.7

5.7

Mar

-0.6

4.3

Feb

0.8

5.9

Jan

1.0

4.9

Dec 2011

1.5

4.4

Nov

0.0

4.0

Oct

0.5

4.3

Sep

0.4

4.0

Aug

0.3

3.4

Jul

0.8

3.2

Jun

0.0

3.1

May

0.2

3.0

Apr

-0.6

4.1

Mar

0.6

6.0

Feb

0.2

6.3

Jan

0.4

6.3

Dec 2010

1.0

6.6

Nov

0.2

5.5

Oct

0.1

6.6

Sep

0.2

6.7

Aug

0.0

7.1

Jul

0.8

7.3

Jun

-0.1

9.0

May

1.4

8.3

Apr

1.0

6.5

Mar

1.1

4.2

Feb

0.1

0.6

Jan

0.9

0.5

Dec 2009

0.1

-3.7

Nov

0.9

-6.6

Oct

-0.1

-9.4

Sep

0.7

-10.7

Aug

1.0

-13.7

Jul

1.2

-15.3

Jun

-0.3

-17.8

May

-1.2

-17.8

Apr

-0.8

-18.4

Mar

-2.1

-17.5

Feb

0.0

-16.3

Jan

-2.9

-16.6

Dec 2008

-3.3

-14.1

Nov

-2.4

-11.4

Oct

-0.7

-9.1

Sep

-3.4

-8.8

Aug

-1.4

-5.3

Jul

-1.1

-3.8

Jun

-0.6

-3.2

May

-0.6

-2.5

Apr

-1.1

-1.3

Mar

-0.4

-0.7

Feb

-0.4

0.8

Jan

-0.4

2.1

Dec 2007

0.3

1.9

Nov

0.4

3.2

Oct

-0.5

2.7

Sep

0.5

2.9

Aug

-0.5

2.6

Jul

0.2

3.4

Jun

0.3

2.9

May

-0.2

3.1

Apr

0.8

3.6

Mar

0.6

2.5

Feb

0.6

1.7

Jan

-0.5

1.4

Dec 2006

 

2.8

Dec 2005

 

3.4

Dec 2004

 

4.0

Dec 2003

 

1.8

Dec 2002

 

2.3

Dec 2001

 

-5.5

Dec 2000

 

0.4

Dec 1999

 

5.4

Average ∆% Dec 1986-Dec 2011

 

2.3

Average ∆% Dec 1986-Dec 1999

 

4.3

Average ∆% Dec 1999-Dec 2006

 

1.3

Average ∆% Dec 1999-Dec 2011

 

0.2

Source: http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/g17/ipdisk/ip_nsa.txt

Chart VA-1 of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System provides industrial production, manufacturing and capacity since the 1970s. There was acceleration of growth of industrial production, manufacturing and capacity in the 1990s because of rapid growth of productivity in the US (see Pelaez and Pelaez, The Global Recession Risk (2007), 135-44). The slopes of the curves flatten in the 2000s. Production and capacity have not recovered to the levels before the global recession.

clip_image002

Chart VA-1, US, Industrial Production, Capacity and Utilization

Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/g17/current/ipg1.gif

The modern industrial revolution of Jensen (1993) is captured in Chart VA-2 of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (for the literature on M&A and corporate control see Pelaez and Pelaez, Regulation of Banks and Finance (2009a), 143-56, Globalization and the State, Vol. I (2008a), 49-59, Government Intervention in Globalization (2008c), 46-49). The slope of the curve of total industrial production accelerates in the 1990s to a much higher rate of growth than the curve excluding high-technology industries. Growth rates decelerate into the 2000s and output and capacity utilization have not recovered fully from the strong impact of the global recession. Growth in the current cyclical expansion has been more subdued than in the prior comparably deep contractions in the 1970s and 1980s. Chart VA-2 shows that the past recessions after World War II are the relevant ones for comparison with the recession after 2007 instead of common comparisons with the Great Depression (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/04/mediocre-growth-with-high-unemployment.html). The bottom left-hand part of Chart VA-2 shows the strong growth of output of communication equipment, computers and semiconductor that continued from the 1990s into the 2000s. Output of semiconductors has already surpassed the level before the global recession.

clip_image004

Chart VA-2, US, Industrial Production, Capacity and Utilization of High Technology Industries

Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/g17/current/ipg3.gif

Additional detail on industrial production and capacity utilization is provided in Chart VA-3 of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Production of consumer durable goods fell sharply during the global recession by more than 30 percent and is still around 5 percent below the level before the contraction. Output of nondurable consumer goods fell around 10 percent and is some 5 percent below the level before the contraction. Output of business equipment fell sharply during the contraction of 2001 but began rapid growth again after 2004. An important characteristic is rapid growth of output of business equipment in the cyclical expansion after sharp contraction in the global recession. Output of defense and space only suffered reduction in the rate of growth during the global recession and surged ahead of the level before the contraction. Output of construction supplies collapsed during the global recession and is well below the level before the contraction. Output of energy materials was stagnant before the contraction but has recovered sharply above the level before the contraction.

clip_image006

Chart VA-3, US, Industrial Production and Capacity Utilization

Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/g17/current/ipg2.gif

The index of general business conditions of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York Empire State Manufacturing Survey rebounded sharply from 6.56 in Apr 2012 to 17.09 in May but fell to 2.29 in Jun near the contraction border below zero, as shown in Table VA-3. The index had been registering negative changes in the five months from Jun to Oct 2011. The new orders segment improved mildly from 6.48 in Apr 2011 to 8.32 in May 2011 but fell to 2.18 in Jun, closer to contraction. There is positive reading in shipments from 6.41 in Apr to 24.14 in May and sharp decline to 4.81 in Jun. The segment of number of employees fell back into contraction territory from minus 5.43 in Sep 2011 to minus 3.66 in Nov 2011 but recovered strongly to 13.58 in Mar 2012, 19.28 in Apr, 20.14 in May but decline to 12.37 in Jun. Number of weekly hours worked fell from 18.52 in Mar 2012 to 6.02 in Apr but also rebounded to 12.05 in May, declining to 3.09 in Jun 2012. Expectations for the next six months of the general business conditions index peaked at 54.87 in Jan 2012, declining to a still strong 47.50 in Mar and 43.12 in Apr but falling to 29.26 in May and 23.12 in Jun. Expectations of new orders also peaked at 53.85 in Jan, declining to a still strong 47.50 in Mar and 45.78 in Apr but falling to 30.12 in May and 15.46 in Jun. There is a similar pattern of strong recovery in shipments with decline to 25.3 in May and 12.37 in Jun. Number of employees fell sharply to 12.05 in May, recovering partially to 16.49 in Jun. and 8.43. Hours worked collapsed to 2.06 in Jun, close to the contraction zone at zero.

Table VA-3, US, New York Federal Reserve Bank Empire State Manufacturing Survey Index SA

 

General
Index

New Orders

Shipments

# Workers

Average Work-week

Current

         

Jun 2012

2.29

2.18

4.81

12.37

3.09

May

17.09

8.32

24.14

20.48

12.05

Apr

6.56

6.48

6.41

19.28

6.02

Mar

20.21

6.84

18.21

13.58

18.52

Feb

19.53

9.73

22.79

11.76

7.06

Jan

13.48

13.70

21.69

12.09

6.59

Dec 2011

8.19

5.99

20.06

2.33

-2.33

Nov

0.80

-0.82

11.70

-3.66

2.44

Oct

-7.22

-0.26

2.89

3.37

-4.49

Sep

-7.43

-7.52

-8.28

-5.43

-2.17

Six Months

         

Jun 2012

23.13

15.46

12.37

16.49

2.06

May

29.26

30.12

25.30

12.05

8.43

Apr

43.12

45.78

44.58

27.71

10.84

Mar

47.50

41.98

43.21

32.10

20.99

Feb

50.38

44.71

49.41

29.41

18.82

Jan

54.87

53.85

52.75

28.57

17.58

Dec 2011

45.61

54.65

51.16

24.42

22.09

Nov

32.06

35.37

36.59

14.63

8.54

Oct

13.99

12.36

17.98

6.74

-2.25

Sep

22.93

13.04

13.04

0.00

-6.52

Source: http://www.newyorkfed.org/survey/empire/empiresurvey_overview.html

Growth rates and levels of sales in millions of dollars of manufacturers, retailers and merchant wholesalers are provided in Table VA-4. Total business sales rose 0.2 percent in Apr 2012 after 0.2 percent in Feb and were up by 4.9 percent in Apr 2012 relative to Apr 2011. Sales of manufacturers fell 0.3 percent in Apr after increasing 0.1 percent in Mar and rose 4.4 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr 2012. Retailers’ sales fell 0.3 percent in Apr after increasing 0.3 percent in Mar and 3.3 percent in 12 months ending in Apr. Sales of merchant wholesalers increased 1.1 percent in Apr after increasing 0.4 percent in Mar and 6.8 percent in 12 months. These data are not adjusted for price changes such that they reflect increases in both quantities and prices.

Table VA-4, US, Percentage Changes for Sales of Manufacturers, Retailers and Merchant Wholesalers

 

Apr 12/   Mar 12
∆% SA

Apr 2012
Millions of Dollars NSA

Mar 12/ Feb 12  ∆% SA

Apr 12/ Apr 11
∆% NSA

Total Business

0.2

1,244,232

0.2

4.9

Manufacturers

-0.3

475,626

0.1

4.4

Retailers

-0.3

354,456

0.3

3.3

Merchant Wholesalers

1.1

414,150

0.4

6.8

Source: US Census Bureau http://www.census.gov/mtis/ http://www.census.gov/mtis/www/data/pdf/mtis_current.pdf

Businesses added to inventories to replenish stocks in an environment of strong sales. Retailers added 0.6 percent to inventories in Apr and 0.4 percent in Mar with growth of 5.6 percent in 12 months, as shown in Table VA-5. Total business increased inventories by 0.4 percent in Apr, 0.3 percent in Mar and 6.1 percent in 12 months. Inventories sales/ratios of total business continued at a level close to 1.26 under judicious management to avoid costs and risks. Inventory/sales ratios of manufacturers and retailers are higher than for merchant wholesalers. There is stability in inventory/sales ratios in individual months and relative to a year earlier.

Table VA-5, US, Percentage Changes for Inventories of Manufacturers, Retailers and Merchant Wholesalers and Inventory/Sales Ratios

Inventory Change

Apr 12
Millions of Dollars NSA

Apr 12/ Mar  12 ∆% SA

Mar 12/  Feb 12 ∆% SA

Apr 12/   Apr 11 ∆% NSA

Total Business

1,580,299

0.4

0.3

6.1

Manufacturers

611,089

0.0

0.1

4.8

Retailers

486,070

0.6

0.4

5.6

Merchant
Wholesalers

483,140

0.6

0.3

8.3

Inventory/
Sales Ratio NSA

Feb 12
Billions of Dollars NSA

Mar 2012 SA

Feb 2012 SA

Mar 2011 SA

Total Business

1,580,299

1.26

1.26

1.25

Manufacturers

611,089

1.28

1.28

1.28

Retailers

486,070

1.34

1.33

1.34

Merchant Wholesalers

483,140

1.17

1.17

1.15

Source: US Census Bureau http://www.census.gov/mtis/ http://www.census.gov/mtis/www/data/pdf/mtis_current.pdf

Inventories follow business cycles. When recession hits sales inventories pile up, declining with expansion of the economy. In a fascinating classic opus, Lloyd Meltzer (1941, 129) concludes:

“The dynamic sequences (I) through (6) were intended to show what types of behavior are possible for a system containing a sales output lag. The following conclusions seem to be the most important:

(i) An economy in which business men attempt to recoup inventory losses will always undergo cyclical fluctuations when equilibrium is disturbed, provided the economy is stable.

This is the pure inventory cycle.

(2) The assumption of stability imposes severe limitations upon the possible size of the marginal propensity to consume, particularly if the coefficient of expectation is positive.

(3) The inventory accelerator is a more powerful de-stabilizer than the ordinary acceleration principle. The difference in stability conditions is due to the fact that the former allows for replacement demand whereas the usual analytical formulation of the latter does not. Thus, for inventories, replacement demand acts as a de-stabilizer. Whether it does so for all types of capital goods is a moot question, but I believe cases may occur in which it does not.

(4) Investment for inventory purposes cannot alter the equilibrium of income, which depends only upon the propensity to consume and the amount of non-induced investment.

(5) The apparent instability of a system containing both an accelerator and a coefficient of expectation makes further investigation of possible stabilizers highly desirable.”

Chart VA-4 shows the increase in the inventory/sales ratios during the recessions of 2001 and 2007-2009. The inventory/sales ratio fell during the expansions. The inventory/sales ratio declined to a trough in 2011, climbed and then stabilized at current levels.

clip_image008

Chart VA-4, Total Business Inventories/Sales Ratios 2002 to 2011

Source: US Census Bureau

http://www2.census.gov/retail/releases/historical/mtis/img/mtisbrf.gif

Sales of retail and food services fell 0.2 percent in May 2012 and fell 0.2 percent in Apr and increased 7.0 percent in Jan-May 2012 relative to Jan-May 2011, as shown in Table VA-6. Excluding motor vehicles and parts, retail sales fell 0.4 percent in May 2012 after falling 0.3 percent in Apr and growing 6.6 percent in Jan-May relative to a year earlier. Sales of motor vehicles and parts increased 0.8 percent in May after increasing 0.1 percent in Apr and 8.7 percent in Jan-May relative to a year earlier. Gasoline station sales decreased 2.2 percent in May after decreasing 1.4 percent in Apr in declining prices of gasoline, increasing 6.8 percent in Jan-May relative to a year earlier.

Table VA-6, US, Percentage Change in Monthly Sales for Retail and Food Services, ∆%

 

May/ Apr ∆% SA

Apr/Mar ∆% SA

Jan-May 2012 Million Dollars NSA

Jan-May 2012 from Jan-May 2011 ∆% NSA

Retail and Food Services

-0.2

-0.2

1,979,360

7.0

Excluding Motor Vehicles and Parts

-0.4

-0.3

1,609,333

6.6

Motor Vehicles & Parts

0.8

0.1

370,027

8.7

Retail

-0.2

-0.3

1,762,012

6.8

Building Materials

-1.7

-2.3

121,627

11.1

Food and Beverage

-0.2

0.3

257,963

4.2

Grocery

-0.2

0.3

232,683

4.0

Health & Personal Care Stores

-0.1

0.6

115,482

2.9

Clothing & Clothing Accessories Stores

0.9

-1.2

90,751

7.2

Gasoline Stations

-2.2

-1.4

224,942

6.8

General Merchandise Stores

-0.5

-0.9

250,877

3.2

Food Services & Drinking Places

-0.2

0.5

217,348

8.7

Source: US Census Bureau http://www.census.gov/retail/ http://www.census.gov/retail/marts/www/marts_current.pdf

Chart VA-5 of the US Bureau of the Census shows percentage change of retail and food services sales. Auto sales have been strongly monthly, and particularly relative to a year earlier, but with weakness in the total excluding auto sales.

clip_image010

Chart VA-5, US, Percentage Change of Retail and Food Services Sales

Source: US Census Bureau

http://www2.census.gov/retail/releases/historical/marts/img/martsbrf.gif

Twelve-month rates of growth of US sales of retail and food services in May from 2000 to 2012 are shown in Table VA-7. Nominal sales have been dynamic in 2012, 2011 and 2010 after decline of 12.5 percent in 2009 and increase of only 1.8 percent in 2008. It is difficult to separate price and quantity effects in these nominal data.

Table VA-7, US, Percentage Change in 12-Month Sales for Retail and Food Services, ∆% NSA

May

12 Months ∆%

2012

7.1

2011

7.8

2010

5.3

2009

-12.5

2008

1.8

2007

4.8

2006

8.2

2005

5.2

2004

5.1

2003

4.0

2002

1.5

2001

4.3

2000

8.2

Source: http://www.census.gov/retail/

The US Treasury budget for fiscal year 2012 in the first eight months of Oct-Dec 2011 and Jan-May 2012 is shown in Table VA-8. Receipts increased 5.4 percent in the first eight months of fiscal year 2012 relative to the same eight months in fiscal year 2011 or Oct-Dec 2010 and Jan-May 2011. Individual income taxes have grown 4.2 percent relative to the same period a year earlier. Outlays were lower by 0.1 percent relative to a year earlier. The final two rows of Table VA-8 provide the projection of the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) of the deficit for fiscal year 2012 at $1.2 trillion not very different from that in fiscal year 2011 of $1.3 trillion. The deficits from 2009 to 2012 exceed one trillion dollars per year, adding to $5.2 trillion in four years, which is the worst fiscal performance since World War II.

Table VA-8, US, Treasury Budget in Fiscal Year to Date Million Dollars

Fiscal Year 2012

Oct 2011 to May 2012

Oct 2010 to May 2011

∆%

Receipts

1,563,904

1,484,375

5.4

Outlays

2,408,399

2,411,821

-0.1

Deficit

-844,494

-927,445

NA

Individual Income Taxes

731,282

701,850

4.2

Social Insurance

379,248

382,987

-1.0

 

Receipts

Outlays

Deficit (-), Surplus (+)

$ Billions

     

CBO Forecast Fiscal Year 2012

2,456

3,627

-1,171

Fiscal Year 2011

2,303

3,603

-1,300

Fiscal Year 2010

2,162

3,456

-1,294

Fiscal Year 2009

2,105

3,518

-1,413

Fiscal Year 2008

2,524

2,983

-459

Source: http://www.fms.treas.gov/mts/index.html

CBO (2011AugBEO); Office of Management and Budget. 2011. Historical Tables. Budget of the US Government Fiscal Year 2011. Washington, DC: OMB; CBO. 2011JanBEO. Budget and Economic Outlook. Washington, DC, Jan. CBO. 2012MarBEO. Updated budget projections: fiscal years 2012 to 2022. Washington, DC: Congressional Budget Office, Mar.

Risk aversion channels funds toward US long-term and short-term securities that finance the US balance of payments and fiscal deficits benefitting at the moment from risk flight to US dollar denominated assets. Net foreign purchases of US long-term securities (row C in Table VA-9) decreased from $36.0 billion in Mar 2012 to $25.6 billion in Apr 2012. Foreign (residents) purchases minus sales of US long-term securities (row A in Table VA-9) in Mar of $21.9 billion increased to $26.1 billion in Apr 2012. Net US (residents) purchases of long-term foreign securities (row B in Table VA-9) fell from $14.1 billion in Mar to minus $0.6 billion in Apr. In Apr, with a minor rounding error,

C = A + B = $26.1 billion - $0.6 billion = $25.6 billion

There is increasing demand in Table VA-12 in Apr in A1 private purchases by residents overseas of US long-term securities of $15.4 billion of which increases in A11 Treasury securities of $22.2 billion, decrease in A12 of $7.2 billion in agency securities decrease by $0.1 of corporate bonds and increase of $0.5 billion in equities. Worldwide risk aversion causes flight into US Treasury obligations. Official purchases of Treasury securities in row A21 increased $10.7 billion with increase of Treasury securities of $15.1 billion, which is sharply lower than $33.9 billion in Mar. Row D shows sharp decrease in Apr in purchases of short-term dollar denominated obligations. Foreign private holdings of US Treasury bills decreased $5.9 billion (row D11) with foreign official holdings decreasing $10.3 billion while the category other increased $10.6 billion. Risk aversion of default losses in foreign securities dominates decisions to accept zero interest rates in Treasury securities with no perception of principal losses. In the case of long-term securities, investors prefer to sacrifice inflation and possible duration risk to avoid principal losses.

Table VA-9, Net Cross-Borders Flows of US Long-Term Securities, Billion Dollars, NSA

 

Apr 2011 12 Months

Apr 2012 12 Months

Mar 2012

Apr 2012

A Foreign Purchases less Sales of
US LT Securities

769.9

461.0

21.9

26.1

A1 Private

591.3

289.8

-6.7

15.4

A11 Treasury

346.7

297.9

-13.8

22.2

A12 Agency

124.3

51.5

-1.4

-7.2

A13 Corporate Bonds

-4.5

-46.5

2.0

-0.1

A14 Equities

124.7

-13.1

6.5

0.5

A2 Official

178.6

171.1

28.6

10.7

A21 Treasury

198.4

166.4

33.9

15.1

A22 Agency

-17.1

-1.4

-5.3

-6.9

A23 Corporate Bonds

-2.6

1.8

-0.4

0.4

A24 Equities

0.0

4.4

0.5

2.1

B Net US Purchases of LT Foreign Securities

-152.7

-12.7

14.1

-0.6

B1 Foreign Bonds

-55.7

16.0

17.0

2.5

B2 Foreign Equities

-97.0

-28.7

-2.9

-3.1

C Net Foreign Purchases of US LT Securities

617.2

448.3

36.0

25.6

D Increase in Foreign Holdings of Dollar Denominated Short-term 

-60.2

-60.0

-9.4

-5.6

D1 US Treasury Bills

-67.1

-36.2

-2.7

-16.2

D11 Private

9.8

39.7

2.1

-5.9

D12 Official

-76.8

-76.0

-4.8

-10.3

D2 Other

6.9

-23.7

-6.7

10.6

C = A + B;

A = A1 + A2

A1 = A11 + A12 + A13 + A14

A2 = A21 + A22 + A23 + A24

B = B1 + B2

D = D1 + D2

D1 = D11 + D12

Sources: http://www.treasury.gov/press-center/press-releases/Pages/tg1614.aspx http://www.treasury.gov/resource-center/data-chart-center/tic/Pages/ticpress.aspx

Table VA-10 provides major foreign holders of US Treasury securities. China is the largest holder with $1145.5 billion in Apr 2012, decreasing 0.6 percent from $1152.5 billion in Apr 2011. Japan increased its holdings from $906.7 billion in Apr 2011 to $1066.1 billion in Apr 2012 or by 17.6 percent likely in part by intervention to buy dollars against the yen to depreciate the overvalued yen/dollar rate that diminishes the competitiveness of Japan. Total foreign holdings of Treasury securities rose from $4496.5 billion in Apr 2011 to $5156.0 billion in Apr 2012, or 14.7 percent. The US continues to finance its fiscal and balance of payments deficits with foreign savings.

Table VA-10, US, Major Foreign Holders of Treasury Securities $ Billions at End of Period

 

Apr 2012

Mar 2012

Apr 2011

Total

5156.0

5135.0

4496.5

China

1145.5

1144.0

1152.5

Japan

1066.1

1076.3

906.7

Oil Exporters

252.4

257.3

221.6

Caribbean Banking Centers

247.0

234.3

140.8

Brazil

246.7

238.1

206.9

Taiwan

188.3

190.1

154.6

UK

154.2

121.9

333.2

Switzerland

151.1

150.5

106.2

Russia

146.8

151.1

125.4

Belgium

141.0

141.6

31.6

Hong Kong

139.4

140.3

121.9

Luxembourg

125.0

140.0

76.2

Source: http://www.treasury.gov/resource-center/data-chart-center/tic/Pages/ticsec2.aspx#ussecs

The current account of the US balance of payments is provided in Table VA-11 for IQ2011 and IQ2012. The US has a large deficit in goods or exports less imports of goods but it has a surplus in services that helps to reduce the trade account deficit or exports less imports of goods and services. The current account deficit of the US increased from $119.9 billion in IQ2011, or 3.2 percent of GDP to $137.3 billion in IQ2012, or 3.6 percent of GDP. The ratio of the current account deficit to GDP has stabilized around 3 percent of GDP compared with much higher percentages before the recession (see Pelaez and Pelaez, The Global Recession Risk (2007), Globalization and the State, Vol. II (2008b), 183-94, Government Intervention in Globalization (2008c), 167-71).

Table VA-11, US Balance of Payments, Millions of Dollars NSA

 

IQ2011

IQ2012

Difference

Goods Balance

-181,358

-194,462

-13,104

X Goods

360,917

388,501

11.0 ∆%

M Goods

-542,276

-582.963

12.9 ∆%

Services Balance

44,133

43,465

-668

X Services

147,894

154,420

9.1 ∆%

M Services

-103,761

-110,955

8.0 ∆%

Balance Goods and Services

-137,225

-150,997

-13,772

Balance Income

52,451

47,571

-4,880

Unilateral Transfers

-35,223

-33,887

1,336

Current Account Balance

-119,997

-137,313

-17,316

% GDP

IQ2011

IVQ2011

IQ2012

 

3.2

3.1

3.6

X: exports; M: imports

Balance on Current Account = Balance on Goods and Services + Balance on Income + Unilateral Transfers

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/international/index.htm#bop

In their classic work on “unpleasant monetarist arithmetic,” Sargent and Wallace (1981, 2) consider a regime of domination of monetary policy by fiscal policy (emphasis added):

“Imagine that fiscal policy dominates monetary policy. The fiscal authority independently sets its budgets, announcing all current and future deficits and surpluses and thus determining the amount of revenue that must be raised through bond sales and seignorage. Under this second coordination scheme, the monetary authority faces the constraints imposed by the demand for government bonds, for it must try to finance with seignorage any discrepancy between the revenue demanded by the fiscal authority and the amount of bonds that can be sold to the public. Suppose that the demand for government bonds implies an interest rate on bonds greater than the economy’s rate of growth. Then if the fiscal authority runs deficits, the monetary authority is unable to control either the growth rate of the monetary base or inflation forever. If the principal and interest due on these additional bonds are raised by selling still more bonds, so as to continue to hold down the growth of base money, then, because the interest rate on bonds is greater than the economy’s growth rate, the real stock of bonds will growth faster than the size of the economy. This cannot go on forever, since the demand for bonds places an upper limit on the stock of bonds relative to the size of the economy. Once that limit is reached, the principal and interest due on the bonds already sold to fight inflation must be financed, at least in part, by seignorage, requiring the creation of additional base money.”

The current real value of government debt plus monetary liabilities depends on the expected discounted values of future primary surpluses or difference between tax revenue and government expenditure excluding interest payments (Cochrane 2011Jan, 27, equation (16)). There is a point when adverse expectations about the capacity of the government to generate primary surpluses to honor its obligations can result in increases in interest rates on government debt.

This analysis suggests that there may be a point of saturation of demand for United States financial liabilities without an increase in interest rates on Treasury securities. A risk premium may develop on US debt. Such premium is not apparent currently because of distressed conditions in the world economy and international financial system. Risk premiums are observed in the spread of bonds of highly indebted countries in Europe relative to bonds of the government of Germany.

The issue of global imbalances centered on the possibility of a disorderly correction (Pelaez and Pelaez, The Global Recession Risk (2007), Globalization and the State Vol. II (2008b) 183-94, Government Intervention in Globalization (2008c), 167-71). Such a correction has not occurred historically but there is no argument proving that it could not occur. The need for a correction would originate in unsustainable large and growing United States current account deficits (CAD) and net international investment position (NIIP) or excess of financial liabilities of the US held by foreigners net of financial liabilities of foreigners held by US residents. The IMF estimated that the US could maintain a CAD of two to three percent of GDP without major problems (Rajan 2004). The threat of disorderly correction is summarized by Pelaez and Pelaez, The Global Recession Risk (2007), 15):

“It is possible that foreigners may be unwilling to increase their positions in US financial assets at prevailing interest rates. An exit out of the dollar could cause major devaluation of the dollar. The depreciation of the dollar would cause inflation in the US, leading to increases in American interest rates. There would be an increase in mortgage rates followed by deterioration of real estate values. The IMF has simulated that such an adjustment would cause a decline in the rate of growth of US GDP to 0.5 percent over several years. The decline of demand in the US by four percentage points over several years would result in a world recession because the weakness in Europe and Japan could not compensate for the collapse of American demand. The probability of occurrence of an abrupt adjustment is unknown. However, the adverse effects are quite high, at least hypothetically, to warrant concern.”

The United States could be moving toward a situation typical of heavily indebted countries, requiring fiscal adjustment and increases in productivity to become more competitive internationally. The CAD and NIIP of the United States are not observed in full deterioration because the economy is well below potential. There are two complications in the current environment relative to the concern with disorderly correction in the first half of the past decade. Table VA-12 provides data on the US fiscal and balance of payments imbalances. In 2007, the federal deficit of the US was $161 billion corresponding to 1.2 percent of GDP while the Congressional Budget Office (CBO 2012MarBEO, 2) estimates the federal deficit in 2012 at $1171 billion or 7.6 percent of GDP. The combined record federal deficits of the US from 2009 to 2012 are $5178 billion or 33 percent of the estimate of GDP of $15,508 billion for 2012 by the CBO (2012MarBEO, 2). Federal debt in 2007 was $5035 billion, less than the combined deficits from 2009 to 2012 of $5178 billion, and corresponded to 36.3 percent of GDP. Federal debt in 2011 was 67.7 percent of GDP and is estimated to reach 73.2 percent of GDP in 2012 (CBO2012MarBEO, 2). This situation may worsen in the future (CBO 2012LTBO):

“The budget outlook is much bleaker under the extended alternative fiscal scenario, which maintains what some analysts might consider “current policies,” as opposed to current laws. Federal debt would grow rapidly from its already high level, exceeding 90 percent of GDP in 2022. After that, the growing imbalance between revenues and spending, combined with spiraling interest payments, would swiftly push debt to higher and higher levels. Debt as a share of GDP would exceed its historical peak of 109 percent by 2026, and it would approach 200 percent in 2037.

The changes under this scenario would result in much lower revenues than would occur under the extended baseline scenario because almost all expiring tax provisions are assumed to be extended through 2022 (with the exception of the current reduction in the payroll tax rate for Social Security). After 2022, revenues under this scenario are assumed to remain at their 2022 level of 18.5 percent of GDP, just above the average of the past 40 years.

Outlays would be much higher than under the other scenario. This scenario incorporates assumptions that through 2022, lawmakers will act to prevent Medicare’s payment rates for physicians from declining; that after 2022, lawmakers will not allow various restraints on the growth of Medicare costs and health insurance subsidies to exert their full effect; and that the automatic reductions in spending required by the Budget Control Act of 2011 will not occur (although the original caps on discretionary appropriations in that law are assumed to remain in place). Finally, under this scenario, federal spending as a percentage of GDP for activities other than Social Security, the major health care programs, and interest payments is assumed to return to its average level during the past two decades, rather than fall significantly below that level, as it does under the extended baseline scenario.”

Table VA-12, US, Current Account, NIIP, Fiscal Balance, Nominal GDP, Federal Debt and Direct Investment, Dollar Billions and %

 

2000

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

Goods &
Services

-377

-697

-698

-379

-495

-559

Income

19

101

147

119

184

227

UT

-58

-115

-126

-122

-131

-133

Current Account

-416

-710

-677

-382

-442

-466

NGDP

9951

14028

14291

13939

14526

15094

Current Account % GDP

-3.8

-5.0

-4.9

-2.7

-3.4

-3.7

NIIP

-1337

-1796

-3260

-2396

-2471

NA

NIIP % GDP

-13.4

-12.8

-22.8

-17.2

-17.0

NA

Exports
Goods
Services
Income

1425

2488

2657

2181

2519

2848

NIIP %
Exports
Goods
Services
Income

-94

-72

-123

-110

-98

NA

DIA MV

2694

5274

3102

4331

4843

NA

DIUS MV

2783

3551

2486

3027

3451

NA

Fiscal Balance

+236

-161

-459

-1413

-1294

-1300

Fiscal Balance % GDP

+2.4

-1.2

-3.2

-9.9

-8.9

-8.7

Federal   Debt

3410

5035

5803

7545

9019

10128

Federal Debt % GDP

34.7

36.3

40.5

54.1

62.8

67.7

Federal Outlays

1789

2729

2983

3518

3456

3598

∆%

5.1

2.8

9.3

17.9

-1.8

4.1

% GDP

18.2

19.7

20.8

25.2

24.1

24.1

Federal Revenue

2052

2568

2524

2105

2162

2303

∆%

10.8

6.7

-1.7

-16.6

2.7

6.5

% GDP

20.6

18.5

17.6

15.1

15.1

15.4

Sources: 

Notes: UT: unilateral transfers; NGDP: nominal GDP or in current dollars; NIIP: Net International Investment Position; DIA MV: US Direct Investment Abroad at Market Value; DIUS MV: Direct Investment in the US at Market Value. There are minor discrepancies in the decimal point of percentages of GDP between the balance of payments data and federal debt, outlays, revenue and deficits in which they original number of the CBO source is maintained. These discrepancies do not alter conclusions.

Sources: Balance of Payments and NIIP, Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) http://www.bea.gov/international/index.htm#bop

Gross Domestic Product, Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) http://www.bea.gov/national/index.htm#gdp

Federal Outlays, Revenues and Debt, Congressional Budget Office (CBO) http://www.cbo.gov/publication/42911

Chart VA-8 provides the explosive potential path of US government debt. The literature of the 1980s called simultaneous fiscal and balance of payments deficits as “twin deficits.” Because of the lack of sufficient domestic savings, the US finances its deficits with foreign savings. The NIIP provides the mechanism of financing with more liabilities of the US held by foreigners than liabilities of foreigners held by US residents. The NIIP of the US has grown from 12.8 percent of GDP in 2007 to 17.0 percent in 2010, which is the most recent annual information available while the ratio of the NIIP to potential revenue to service it from exports of goods, services and income is 98 percent (Table VA-12). Another complicating factor is “unconventional monetary” policy consisting of discretionary wide swings that characterized financial and economic instability in the past compared with monetary policy rules that characterized financial and economic stability with sound aggregate performance (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/rules-versus-discretionary-authorities.html). Taylor (1993, 1998LB, 1999, 2012JMCB) argues that economic performance has been enhanced during periods of long-term focus of monetary policy in the form of guidance under monetary policy rules. Periods of discretion such as the Great Inflation from the second half of the 1960s to the beginning of the 1980s (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/05/slowing-growth-global-inflation-great.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/04/new-economics-of-rose-garden-turned.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/03/is-there-second-act-of-us-great.html) and the past decade since 2003 have been characterized by instability and mediocre economic performance.

clip_image012

Chart VA-8, United States, Long-term Projections of the Federal Debt Held by the Public

Congressional Budget Office

http://www.cbo.gov/

Chart VA-9 of the Bureau of Economic Analysis of the Department of Commerce shows on the lower negative panel the sharp increase in the deficit in goods and the deficits in goods and services from 1960 to 2011. The upper panel shows the increase in the surplus in services that was insufficient to contain the increase of the deficit in goods and services. The adjustment during the global recession has been in the form of contraction of economic activity that reduced demand for goods.

clip_image014

Chart VA-9, US, Balance of Goods, Balance on Services and Balance on Goods and Services, 1960-2011, Millions of Dollars

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_ita.cfm

Chart VA-10 of the Bureau of Economic Analysis shows exports and imports of goods and services from 1960 to 2011. Exports of goods and services in the upper positive panel have been quite dynamic but have not compensated for the sharp increase in imports of goods. The US economy apparently has become less competitive in goods than in services.

clip_image016

Chart VA-10, US, Exports and Imports of Goods and Services, 1960-2011, Millions of Dollars

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_ita.cfm

Chart VA-11 of the Bureau of Economic Analysis shows the US balance on current account from 1960 to 2011. The sharp devaluation of the dollar resulting from unconventional monetary policy of zero interest rates and elimination of auctions of 30-year Treasury bonds did not adjust the US balance of payments. Adjustment only occurred after the contraction of economic activity during the global recession.

clip_image018

Chart VA-11, US, Balance on Current Account, 1960-2011, Millions of Dollars

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_ita.cfm

Chart VA-12of the Bureau of Economic Analysis provides real GDP in the US from 1960 to 2011. The contraction of economic activity during the global recession was a major factor in the reduction of the current account deficit as percent of GDP.

clip_image020

Chart VA-12, US, Real GDP, 1960-2011, Billions of Chained 2005 Dollars

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

VB Japan. Table VB-BOJF provides the forecasts of economic activity and inflation in Japan by the majority of members of the Policy Board of the Bank of Japan, which is part of their Outlook for Economic Activity and Prices (http://www.boj.or.jp/en/mopo/outlook/gor1204a.pdf

http://www.boj.or.jp/en/mopo/outlook/gor1204b.pdf). For fiscal 2012, the forecast is of growth of GDP between 2.1 and 2.4 percent, with domestic producer price inflation (Corporate Goods Price Index, CGPI) in the range of 0.4 to 0.7 percent and the all items CPI less fresh food of 0.1 to 0.4 percent.

Table VB-BOJF, Bank of Japan, Forecasts of the Majority of Members of the Policy Board, % Year on Year

Fiscal Year
Date of Forecast

Real GDP

Domestic CGPI

CPI All Items Less Fresh Food

2011

     

Apr 2012

-0.2 to –0.2
[-0.2]

+1.7

0.0

Jan 2012

-0.4 to –0.3
[-0.4]

+1.8 to +1.9
[+1.8]

-0.1 to 0.0
[-0.1]

2012

     

Apr 2012

+2.1 to +2.4
[+2.3]

+0.4 to +0.7
[+0.6]

+0.1 to +0.4
[+0.3]

Jan 2012

+1.8 to +2.1
[+2.0]

-0.1 to +0.2
[+0.1]

0.0 to +0.2
[+0.1]

2013

     

Apr 2012

+1.6 to +1.8
[+1.7]

+0.7 to +0.9
[+0.8]

+0.5 to +0.7
[+0.7]

Jan 2012

+1.4 to +1.7
[+1.6]

+0.6 to 1.0
[+0.8]

+0.4 to +0.5
[+0.5]

Figures in brackets are the median of forecasts of Policy Board members

Source: Policy Board, Bank of Japan

http://www.boj.or.jp/en/mopo/outlook/gor1204a.pdf

http://www.boj.or.jp/en/mopo/outlook/gor1204b.pdf

Private-sector activity in Japan expanded at lower pace with the Markit Composite Output PMI Index declining from 51.3 in Apr to 50.1 in May (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9619). Alex Hamilton, economist at Markit and author of the report, finds softer conditions in Japan relative to Apr with the survey’s index suggesting movement toward stagnation (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9619). The Markit Business Activity Index of Services decreased from 51.0 in Apr to 49.8 in May, also showing slower pace and the first reading below 50.0 in six months (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9619). The Markit/JMMA Purchasing Managers’ Index, seasonally adjusted, registered 50.7 in May, indicating marginal improvement in manufacturing in Japan (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9457). Alex Hamilton, economist at Markit and author of the report, finds output and new business growing at marginal rate with the impulse originating in investment goods while consumer and intermediate goods contracted (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9457). Table JPY provides the country data table for Japan.

Table JPY, Japan, Economic Indicators

Historical GDP and CPI

1981-2010 Real GDP Growth and CPI Inflation 1981-2010
Blog 7/31/11

Corporate Goods Prices

May ∆% -0.4
12 months ∆% minus 0.5
Blog 6/17/12

Consumer Price Index

Apr NSA ∆% 0.1
Apr 12 months NSA ∆% 0.4
Blog 5/27/12

Real GDP Growth

IQ2012 ∆%: 1.2 on IVQ2011;  IQ2012 SAAR 4.7;
∆% from quarter a year earlier: 2.8 %
Blog 6/10/12

Employment Report

Apr Unemployed 3.15 million

Change in unemployed since last year: minus 140 thousand
Unemployment rate: 4.6%
Blog 6/3/12

All Industry Indices

Mar month SA ∆% minus 0.3
12-month NSA ∆% 5.5

Blog 5/27/12

Industrial Production

Apr SA month ∆%: 0.2
12-month NSA ∆% 13.4
Blog 6/3/12

Machine Orders

Total Apr ∆% -4.0

Private ∆%: 16.4
Apr ∆% Excluding Volatile Orders 5.7
Blog 6/17/12

Tertiary Index

Apr month SA ∆% -0.3
Apr 12 months NSA ∆% 2.5
Blog 6/17/12

Wholesale and Retail Sales

Apr 12 months:
Total ∆%: +1.8
Wholesale ∆%: +0.3
Retail ∆%: +5.8
Blog 6/3/12

Family Income and Expenditure Survey

Apr 12-month ∆% total nominal consumption 3.2, real 2.6 Blog 6/3/12

Trade Balance

Exports Apr 12 months ∆%: +7.9 Imports Apr 12 months ∆% +8.0 Blog 5/27/12

Links to blog comments in Table JPY:

6/10/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/rules-versus-discretionary-authorities_10.html

6/3/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/mediocre-recovery-without-jobs_04.html

5/27/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/05/world-financial-turbulence-global_27.html

7/31/11: http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/07/growth-recession-debt-financial-risk.html

The tertiary activity index of Japan seasonally adjusted fell at the annual equivalent rate of minus 4.4 percent in Jan-Apr 2012 for cumulative decline of 1.5 percent but increased 2.5 percent not seasonally adjusted in the 12 months ending in Apr 2012, as shown in Table VB-1. There was strong impact from the Tōhoku or Great East Earthquake and Tsunami of Mar 11, 2011 in the decline of the tertiary activity index by 5.4 percent in Mar 2011 and 3.4 percent in 12 months. The performance of the tertiary sector in the quarter Jul-Sep was weak: increase of 0.4 percent in Jul, increase of 0.1 percent in Aug and decline of 0.2 percent in Sep, after increasing 1.2 percent in Jun. The not seasonally adjusted index gained 4.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Mar 2012. Most of the growth occurred in the quarter from Apr to Jun 2011 with gain of 4.3 percent or at annual equivalent rate of 18.1 percent.

Table VB-1, Japan, Tertiary Activity Index, ∆%

 

Month ∆% SA

12 Months ∆% NSA

Apr 2012

-0.3

2.5

Mar

-0.6

4.2

Feb

0.0

2.4

Jan

-0.6

0.4

Dec 2011

1.6

1.2

Nov

-0.8

-0.3

Oct

0.6

0.9

Sep

-0.2

0.1

Aug

0.1

0.8

Jul

0.4

0.1

Jun

1.2

1.0

May

0.9

-0.2

Apr

2.1

-2.3

Mar

-5.4

-3.4

Feb

0.3

2.0

Jan

0.5

1.0

Dec 2010

-0.2

1.8

Nov

0.6

2.5

Oct

0.2

0.5

Sep

-0.4

1.3

Aug

0.1

2.3

Jul

0.7

1.6

Jun

0.1

1.0

May

-0.3

1.2

Dec 2009

 

-2.7

Dec 2008

 

-3.3

Dec 2007

 

-0.3

Dec 2006

 

0.6

Dec 2005

 

2.6

Dec 2004

 

1.6

Calendar Year

   

2011

 

0.1

2010

 

1.3

2009

 

-5.2

Source: http://www.meti.go.jp/english/statistics/tyo/sanzi/index.html

http://www.meti.go.jp/statistics/tyo/sanzi/result/pdf/hv37903_201204j.pdf

Month and 12-month rates of growth of the tertiary activity index of Japan and components in Jan are provided in Table VB-2. Electricity, gas, heat supply and water declined 1.3 percent in Apr and increased 2.9 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr. Wholesale and retail trade increased 0.8 percent in the month of Apr and 2.1 percent in 12 months. Information and communications increased 6.5 percent in Apr and was flat in 12 months.

Table VB-2, Japan, Tertiary Index and Components, Month and 12-Month Percentage Changes ∆%

Apr 2012

Weight

Month ∆% SA

12 Months ∆% NSA

Tertiary Index

10,000.0

-0.3

2.5

Electricity, Gas, Heat Supply & Water

372.9

-1.3

2.9

Information & Communications

951.2

6.5

0.0

Wholesale & Retail Trade

2,641.2

0.8

2.1

Finance & Insurance

971.1

0.7

3.1

Real Estate & Goods Rental & Leasing

903.4

0.2

0.2

Scientific Research, Professional & Technical Services

551.3

-0.4

6.5

Accommodations, Eating, Drinking

496.0

-0.5

9.3

Living-Related, Personal, Amusement Services

552.7

-0.2

12.8

Learning Support

116.9

0.6

2.5

Medical, Health Care, Welfare

921.1

0.0

1.5

Miscellaneous ex Government

626.7

-2.2

-4.4

Source: http://www.meti.go.jp/english/statistics/tyo/sanzi/index.html http://www.meti.go.jp/statistics/tyo/sanzi/result/pdf/hv37903_201204j.pdf

Japan’s machinery orders in Table VB-3 decreased 4.0 percent in Apr after increasing 4.1 percent in Mar. Total orders grew 13.4 percent in Jan after falling 2.7 percent in Dec but fell 11.3 percent in Feb. Private-sector orders excluding volatile orders, which are closely watched, increased 5.7 percent in Apr, decreasing 2.8 percent in Mar after growing 2.8 percent in Feb and 0.7 percent in Jan but falling 20.2 percent in Dec. Orders for manufacturing increased 3.4 percent in Apr but fell 8.4 percent in Mar, increasing 9.5 percent in Feb after falling 1.3 percent in Jan and 4.0 percent in Dec. Overseas orders increased 0.3 percent in Apr and fell 14.4 percent in Mar after dropping 13.4 percent in Feb but jumping 14.6 percent in Jan. There is significant volatility in industrial orders in advanced economies.

Table VB-3, Japan, Machinery Orders, Month ∆%, SA 

2011-2012

Apr

Mar

Feb

Jan

Total

-4.0

4.1

-11.4

13.4

Private Sector

16.4

-4.3

3.5

4.6

Excluding Volatile Orders

5.7

-2.8

2.8

0.7

Mfg

3.4

-8.4

9.5

-1.3

Non Mfg ex Volatile

5.7

-3.9

2.1

1.4

Government

-5.0

40.0

-6.1

-16.1

From Overseas

0.3

-14.4

-13.4

14.6

Through Agencies

-21.1

21.5

3.8

-2.1

Note: Mfg: manufacturing

Source: Japan Economic and Social Research Institute, Cabinet Office

http://www.esri.cao.go.jp/en/stat/juchu/juchu-e.html

Total orders for machinery and total private-sector orders excluding volatile orders for Japan are shown in Chart VB-1 of Japan’s Economic and Social Research Institute at the Cabinet Office. The trend of private-sector orders excluding volatile orders is showing recovery from the drop in after Mar 2011 because of the earthquake/tsunami. There could be reversal of the trend of increase in total orders with recent increases. Fluctuations still prevent detecting longer term trends but recovery is evident from the global recession.

clip_image021

Chart VB-1, Japan, Machinery Orders

Source: Japan Economic and Social Research Institute, Cabinet Office

http://www.esri.cao.go.jp/en/stat/juchu/juchu-e.html

Table VB-4 provides values and percentage changes from a year earlier of Japan’s machinery orders without seasonal adjustment. Total orders of JPY 1,904,319 million in Apr 2012 are divided between JPY 679,947 million overseas orders, or 35.7 percent of the total, and domestic orders of JPY 1,135,840 million, or 59.6 percent of the total, with orders through agencies of JPY 88,352 million, or 4.6 percent of the total. Orders through agencies are not shown in the table because of the minor value. Twelve-month percentages changes in Apr 2012 rebounded again: 7.5 percent for total orders, minus 10.0 percent for overseas orders, 23.0 percent for domestic orders and 6.6 percent for private orders excluding volatile items. Performance was also strong in Mar with growth of total orders of 8.1 percent mostly because of growth of domestic orders by 19.0 percent. Percentage growth of overseas orders was negative in three consecutive months from Feb to Apr 2012. Performance in Feb 2012 was weak with growth of total orders of minus 9.3 percent, minus 8.9 percent of overseas orders, minus 11.2 percent of domestic orders and 8.9 percent of private orders excluding volatile items. Jan 2012 was quite strong with growth of total orders of 9.8 percent driven by growth of overseas orders of 18.3 percent. There is sharp reversal of 12-month percentage changes in Nov with increase of 11.0 percent in total orders, 8.0 percent in overseas orders, 13.5 percent in domestic orders and 12.5 percent in private orders excluding volatile items. The pace of increase declined in Dec with growth in 12 months of 0.8 percent for total orders, 12.6 percent for overseas orders, decline of 8.5 percent for domestic orders and growth of private orders excluding volatile items of 6.3 percent. There was strong impact from the global recession with total orders falling 23.3 percent in 2008, overseas orders dropping 29.4 percent and domestic orders decreasing 17.4 percent. Recovery was vigorous in 2010 with increase of total orders by 9.4 percent, overseas orders by 3.5 percent and domestic orders by 14.1 percent. The heavy impact of the Tōhoku or Great East Earthquake and Tsunami of Mar 11, 2011 also affected machinery orders.

Table VB-4, Japan, Machinery Orders, 12 Months ∆% and Million Yen, Original Series  

 

Total

Overseas

Domestic

Private ex Volatile

Value Mar 2012

1,904,319

679,947

1,135,840

702,762

% Total

100.0

35.7

59.6

36.9

Value Mar 2011

1,771,130

752,127

923,497

659,031

% Total

100.0

42.5

52.1

37.2

12-month ∆%

       

Apr 2012

7.5

-9.6

23.0

6.6

Mar 2012

8.1

-10.0

19.0

-1.1

Feb 2012

-9.3

-8.9

-11.2

8.9

Jan 2012

9.8

18.3

0.5

5.7

Dec 2011

0.8

12.6

-8.5

6.3

Nov 2011

11.0

8.0

13.5

12.5

Oct 2011

-6.8

-15.6

-1.0

1.5

Dec 2010

9.4

3.5

14.1

-0.6

Dec 2009

1.8

0.4

3.6

-1.9

Dec 2008

-23.3

-29.4

-17.4

-24.7

Dec 2007

1.3

9.8

-4.3

-6.4

Dec 2006

0.8

0.9

-0.1

0.1

Note: Total machinery orders = overseas + domestic demand + orders through agencies. Orders through agencies in Apr 2012 were JPY 88,532 million, or 4.6 percent of the total, and are not shown in the table. The data are the original numbers without any adjustments and differ from the seasonally-adjusted data.

Source: Japan Economic and Social Research Institute, Cabinet Office

http://www.esri.cao.go.jp/en/stat/juchu/juchu-e.html

VC China. China estimates an index of nonmanufacturing purchasing managers on the basis of a sample of 1200 nonmanufacturing enterprises across the country (http://www.stats.gov.cn/english/pressrelease/t20120605_402810072.htm). Table CIPMS provides this index and components from Jan to May 2012. The index fell from 57.3 in Mar to 55.2 in May and is now lower than 55.7 in Jan but still remains above the threshold of contraction of 50.0.

Table CIPMS, China, Nonmanufacturing Index of Purchasing Managers, %, Seasonally Adjusted

 

Total Index

New Orders

Interm.
Input Prices

Subs Prices

Exp

May

55.2

52.5

53.6

48.5

65.4

Apr

56.1

52.7

57.9

50.3

66.1

Mar

58.0

53.5

60.2

52.0

66.6

Feb

57.3

52.7

59.0

51.2

63.8

Jan

55.7

52.2

58.2

51.1

65.3

Notes: Interm.: Intermediate; Subs: Subscription; Exp: Business Expectations

Source: National Bureau of Statistics of China

http://www.stats.gov.cn/english/pressrelease/t20120605_402810072.htm

Chart CIPMS provides China’s nonmanufacturing purchasing managers’ index from May 2011 to May 2012. There was slowing of the general index in Apr 2012 after the increase in Jan-Mar 2012 and further decline to 55.2 in May 2012, which is the lowest level since May 2011.

clip_image022

Chart CIPMS, China, Nonmanufacturing Index of Purchasing Managers, Seasonally Adjusted

Source: National Bureau of Statistics of China

http://www.stats.gov.cn/english/pressrelease/t20120605_402810072.htm

China estimates a manufacturing index of purchasing managers on the basis of a sample of 820 enterprises (http://www.stats.gov.cn/english/pressrelease/t20120605_402810071.htm). Chart CIPMM provides the index from May 2011 to May 2012. There is deceleration from 52.0 in May 2011 to marginal contraction at 49.0 in Nov 2011. Manufacturing activity recovered to 53.3 in Apr 2012 but then declined to 50.4 in May 2012, which is the second lowest level in a year, lower than 49.0 in Nov 2011 and equal to 50.4 in Oct 2011, and close to the contraction zone at 50.0.

clip_image023

Chart CIPMM, China, Manufacturing Index of Purchasing Managers, Seasonally Adjusted

Source: National Bureau of Statistics of China

http://www.stats.gov.cn/english/pressrelease/t20120605_402810072.htm

The HSBC China Services PMI, compiled by Markit, improving business activity in China with the HSBC Composite Output, combining manufacturing and services, increasing from 51.4 in Apr to 51.9 in May for a second consecutive month above 50.0 (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9620). Hongbin Qu, Chief Economist, China and Co-Head of Asian Economic Research at HSBC, finds improving activity in services resulting from continuing gains in new business (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9620

).The HSBC Purchasing Managers’ Index (PMI), compiled by Markit, fell slightly to 48.4 in May from 49.3 in Feb, in a seventh consecutive month of declining conditions in manufacturing in China but at a marginal rate (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9613). The index for the first quarter of 2012 was the weakest since IQ2009. Hongbin Qu, Chief Economist, China and Co-Head of Asian Economic Research at HSBC, finds continuing slowdown in China’s economy into IIQ2012, which requires further reduction of bank reserve requirements and the policy interest rate together with fiscal measures (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9613).

Wang Xiaotian, writing on China Daily, on “China cuts its reserve ratio again,” published by Xinhuanet on May 13, 2012 (http://news.xinhuanet.com/english/china/2012-05/13/c_131584252.htm), informs that the People’s Bank of China (PBC) (http://www.pbc.gov.cn/publish/english/963/index.html) reduced the reserve requirement imposed on Chinese lenders by 50 basis points with the objective of injecting liquidity to strengthen the economy. This is the second such reduction of reserve requirements in 2012. The reduction is estimated to release CNY 400 in China’s money market. The reserve requirement will be 20 percent for larger banks and 16.5 percent for smaller banks. On Jun 8, 2012, the People’s Bank of China lowered the one year benchmark deposit and loan interest rates by 25 basis points (http://www.pbc.gov.cn/publish/english/955/2012/20120608171005950734495/20120608171005950734495_.html). The measures are intended to strengthen the economy. Table CNY provides the country data table for China.

Table CNY, China, Economic Indicators

Price Indexes for Industry

May 12-month ∆%: minus 1.4

May month ∆%: minus 0.4
Blog 6/17/12

Consumer Price Index

May month ∆%: -0.2 May 12 month ∆%: 3.0
Blog 6/17/12

Value Added of Industry

May month ∆%: 0.89

Jan-May 2012/Jan-May 2011 ∆%: 10.7
Blog 6/17/12

GDP Growth Rate

Year IQ2012 ∆%: 8.1
Quarter IQ2012 ∆%: 1.8
Blog 4/15/12

Investment in Fixed Assets

Total Jan-May 2012 ∆%: 20.1

Real estate development: 18.5
Blog 6/17/12

Retail Sales

May month ∆%: 0.84
May 12 month ∆%: 13.8

Jan-May ∆%: 14.5
Blog 6/17/12

Trade Balance

May balance $18.7 billion
Exports ∆% 15.3
Imports ∆% 12.7

Cumulative May: $37.9 billion
Blog 6/17/12

Links to blog comments in Table CNY:

4/15/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/04/fractured-labor-market-with-hiring_15.html

Cumulative and 12-months rates of value added of industry in China are provided in Table VC-1. Value added in total industry in Jan-May 2012 increased 10.7 percent relative to a year earlier and 9.6 percent in the 12 months ending in May. Heavy industry had been the driver of growth with a cumulative rate of 11.0 percent relative to a year earlier in Mar that declined to 10.5 percent in Jan-Apr 2012 relative to the same period a year earlier and further down to 10.3 percent in Jan-May. Light industry grew 11.5 percent in Jan-May 2012 relative to a year earlier and 9.1 percent in 12 months ending in May. Growth of total industry has decelerated from cumulative 14.4 percent in Jan-Mar 2011 to 10.7 percent in Jan-May 2012.

Table VC-1, China, Growth Rate of Value Added of Industry ∆%

 

Industry

Light Industry

Heavy
Industry

State
Owned

Private

2012

         

Jan-May

10.7

11.5

10.3

6.7

12.4

12 M May

9.6

9.1

9.8

6.6

11.0

Jan-Apr

11.0

12.3

10.5

6.6

12.9

12 M Apr

9.3

10.3

8.9

4.3

10.7

Jan-Mar

11.6

13.2

11.0

7.2

13.8

12 M Mar

11.9

13.9

11.2

8.0

13.7

Jan-Feb

11.4

12.7

10.9

7.3

13.9

2011

         

Jan-Dec

13.9

13.0

14.3

9.9

15.8

12 M Dec

12.8

12.6

13.0

9.2

14.7

Jan-Nov

14.0

13.0

14.4

9.9

16.0

12 M Nov

12.4

12.4

12.4

7.8

14.4

Jan-Oct

14.1

13.0

14.5

10.1

9.1

12 M Oct

13.2

12.1

13.7

8.9

15.1

Jan-Sep

14.2

13.1

14.6

10.4

16.1

12 M Sep

13.8

12.8

14.3

9.9

16.0

Jan-Aug

14.2

13.1

14.6

10.4

16.1

12 M Aug

13.5

13.4

13.5

9.4

15.5

Jan-Jul

14.3

       

12 M
Jul

14.0

12.8

14.5

9.5

 

Jan-Jun

14.3

13.1

14.7

10.7

19.7

12 M
Jun

15.1

13.9

15.6

10.7

20.8

Jan-May

14.0

12.9

14.4

10.7

19.3

12 M May

13.3

12.9

13.5

8.9

18.7

Jan-Apr

14.2

12.9

14.7

11.2

19.5

12 M Apr

13.4

11.9

14.0

10.4

18.0

Jan-Mar

14.4

13.1

14.9

11.4

19.8

12 M Mar

14.8

12.8

15.6

12.9

19.2

12 M Feb

14.9

13.1

15.6

10.5

21.7

Jan-Feb

14.1

13.3

14.4

10.6

20.3

Source: National Bureau of Statistics of China

http://www.stats.gov.cn/english/pressrelease/t20120611_402811200.htm

Chart VC-1 provides 12-month percentage changes of value added of industry in 2011 and Jan-May 2012. Growth rates of value added of industry in the first five months of 2010 were higher than in 2011 as would be expected in an earlier phase of recovery from the global recession. Growth rates have converged in the second half of 2011 to lower percentages with further decline into 2012.

clip_image024

Chart VC-1, China, Growth Rate of Total Value Added of Industry, 12-Month ∆%

Source: National Bureau of Statistics of China

http://www.stats.gov.cn/english/pressrelease/t20120611_402811200.htm

Yearly rates of growth for the past 12 months and cumulative relative to the earlier year of various segments of industrial production in China are provided in Table VC-2. Rates for Jan-Dec 2011 relative to the same period a year earlier fluctuated but remained mostly above 10 percent with the exception of motor vehicles and crude oil. There is deceleration in Jan-May of percentage change with no segment showing growth exceeding 10 percent with exception of 10.7 percent for motor vehicles in the 12 months ending Apr 2012 and 18.5 percent in the 12 months ending in May.

Table VC-2, China, Industrial Production Operation ∆%

 

Elec-
tricity

Pig Iron

Cement

Crude
Oil

Non-
ferrous
Metals

Motor Vehicles

2012

           

Jan-May

4.7

6.3

5.0

2.2

5.1

6.2

12 M May

2.7

6.3

4.3

0.7

6.6

18.5

Jan-Apr

5.0

6.2

5.5

2.9

4.6

3.1

12 M Apr

0.7

7.9

4.9

-0.3

2.3

10.7

Jan-Mar

7.1

6.5

7.3

3.1

5.8

0.0

12 M Mar

7.2

10.2

7.9

2.0

3.3

5.1

Jan-Feb

7.1

4.6

4.8

4.0

8.4

-1.8

2011

           

Jan-Dec

12.0

8.4

16.1

4.9

10.6

3.0

12 M Dec

9.7

3.7

7.0

4.0

13.2

-6.5

Jan-Nov

12.0

13.1

17.2

5.3

10.2

3.9

12 M Nov

8.5

7.8

11.2

3.2

8.2

-1.3

Jan-Oct

12.3

13.7

18.0

5.4

10.4

5.2

12 M
Oct

9.3

13.4

16.5

-0.9

3.7

1.3

Jan-Sep

12.7

13.9

18.1

6.0

11.2

5.5

12 M Sep

11.5

18.8

15.7

1.5

13.9

2.5

Jan-Aug

13.0

13.1

18.4

6.6

 

4.7

12 M Aug

10.0

12.9

12.8

4.5

15.6

9.5

Jan-Jul

13.3

13.0

19.2

6.9

9.9

4.0

12 M
Jul

13.2

14.9

16.8

5.9

9.8

-1.3

12 M
Jun

16.2

14.8

19.9

-0.7

9.8

3.6

12 M
May

12.1

10.6

19.2

6.0

14.2

-1.9

12 M Apr

11.7

8.3

22.4

6.8

6.1

-1.6

12 M Mar

14.8

13.7

29.8

8.0

11.6

9.9

12 M Feb

11.7

14.5

9.1

10.9

14.4

10.3

12 M Jan

5.1

3.5

16.4

12.2

1.4

23.9

12 M Dec 2010

5.6

4.6

17.3

10.3

-1.9

27.6

M: month

Source: National Bureau of Statistics of China

http://www.stats.gov.cn/english/pressrelease/t20120611_402811200.htm

Monthly growth rates of industrial production in China are provided in Table VC-3. Monthly rates have fluctuated around 1 percent. Jan and Feb 2012 are somewhat weaker but there was improvement to 1.19 percent in Mar. The rate of 0.36 percent in Apr is the lowest in the monthly series from Feb 2011 to May 2012.

Table VC-3, China, Industrial Production Operation, Month ∆%

2011

Month ∆%

Feb

0.93

Mar

0.99

Apr

1.32

May

0.79

Jun

1.31

Jul

0.75

Aug

0.84

Sep

1.01

Oct

0.76

Nov

0.75

Dec

0.97

Jan 2012

0.49

Feb

0.64

Mar

1.19

Apr

0.36

May

0.89

Source: National Bureau of Statistics of China http://www.stats.gov.cn/english/pressrelease/t20120611_402811200.htm

Table VC-4 provides cumulative growth of investment in fixed assets in China in 2011 relative to 2010 and in Jan-May 2012 relative to a year earlier. Total fixed investment has grown at a high rate fluctuating around 25 percent and fixed investment in real estate development has grown at rates in excess of 30 percent. In Jan-May 2012 investment in fixed assets in China grew 20.1 percent relative to a year earlier and 18.5 percent in real estate development. There was slight deceleration in the final two months of 2011 that continued into Jan-May 2012.

Table VC-4, China, Investment in Fixed Assets ∆% Relative to a Year Earlier

 

Total

State

Real Estate Development

Jan-May 2012

20.1

10.0

18.5

Jan-Apr

20.2

9.5

18.7

Jan-Mar

20.9

9.0

23.5

Jan-Feb

21.5

8.8

27.8

Jan-Dec 2011

23.8

11.1

27.9

Jan-Nov

24.5

11.7

29.9

Jan-Oct

24.9

12.4

31.1

Jan-Sep

24.9

12.7

32.0

Jan-Aug

25.0

12.1

33.2

Jan-Jul

25.4

13.6

33.6

Jan-Jun

25.6

14.6

32.9

Jan-May

25.8

14.9

34.6

Jan-Apr

25.4

16.6

34.3

Jan-Mar

25.0

17.0

34.1

Jan-Feb

24.9

15.6

35.2

Source: National Bureau of Statistics of China

http://www.stats.gov.cn/english/pressrelease/t20120612_402811367.htm

http://www.stats.gov.cn/english/pressrelease/t20120612_402811457.htm

Chart VC-2 provides cumulative fixed asset investment in China relative to a year earlier. Growth rose to 25.8 percent in Jan-May 2011 and then fell back to 24.9 percent in Sep and Oct, declining further to 24.5 percent in Nov and 23.8 percent in Dec with deeper drop in Jan-Feb 2012 to 21.5 percent, 20.9 percent in Jan-Mar, 20.2 percent in Jan-Apr 2012 and 20.1 percent in Jan-Apr 2012.

clip_image025

Chart VC-2, China, Investment in Fixed Assets, ∆% Cumulative over Year Earlier

Source: National Bureau of Statistics of China

http://www.stats.gov.cn/english/pressrelease/t20120612_402811367.htm

Monetary policy has been used in China in the form of increases in interest rates and required reserves of banks to moderate real estate investment. These policies have been reversed because of lower inflation and weakening economic growth. Chart VC-3 shows decline of fluctuating cumulative growth rates of investment in real estate development relative to a year earlier from 35.2 percent in Jan-Feb 2011 to 31.1 percent in Jan-Oct 2011, 29.9 percent in Jan-Nov 2011, 27.9 percent in Jan-Dec 2011, 27.8 percent in Jan-Feb 2012 and sharper decline to 23.5 percent in Jan-Mar 2012, 18.7 percent in Jan-Apr 2012 and 18.5 percent in Jan-May 2012.

clip_image026

Chart VC-3, China, Investment in Real Estate Development, ∆% Cumulative over Year Earlier

Source: National Bureau of Statistics of China

http://www.stats.gov.cn/english/pressrelease/t20120612_402811457.htm

Table VC-5 provides monthly growth rates of investment in fixed assets in China from Feb 2011 to May 2012. Growth rates moderated from Nov 2011 to May 2012. The rate of 0.92 percent in Apr 2012 is the lowest for any month after Mar 2011.

Table VC-5, China, Investment in Fixed Assets, Month ∆%

 

Month ∆%

Feb 2011

-0.23

Mar

2.45

Apr

2.22

May

1.68

Jun

1.59

Jul

1.52

Aug

1.43

Sep

1.92

Oct

1.82

Nov

1.10

Dec

1.45

Jan 2012

1.16

Feb

1.57

Mar

1.73

Apr

0.92

May

1.15

Source: National Bureau of Statistics of China

http://www.stats.gov.cn/english/pressrelease/t20120612_402811367.htm

Growth rates of retail sales in China monthly, 12 months and cumulative relative to a year earlier are in Table VC-6. There is still insufficient data to assess if the decline of growth rates to cumulative 14.7 percent in Feb 2012, 14.8 percent in Mar, 14.7 percent in Apr and 14.5 percent in May constitutes the beginning of a downward trend but rates have declined in Jan-May 2012 relative to earlier months.

Table VC-6, China, Total Retail Sales of Consumer Goods ∆%

 

Month ∆%

12-Month ∆%

Cumulative ∆%/
Cumulative
Year Earlier

2012

     

May

0.84

13.8

14.5

Apr

0.96

14.1

14.7

Mar

1.21

15.2

14.8

Feb

1.29

14.7

14.7

Jan

0.78

   

2011

     

Dec

1.65

18.1

17.1

Nov

1.42

17.3

17.0

Oct

1.43

17.2

17.0

Sep

1.51

17.7

17.0

Aug

1.42

17.0

16.9

Jul

1.33

17.2

16.8

Jun

1.50

17.7

16.8

May

1.39

16.9

16.6

Apr

1.30

17.1

16.5

Mar

1.26

17.4

17.4

Feb

1.35

11.6

15.8

Jan

 

19.9

19.9

Note: there are slight revisions of month relative to earlier month data but not of the month on the same month year earlier or cumulative relative to cumulative year earlier in the databank

Source: http://www.stats.gov.cn/english/pressrelease/t20120612_402811459.htm

Chart VC-4 of the National Bureau of Statistics of China provides 12-month rates of growth of retail sales in 2011. There is again a drop into 2012 with the lowest percentages in Chart VC-4.

clip_image027

Chart VC-4, China, Total Retail Sales of Consumer Goods 12-Month ∆%

Source: National Bureau of Statistics of China

http://www.stats.gov.cn/english/pressrelease/t20120612_402811459.htm

Table VC-7 provides monthly percentage changes of retail sales in China. Although the rate of 0.78 percent in Jan 2012 is the lowest in Table VC-7, the rate of 1.29 percent in Feb is relatively high and 1.21 percent in Mar is also relatively low followed by lower 0.96 percent in Apr and 0.84 percent in May.

Table VC-7, China, Retail Sales, Month ∆%

2011

Month ∆%

Feb

1.35

Mar

1.26

Apr

1.30

May

1.39

Jun

1.50

Jul

1.33

Aug

1.42

Sep

1.51

Oct

1.43

Nov

1.42

Dec

1.65

2012

 

Jan

0.78

Feb

1.29

Mar

1.21

Apr

0.96

May

0.84

Source: National Bureau of Statistics of China

http://www.stats.gov.cn/english/pressrelease/t20120612_402811459.htm

Table VC-8 provides China’s exports, imports, trade balance and percentage changes from Dec 2010 to May 2012. The rate of growth of exports fell to 4.9 percent in Apr 2012 relative to a year earlier and imports increased 0.3 percent but export growth was 15.3 percent in May and imports increased 12.7 percent. China reversed the large trade deficit of USD 31.48 billion in Feb 2012 with a surplus of $5.35 billion in Mar 2012, $18.42 billion in Apr 2012 and $18.7 billion in May 2012. Exports fell 0.5 percent in the 12 months ending in Jan while imports fell 15.3 percent for a still sizeable trade surplus of $27.28 billion. In Feb, exports increased 18.4 percent while imports jumped 39.6 percent for a sizeable deficit of $31.48 billion. There are distortions from the New Year holidays.

Table VC-8, China, Exports, Imports and Trade Balance USD Billion and ∆%

 

Exports
USD
Billion

∆% Relative
Year Earlier

Imports USD
Billion

∆% Relative
Year Earlier

Balance
USD
Billion

May 2012

181.1

15.3

162.4

12.7

18.7

Apr

163.25

4.9

144.83

0.3

18.42

Mar

165.66

8.9

160.31

5.4

5.35

Feb

114.47

18.4

145.95

39.6

-31.48

Jan

149.94

-0.5

122.66

-15.3

27.28

Dec 2011

174.72

13.4

158.20

11.8

16.52

Nov

174.46

13.8

159.94

22.1

14.53

Oct

157.49

15.9

140.46

28.7

17.03

Sep

169.67

17.1

155.16

20.9

14.51

Aug

173.32

24.5

155.56

30.2

17.76

Jul

175.13

20.4

143.64

22.9

31.48

Jun

161.98

17.9

139.71

19.3

22.27

May

157.16

19.4

144.11

28.4

13.05

Apr

155.69

29.9

144.26

21.8

11.42

Mar

152.20

35.8

152.06

27.3

0.14

Feb

96.74

2.4

104.04

19.4

-7.31

Jan

150.73

37.7

144.27

51.0

6.46

Dec 2010

154.15

17.9

141.07

25.6

13.08

Source:

http://english.customs.gov.cn/publish/portal191/

http://english.mofcom.gov.cn/static/column/statistic/BriefStatistics.html/1

Table VC-9 provides cumulative exports, imports and the trade balance of China together with percentage growth of exports and imports. The trade balance in 2011 of $155.14 billion is lower than those from 2008 to 2010. There is a rare cumulative deficit of $4.2 billion in Feb 2012 reversed to a small surplus in Mar 2012 and a higher surplus of $19.3 billion in Apr 2012, increasing to $37.9 billion in May. More observations are required to detect trends of Chinese trade.

Table VC-9, China, Year to Date Exports, Imports and Trade Balance USD Billion and ∆%

 

Exports
USD
Billion

∆% Relative
Year Earlier

Imports USD
Billion

∆% Relative
Year Earlier

Balance
USD
Billion

May 2012

774.4

8.7

736.5

6.7

37.9

Apr

593.24

6.9

573.94

5.1

19.3

Mar

430.06

7.6

428.95

6.9

1.11

Feb

264.40

6.9

268.64

7.7

-4.24

Jan

149.94

-0.5

122.66

-15.3

27.28

Dec 2011

1,898.60

20.3

1,743.46

24.9

155.14

Nov

1,724.01

21.1

1585.61

26.4

138.40

Oct

1,549.71

22.0

1,425.68

26.9

124.03

Sep

1,392.27

22.7

1,285.17

26.7

107.10

Aug

1,222.63

23.6

1,129.90

27.5

92.73

Jul

1,049.38

23.4

973.17

26.9

76.21

Jun

874.3

24.0

829.37

27.6

44.93

May

712.37

25.5

689.41

29.4

22.96

Apr

555.30

27.4

545.02

29.6

10.28

Mar

399.64

26.5

400.66

32.6

-1.02

Feb

247.47

21.3

248.36

36.0

-0.89

Jan

150.7

37.7

144.27

51.0

6.46

Dec 2010

1577.93

31.3

1394.83

38.7

183.10

Source:

http://english.customs.gov.cn/publish/portal191/

http://english.mofcom.gov.cn/static/column/statistic/BriefStatistics.html/1

VD Euro Area. Table VD-EUR provides inflation, unemployment and real GDP growth in the euro area yearly from 1999 to 2011 together with growth forecasts of EUROSTAT for 2012 and 2013. Inflation in the euro zone remained subdued around 2 percent in the first five years of the euro zone from 1999 to 2004, as shown in Table VD-EUR. Inflation climbed above 2.0 percent after 2005, peaking at 3.3 percent in 2008 with the surge in commodity prices but falling to 0.3 percent in 2009 with the collapse of commodity prices. Inflation climbed back to 1.6 percent in 2010 and 2.7 percent in 2011. Under the regime of zero interest rates inflation returns worldwide during relaxation of risk aversion. The rate of unemployment increased in 2011 while the rate of GDP growth fell. EUROSTAT forecasts slightly negative growth of 0.3 percent in 2012 and growth of 1.0 percent in 2013.

Table VD-EUR, Euro Area, Yearly Percentage Change of Harmonized Index of Consumer Prices, ∆%

Year

HICP ∆%

Unemployment
%

GDP ∆%

1999

1.2

9.6

2.9

2000

2.2

8.7

3.8

2001

2.4

8.1

2.0

2002

2.3

8.5

0.9

2003

2.1

9.0

0.7

2004

2.2

9.3

2.2

2005

2.2

9.2

1.7

2006

2.2

8.5

3.3

2007

2.1

7.6

3.0

2008

3.3

7.6

0.4

2009

0.3

9.6

-4.4

2010

1.6

10.1

2.0

2011

2.7

10.2

1.5

2012*

   

-0.3

2013*

   

1.0

*EUROSTAT forecast

http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page/portal/statistics/search_database

The Markit Eurozone PMI® Composite Output Index, combining services and manufacturing activity with close association with GDP, fell from 46.7 in Apr to 46.0 in May (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9638) in the deepest contraction since the Jun 2009. Chris Williamson, Chief Economist at Markit, finds that the data are consistent with decline of GDP at a quarterly rate of 0.5 percent IIQ2012 but even higher depending on data for Jun, which could result in the third consecutive quarterly contraction of euro area GDP (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9638). The Markit Eurozone Manufacturing PMI® declined close to a three-year low at 45.1 in May from 45.9 in Apr in ten consecutive monthly readings of contraction (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9460). Chris Williamson, Chief Economist at Markit, finds that the index suggests manufacturing in the euro area in May declined at a quarterly rate of about 1 percent, exerting pressure on GDP in IIQ2012 (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9460). Table EUR provides the regional data table for the euro area.

Table EUR, Euro Area Economic Indicators

GDP

IQ2012 ∆% 0.0; IQ2012/IQ2011 ∆% -0.1 Blog 6/10/12

Unemployment 

Apr 2012: 11.0% unemployment rate

Apr 2012: 17.405 million unemployed

Blog 6/3/12

HICP

May month ∆%: -0.1

12 months May ∆%: 2.4
Blog 6/17/12

Producer Prices

Euro Zone industrial producer prices Apr ∆%: 0.0
Apr 12-month ∆%: 2.6
Blog 6/3/12

Industrial Production

Apr month ∆%: -0.8; Apr 12 months ∆%: -2.3
Blog 6/17/12

Retail Sales

Apr month ∆%: -1.0
Apr 12 months ∆%: -2.5
Blog 6/10/12

Confidence and Economic Sentiment Indicator

Sentiment 90.6 May 2012

Confidence minus 19.3 May 2012

Blog 6/3/12

Trade

Jan-Apr 2012/Jan-Apr 2011 Exports ∆%: 7.9
Imports ∆%: 2.6

Apr 2012 12-month Exports ∆% 6.1 Imports ∆% -0.9
Blog 6/17/12

Links to blog comments in Table EUR:

6/10/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/rules-versus-discretionary-authorities_10.html

6/3/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/mediocre-recovery-without-jobs_04.html

Industrial production in the euro area decreased 0.8 percent in Apr 2012, declining in five of six months from Nov 2011 to Apr 2012, as shown in Table VD-1 with revised estimates by EUROSTAT. Energy was the only segment increasing in Apr. Improved weather caused decline of energy by 8.1 percent in Mar that drove down the rate of growth of total industry to minus 0.1 percent. All segments of industrial production fell in Dec with exception of no change in nondurable goods and 0.8 percent in energy but all increased in Jan with exception of declines of capital goods by 1.0 percent and nondurable goods by 0.6 percent. Industrial production is highly volatile in the euro zone.

Table VD-1, Euro Zone, Industrial Production Month ∆%

 

Total

INT

ENE

CG

DUR

NDUR

Apr 2012

-0.8

-1.2

6.9

-2.6

-0.9

-1.6

Mar

-0.1

1.0

-8.1

1.2

0.0

1.5

Feb

0.7

-1.3

7.7

1.2

-1.6

-1.3

Jan

-0.2

0.7

0.8

-1.0

0.0

-0.6

Dec 2011

-0.8

-1.0

-2.8

-0.3

0.2

0.0

Nov

-0.4

-0.1

0.2

0.1

0.3

-1.6

Notes: INT: Intermediate; ENE: Energy; CG: Capital Goods; DUR: Durable Consumer Goods; NDUR: Nondurable Consumer Goods

Source: Eurostat

http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/cache/ITY_PUBLIC/4-13062012-AP/EN/4-13062012-AP-EN.PDF

Table VD-2 provides monthly and 12-month percentage changes of industrial production and major industrial categories in the euro zone. Industrial production decreased 2.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr. There is only positive 12-month growth of 3.3 percent for energy. With the exception of energy, increasing 6.9 percent, all segments registered decreases in Apr 2012.

Table VD-2, Euro Zone, Industrial Production 12-Month ∆%

2012

Apr Month ∆%

Apr 12-Month ∆%

Total

-0.8

-2.3

Intermediate Goods

-1.2

-4.5

Energy

6.9

3.3

Capital Goods

-2.6

-0.3

Durable Consumer Goods

-0.9

-6.2

Nondurable Consumer Goods

-1.6

-3.4

Source: Eurostat

http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/cache/ITY_PUBLIC/4-13062012-AP/EN/4-13062012-AP-EN.PDF

There has been significant decline in percentage changes of industrial production and major categories in 12-month rates throughout 2011 and into 2012 as shown in Table VD-3. The 12-month rate of growth in Nov 2011 of 0.0 percent has fallen to minus 2.3 percent in Apr 2012. Trend is difficult to identify because of significant volatility. Capital goods were growing at 4.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Nov 2011 and only at minus 0.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr 2012.

Table VD-3, Euro Zone, Industrial Production 12-Month ∆%

 

Total

INT

ENE

CG

DUR

NDUR

Apr 2012

-2.3

-4.5

3.3

-0.3

-6.2

-3.4

Mar

-1.5

-2.6

-6.3

2.9

-6.0

-2.2

Feb

-1.6

-4.4

3.8

1.6

-5.7

-4.7

Jan

-1.8

-1.7

-7.3

1.6

-3.0

-2.0

Dec 2011

-1.6

-0.2

-12.2

2.1

-2.9

-0.4

Nov

0.0

-0.6

-5.4

4.7

-3.1

-1.7

Notes: INT: Intermediate; ENE: Energy; CG: Capital Goods; DUR: Durable Consumer Goods; NDUR: Nondurable Consumer Goods

Source: Eurostat

http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/cache/ITY_PUBLIC/4-13062012-AP/EN/4-13062012-AP-EN.PDF

Blanchard (2011WEOSep) analyzes the difficulty of fiscal consolidation efforts during periods of weak economic growth. Table VD-4 provides monthly and 12-month percentage changes of industrial production in the euro zone for various members and the UK, which is not a member. The only positive growth rates of industrial production in the 12 months ending in Apr 2012 are 2.0 percent for France, 4.7 percent for the Netherlands and 0.2 percent for Ireland.

Table VD-4, Euro Zone, Industrial Production, Month and 12-Month ∆%

 

Month ∆% Apr 2012

Month ∆% Mar 2012

12 Months ∆% Apr 2012

12 Months ∆% Mar 2012

Euro Zone

-0.8

-0.1

-2.3

-1.5

Germany

-2.0

0.9

-0.8

1.4

France

1.5

-1.0

2.0

-1.3

Netherlands

2.9

-9.1

4.7

-3.1

Finland

0.9

-1.1

-2.9

-4.3

Belgium

NA

2.5

NA

-4.1

Portugal

-6.5

3.2

-7.6

-4.6

Ireland

1.8

2.8

0.2

4.4

Italy

-1.9

0.6

-9.2

-5.6

Greece

0.3

-0.5

-2.1

-8.1

Spain

-0.7

-1.9

-8.3

-7.5

UK

0.0

-0.3

-1.7

-1.8

European Union

-0.4

-0.2

-1.7

-1.4

Source: Eurostat

http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/cache/ITY_PUBLIC/4-13062012-AP/EN/4-13062012-AP-EN.PDF

Euro zone trade growth continues to be relatively strong as shown in Table VD-5. Exports grew at 7.9 percent and imports at 2.6 percent in Jan-Apr 2012 relative to Jan-Apr 2011. The 12-month rate of growth of exports was 6.1 percent in Apr 2012 while imports fell 0.9 percent. In Mar 2012, exports increased 4.6 percent in 12 months and imports increased 0.4 percent. At the margin, rates of growth of trade are declining in part because of moderation of commodity prices.

Table VD-5, Euro Zone, Exports, Imports and Trade Balance, Billions of Euros and Percent, NSA

 

Exports

Imports

Jan-Apr 2012

601.2

595.3

Jan-Apr 2011

556.9

580.3

∆%

7.9

2.6

Mar 2012

165.1

157.6

Mar 2011

157.9

157.0

∆%

4.6

0.4

Apr 2012

147.6

142.4

Apr 2011

139.1

143.7

∆%

6.1

-0.9

Trade Balance

Jan-Apr 2012

Jan-Apr 2011

€ Billions

5.9

-23.3

Source: EUROSTAT

http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/cache/ITY_PUBLIC/6-15062012-BP/EN/6-15062012-BP-EN.PDF

The structure of trade of the euro zone in Jan-Mar 2012 is provided in Table VD-6. Data are still not available for trade structure for Mar 2012. Manufactured exports increased 7.3 percent in Jan-Mar 2012 relative to Jan-Mar 2011 while imports fell 1.3 percent. The trade surplus in manufactured products was lower than the trade deficit in primary products in both Jan-Mar 2012 and Jan-Mar 2011.

Table VD-6, Euro Zone, Structure of Exports, Imports and Trade Balance, € Billions, NSA, ∆%

 

Primary

Manufactured

Other

Total

Exports

       

Jan-Mar 2012 € B

70.9

369.6

13.2

453.6

Jan-Mar 2011 € B

62.1

344.6

11.1

417.8

∆%

14.2

7.3

18.9

8.6

Imports

       

Jan-Mar 2012 € B

169.3

275.3

8.2

452.8

Jan-Mar 2011  € B

150.6

279.0

6.9

436.6

∆%

12.4

-1.3

18.8

3.7

Trade Balance

€ B

       

Jan-Mar 2012

-98.4

94.3

4.9

0.8

Jan-Mar 2011

-88.6

65.6

4.2

-18.8

Source: EUROSTAT http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/cache/ITY_PUBLIC/6-15062012-BP/EN/6-15062012-BP-EN.PDF

VE Germany. Table VE-DE provides yearly growth rates of the German economy from 1992 to 2011, price adjusted chain-linked and price and calendar-adjusted chain-linked. Germany’s GDP fell 5.1 percent in 2009 after growing below trend at 1.1 percent in 2008. Recovery has been robust in contrast with other advanced economy. The German economy grew at 3.7 percent in 2010 and at 3.0 percent in 2011. Growth slowed in 2011 from 1.3 percent in IQ2011, 0.3 percent in IIQ2011 and 0.6 percent in IIIQ2011 to decline of 0.2 percent in IVQ2011 and growth of 0.5 percent in IQ2012. The Federal Statistical Agency of Germany analyzes the fall and recovery of the German economy (http://www.destatis.de/jetspeed/portal/cms/Sites/destatis/Internet/EN/Content/Statistics/VolkswirtschaftlicheGesamtrechnungen/Inlandsprodukt/Aktuell,templateId=renderPrint.psml):

“The German economy again grew strongly in 2011. The price-adjusted gross domestic product (GDP) increased by 3.0% compared with the previous year. Accordingly, the catching-up process of the German economy continued during the second year after the economic crisis. In the course of 2011, the price-adjusted GDP again exceeded its pre-crisis level. The economic recovery occurred mainly in the first half of 2011. In 2009, Germany experienced the most serious post-war recession, when GDP suffered a historic decline of 5.1%. The year 2010 was characterised by a rapid economic recovery (+3.7%).”

Table VE-DE, Germany, GDP Year ∆%

 

Price Adjusted Chain-Linked

Price- and Calendar-Adjusted Chain Linked

2011

3.0

3.1

2010

3.7

3.6

2009

-5.1

-5.1

2008

1.1

0.8

2007

3.3

3.4

2006

3.7

3.9

2005

0.7

0.8

2004

1.2

0.7

2003

-0.4

-0.4

2002

0.0

0.0

2001

1.5

1.6

2000

3.1

3.3

1999

1.9

1.8

1998

1.9

1.7

1997

1.7

1.8

1996

0.8

0.8

1995

1.7

1.8

1994

2.5

2.5

1993

-1.0

-1.0

1992

1.9

1.5

Source: Statistiche Bundesamt Deutschland

https://www.destatis.de/EN/PressServices/Press/pr/2012/05/PE12_178_811.html

The Markit Germany Composite Output Index of the Markit Germany Services PMI®, combining manufacturing and services with close association with Germany’s GDP, fell from 50.5 in Apr to 49.3 in May, indicating marginal deterioration in private sector output for the first time in six months and the deepest since Jul 2009 (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9659). Tim Moore, Senior Economist at Markit and author of the report, finds that the index suggests flat GDP in Germany in IIQ2012 (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9659). The Markit/BME Germany Purchasing Managers’ Index® (PMI®), showing close association with Germany’s manufacturing output, fell from 46.2 in Apr to 45.2 in May, indicating the sharpest decline of manufacturing conditions since Jun 2009 (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9626). Tim Moore, Senior Economist at Markit and author of the report, finds that Germany’s manufacturing output is showing the sharpest drop in about three years with contracting orders from export markets (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9626). Table DE provides the country data table for Germany.

Table DE, Germany, Economic Indicators

GDP

IQ2012 0.5 ∆%; I/Q2012/IQ2011 ∆% 1.7

2011/2010: 3.0%

GDP ∆% 1992-2011

Blog 5/27/12

Consumer Price Index

May month SA ∆%: -0.2
May 12-month ∆%: 1.9
Blog 6/17/12

Producer Price Index

Apr month ∆%: 0.2
12-month NSA ∆%: 2.4
Blog 5/20/12

Industrial Production

Mfg Apr month SA ∆%: -0.9
12-month NSA: -2.3
Blog 6/10/12

Machine Orders

Apr month ∆%: -3.7
Apr 12-month ∆%: -1.9
Blog 6/10/12

Retail Sales

Apr Month ∆% 0.6

12-Month ∆% minus 3.8

Blog 6/3/12

Employment Report

Unemployment Rate Mar 5.2%
Blog 6/3/12

Trade Balance

Exports Apr 12-month NSA ∆%: 3.4
Imports Apr 12 months NSA ∆%: -1.0
Exports Apr month SA ∆%: -1.7; Imports Apr month SA -4.8

Blog 6/10/12

Links to blog comments in Table DE:

6/10/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/rules-versus-discretionary-authorities_10.html

6/3/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/mediocre-recovery-without-jobs_04.html

5/27/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/05/world-financial-turbulence-global_27.html

5/20/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/05/world-inflation-waves-monetary-policy_20.html

VF France. The Markit France Composite Output Index, combining services and manufacturing with close association with French GDP, fell from 45.9 in Apr to 44.6 in May, which is the lowest reading in 37 months (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9630). Jack Kennedy, Senior Economist at Markit and author of the France Services PMI®, finds that weak services and manufacturing survey data suggest contraction of GDP in IIQ2012 after no growth in IQ2012 (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9630).The Markit France Manufacturing Purchasing Managers’ Index® fell to 44.7 in May from 46.9 in Apr for the sharpest decline of the manufacturing economy in three years (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9629). Jack Kennedy, Senior Economist at Markit and author of the France Manufacturing PMI®, finds continuing deterioration in manufacturing with the sharpest contraction of new orders since Apr 2009 (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9629). Table FR provides the country data table for France.

Table FR, France, Economic Indicators

CPI

May month ∆% -0.1
12 months ∆%: 2.0
6/17/12

PPI

Apr month ∆%: 0.0
Apr 12 months ∆%: 2.7

Blog 6/3/12

GDP Growth

IQ2012/IVQ2011 ∆%: 0.0
IQ2012/IQ2011 ∆%: 0.0
Blog 5/20/12

Industrial Production

Apr SA ∆%:
Industrial Production 1.5;
Manufacturing -0.7
YOY NSA ∆%:
Industrial Production -0.6;
Manufacturing -1.8
Blog 6/17/12

Consumer Spending

Apr Manufactured Goods
∆%: minus 1.3 Apr 12-Month Manufactured Goods
∆%: minus 1.6
Blog 6/3/12

Employment

IQ2012 Unemployed 2.746 million
Unemployment Rate: 9.6%
Employment Rate: 63.8%
Blog 6/10/12

Trade Balance

Apr Exports ∆%: month 1.8, 12 months 7.4

Apr Imports ∆%: month 2.1, 12 months 3.4

Blog 6/10/12

Confidence Indicators

Historical averages 100

May Mfg Business Climate 93

Blog 5/27/12

Links to blog comments in Table FR:

6/10/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/rules versus-discretionary-authorities_10.html

6/3/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/mediocre-recovery-without-jobs_04.html

5/27/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/05/world-financial-turbulence-global_27.html

5/20/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/05/world-inflation-waves-monetary-policy_20.html

France’s industrial production by segments is provided in Table VF-1. Total industry increased 1.5 percent in Apr after decreasing 1.0 percent in Mar. Construction increased 2.3 percent in Apr after increasing 17.1 percent in Mar. Mining increased 16.6 in Apr after falling 15.0 percent in Mar. There were declines for all categories relative to the same quarter a year earlier with exception of growth of mining by 7.6 percent.

Table VF-1, France, Industrial Production ∆%

2011-2012

Apr/Mar

Mar/Feb

QOQ

YOY

Industry

1.5

-1.0

0.4

-0.6

Manufacturing

-0.7

1.4

-0.7

-1.8

Mining, Quarrying, Energy, Water, Waste Mgt

16.6

-15.0

7.4

7.6

Construction

2.3

17.1

-5.0

-3.9

Note: QOQ: quarter on quarter; YOY:most recent quarter on the same quarter a year earlier

Source: Institut National de la Statistique et des Études Économiques

http://www.insee.fr/en/themes/info-rapide.asp?id=10&date=20120611

Table VF-2 provides longer historical perspective of manufacturing in France. The decline of manufacturing in Apr by 0.7 percent pulled down to 12-month percentage change to minus 1.4 percent. In contrast, the increase of 1.4 percent in manufacturing in Mar 2012 reduced the decline in 12 months to minus 0.4 percent. In the quarter Dec 2011 to Feb 2012, manufacturing fell 2.4 at the annual equivalent rate of minus 9.2 percent. There is strength earlier in the recovery in 2010 and early 2011 with less strong performance in the latter part of 2011. Manufacturing fell 12.9 percent in 2008 during the global contraction and an additional 2.8 percent in 2009.

Table VF-2, France, Manufacturing, Month and 12-Month ∆%

 

Month ∆%

12-Month ∆%

Apr 2012

-0.7

-1.4

Mar

1.4

-0.4

Feb

-0.9

-3.4

Jan

-0.1

-1.8

Dec 2011

-1.4

0.6

Nov

1.2

2.1

Oct

0.2

2.8

Sep

-2.2

1.8

Aug

0.4

4.8

Jul

1.6

4.0

Jun

-1.9

3.3

May

1.0

4.0

Apr

0.3

3.6

Mar

-1.6

4.3

Feb

0.8

7.5

Jan

2.3

6.7

Dec 2010

0.1

5.1

Dec 2009

 

-2.8

Dec 2008

 

-12.9

Dec 2007

 

-0.2

Dec 2006

 

2.3

Dec 2005

 

0.0

Dec 2004

 

1.4

Dec 2003

 

0.4

Dec 2002

 

-0.5

Dec 2001

 

-4.9

Dec 2000

 

5.2

Annual

   

Average ∆% 1990-2000

 

1.1

Source:

Institut National de la Statistique et des Études Économiques

http://www.insee.fr/en/themes/info-rapide.asp?id=10&date=20120611

Chart VF-1 of France’s Institut National de la Statistique et des Études Économiques shows indices of manufacturing in France from 2008 to 2012. Manufacturing, which is CZ in Chart VF-1, fell deeply in 2008 and part of 2009. All curves of industrial indices tend to flatten recently with oscillations.

clip_image029

Chart VF-1, France, Industrial Production Indices 2007-2011

Legend : CZ : Manufacturing - (C1) : Manufacture of food products and beverages - (C3) : Electrical and electronic equipment; machine equipment - (C4) : Manufacture of transport equipment - (C5) : Other manufacturing

Source: Institut National de la Statistique et des Études Économiques

http://www.insee.fr/en/themes/info-rapide.asp?id=10&date=20120611

VG Italy. The Markit/ADACI Business Activity Index increased from 42.3 in Apr to 42.8 in May, indicating sharp contraction of output of Italy’s services sector in 12 consecutive months of contraction (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9651). Phil Smith, economist at Markit and author of the Italy Services PMI®, finds that the combined manufacturing and services indexes suggest continuing recession into IIQ2012 (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9651). The Markit/ADACI Purchasing Managers’ Index® (PMI®), increased from 43.8 in Apr to 44.8 in May for a tenth consecutive month of contraction of Italy’s manufacturing and the sharpest since Oct (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9615). Phil Smith, economist at Markit and author of the Italian Manufacturing PMI®, finds continuing sharp contraction of new orders of manufacturing in Italy (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9615). Table IT provides the country data table for Italy.

Table IT, Italy, Economic Indicators

Consumer Price Index

May month ∆%: 0.0
May 12-month ∆%: 3.2
Blog 6/17/12

Producer Price Index

Apr month ∆%: 0.3
Apr 12-month ∆%: 2.5

Blog 6/3/12

GDP Growth

IQ2012/IVQ2011 SA ∆%: minus 0.8
IQ2012/IQ2011 NSA ∆%: minus 1.4
Blog 6/17/12

Labor Report

Apr 2012

Participation rate 63.4%

Employment ratio 57.0%

Unemployment rate 10.2%

Blog 6/3/12

Industrial Production

Apr month ∆%: -1.9
12 months ∆%: minus 9.2
Blog 6/10/12

Retail Sales

Mar month ∆%: -0.2

Mar 12-month ∆%: 1.7

Blog 5/27/12

Business Confidence

Mfg May 86.2, Jan 91.3

Construction Apr 81.9, Jan 82.8

Blog 6/3/12

Consumer Confidence

Consumer Confidence May 86.5, Apr 88.8

Economy May 64.4, Apr 71.6

Blog 5/27/12

Trade Balance

Balance Apr SA -€36 million versus Mar +€714
Exports Apr month SA ∆%: 0.2; Imports Apr month ∆%: 2.5
Exports 12 months NSA ∆%: -1.7 Imports 12 months NSA ∆%: minus 9.3
Blog 6/17/12

Links to blog comments in Table IT:

6/10/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/rules-versus-discretionary-authorities_10.html

6/3/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/mediocre-recovery-without-jobs_04.html

5/27/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/05/world-financial-turbulence-global_27.html

Table VG-1 provides revised percentage changes of GDP in Italy of quarter on prior quarter and quarter on same quarter a year earlier. Italy’s GDP fell 0.8 percent in IQ2012 and declined revised 1.4 percent relative to IQ2011. GDP had been growing during six consecutive quarters but at very low rates from IQ2010 to IIQ2011 but has fallen in three consecutive quarters from IIIQ2011 to IQ2012 at increasingly higher rates of contraction from 0.2 percent in IIIQ2011 to 0.7 percent in IVQ2011 and 0.8 percent in IQ2012. The yearly rate has fallen from 2.3 percent in IVQ2010 to minus 1.4 percent in IQ2012. The fiscal adjustment of Italy is significantly more difficult with the economy not growing especially on the prospects of increasing government revenue. The strategy is for reforms to improve productivity so as to facilitate future fiscal consolidation.

Table VG-1, Italy, GDP ∆%

 

Quarter ∆% Relative to Preceding Quarter

Quarter ∆% Relative to Same Quarter Year Earlier

IQ2012

-0.8

-1.4

IVQ2011

-0.7

-0.5

IIIQ2011

-0.2

0.4

IIQ2011

0.3

1.0

IQ2011

0.1

1.3

IVQ2010

0.2

2.3

IIIQ2010

0.4

1.9

IIQ2010

0.5

1.8

IQ2010

1.0

1.1

IVQ2009

-0.2

-3.5

IIIQ2009

0.4

-5.1

IIQ2009

-0.2

-6.5

IQ2009

-3.5

-6.9

IVQ2008

-1.8

-3.0

IIIQ2008

-1.1

-1.8

IIQ2008

-0.6

-0.3

IQ2008

0.5

0.4

IV2007

-0.4

0.1

IIIQ2007

0.3

1.7

IIQ2007

0.2

2.0

IQ2007

0.0

2.4

Source: Istituto Nazionale di Statistica

http://www.istat.it/it/archivio/64548

Chart VG-1 of the Italian National Institute of Statistics (ISTAT) provides growth of GDP of Italy at market prices. The year on year rate of growth pulled strongly out of the contraction. There is an evident trend of deceleration with increasingly sharper contraction.

clip_image030

Chart VG-1, Italy, GDP at Market Prices, ∆% on Same Quarter Year Earlier

Source: Istituto Nazionale di Statistica

http://www.istat.it/en/

Exports and imports of Italy and monthly growth rates SA are provided in Table VG-2. There have been significant fluctuations. Seasonally-adjusted exports increased 0.2 percent in Apr 2012 while imports increased 2.5 percent. The SA trade balance deteriorated from surplus of €714 million in Mar to deficit of €36 million in Apr 2012.

Table VG-2, Italy, Exports, Imports and Trade Balance SA Million Euros and Month SA ∆%

 

Exports

€ M

Exports
Month ∆%

Imports

€ M

Imports
Month ∆%

Balance

€ M

Apr 2012

32,435

0.2

32,471

2.5

-36

Mar

32,383

1.7

31,669

-2.1

714

Feb

31,835

0.0

32,350

0.5

-515

Jan

31,849

-2.8

32,184

-0.4

-335

Dec 2011

32,756

3.9

32,313

-1.6

443

Nov

31,531

1.6

32,823

0.8

-1,292

Oct

31,028

-2.8

32,566

-1.8

-1,538

Sep

31,923

0.1

33,159

-3.8

-1,236

Aug

31,889

0.9

34,457

2.5

-2,568

Jul

31,595

1.0

33,622

2.8

-2,027

Jun

31,273

-2.4

32,697

-5.8

-1,424

May

32,055

1.9

34,698

1.3

-2,643

Apr

31,471

1.1

34,262

-2.0

-2,791

Mar

31,122

2.1

34,960

5.5

-3,838

Feb

30,496

-1.8

33,153

-1.8

-2,657

Jan

31,068

4.9

33,756

1.1

-2,688

Dec 2010

29,630

1.5

33,398

2.9

-3,768

Source: Istituto Nazionale di Statistica http://www.istat.it/it/archivio/64824

Italy’s trade not seasonally adjusted is provided in Table VG-3. Values are different because the data are original and not adjusted. Exports fell 1.7 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr 2012 while imports decreased 9.3 percent. Twelve-month rates of growth picked up again in Aug 2011 with 14.9 percent for exports and 12.1 percent for imports. In Sep, exports grew 10.2 percent relative to a year earlier while imports grew only 3.6 percent. In Oct, exports grew 4.5 percent while imports fell 0.4 percent. In Nov, exports grew 6.5 percent in 12 months while imports grew 0.5 percent. Exports continued to growth of 4.9 percent in Mar while imports fell 10.9 percent. The actual or not seasonally adjusted trade balance deficit fell from €2905 million in Aug to surplus of €1150 million in Dec but turned into deficit of €4346 million in Jan 2012, improving to lower deficit of €1113 million in Feb 2012 and surplus of €2067 million in Mar 2012, returning to deficit of €202 million in Apr. Exports fell 20.9 percent and imports 22.1 percent during the global recession in 2009.

Table VG-3, Italy, Exports, Imports and Trade Balance NSA Million Euros and 12 Month ∆%

 

Exports

€ M

Exports
12 Months ∆%

Imports

€ M

Imports
12 Months ∆%

Balance

€ M

Apr 2012

30,519

-1.7

30,721

-9.3

-202

Mar

36,107

4.9

34,042

-10.9

2,067

Feb 2012

31,754

7.3

32,890

0.8

-1,136

Jan

27,271

4.3

31,617

-2.6

-4,346

Dec 2011

31,551

6.2

34,401

-7.1

1,150

Nov

32,428

6.5

34,011

0.5

-1,583

Oct

32,131

4.5

33,186

-0.4

-1,055

Sep

32,997

10.2

34,878

3.6

-1,881

Aug

24,177

14.9

27,082

12.1

-2,905

Jul

35,264

5.8

33,743

6.1

1,521

Jun

32,605

7.9

34,309

1.6

-1,704

May

33,491

19.8

35,722

18.4

-2,231

Apr

31,045

12.5

33,869

18.0

-2,824

Mar

34,418

14.0

38,203

19.8

-3,785

Feb

29,595

17.7

32,621

16.2

-3,026

Jan

26,146

24.6

32,455

28.4

-6,309

Dec 2010

29,714

20.2

32,732

31.7

-3,018

Year

         

2011

375,850

11.4

400,480

9.0

-24,630

2010

337,346

15.6

367,390

23.4

-30,044

2009

291,733

-20.9

297,609

-22.1

-5,876

2008

369,016

1.2

382,050

2.3

-13,034

Source: Istituto Nazionale di Statistica http://www.istat.it/it/archivio/64824

Growth rates of Italy’s trade and major products are provided in Table VG-4 for the period Mar 2012 relative to Mar 2011. Growth rates of imports are negative with the exception of energy. The higher rate of growth of exports of 3.7 percent relative to imports of minus 5.7 percent may reflect weak demand in Italy with GDP declining during three consecutive quarters from IIIQ2011 through IQ2012.

Table VG-4, Italy, Exports and Imports % Share of Products in Total and ∆%

 

Exports
Share %

Exports
∆% Jan-Apr 2012/ Jan-Apr 2011

Imports
Share %

Imports
∆% Jan-Apr 2012/ Jan-Apr 2011

Consumer
Goods

28.9

4.7

25.0

-2.8

Durable

5.9

0.8

3.0

-9.8

Non
Durable

23.0

5.7

22.0

-1.8

Capital Goods

32.2

1.9

20.8

-13.9

Inter-
mediate Goods

34.3

2.6

34.5

-13.0

Energy

4.7

17.3

19.7

13.0

Total ex Energy

95.3

3.0

80.3

-10.2

Total

100.0

3.7

100.0

-5.7

Source: Istituto Nazionale di Statistica http://www.istat.it/it/archivio/64824

Table VG-5 provides Italy’s trade balance by product categories in Apr 2012 and cumulative Jan-Apr 2012. Italy’s trade balance excluding energy generated surplus of €5351 million in Apr 2012 and €19,377 million in Jan-Apr 2012 but the energy trade balance created deficit of €5553 million in Apr 2012 and €22,994 million in Jan-Apr 2012. The overall deficit in Apr 2012 was €202 million but there was an overall deficit of €3617 million in Jan-Apr 2012. Italy has significant competitiveness in various economic activities in contrast with some other countries with debt difficulties.

Table VG-5, Italy, Trade Balance by Product Categories, € Millions

 

Mar 2012

Cumulative Jan-Mar 2012

Consumer Goods

788

4,286

  Durable

867

3,510

  Nondurable

-80

776

Capital Goods

4,452

14,072

Intermediate Goods

112

1,019

Energy

-5,553

-22,994

Total ex Energy

5,351

19,377

Total

-202

-3,617

Source: Istituto Nazionale di Statistica http://www.istat.it/it/archivio/64824

Professors Ricardo Caballero and Francesco Giavazzi (2012Jan15) find that the resolution of the European sovereign crisis with survival of the euro area would require success in the restructuring of Italy. That success would be assured with growth of the Italian economy. A critical problem is that the common euro currency prevents Italy from devaluing the exchange rate to parity or the exchange rate that would permit export growth to promote internal economic activity, which could generate fiscal revenues for primary fiscal surplus that ensure creditworthiness. Fiscal consolidation and restructuring are important but of long-term gestation. Immediate growth of the Italian economy would consolidate the resolution of the sovereign debt crisis. Caballero and Giavazzi (2012Jan15) argue that 55 percent of the exports of Italy are to countries outside the euro area such that devaluation of 15 percent would be effective in increasing export revenue. Newly available data in Table VG-6 providing Italy’s trade with regions and countries supports the argument of Caballero and Giavazzi (2012Jan15). Italy’s exports to the European Monetary Union (EMU) are only 42.7 percent of the total. Exports to the non-European Union area are growing at 8.0 percent in Apr 2012 relative to Apr 2011 while those to EMU are falling at 0.5 percent.

Table VG-6, Italy, Exports and Imports by Regions and Countries, % Share and 12-Month ∆%

Apr 2012

Exports
% Share

∆% Jan-Apr 2012/ Jan-Apr 2011

Imports
% Share

Imports
∆% Jan-Apr 2012/ Jan-Apr 2011

EU

56.0

0.5

53.3

-7.6

EMU 17

42.7

-0.5

43.2

-7.1

France

11.6

0.6

8.3

-4.7

Germany

13.1

3.3

15.6

-10.3

Spain

5.3

-9.3

4.5

-9.9

UK

4.7

8.9

2.7

-16.4

Non EU

44.0

8.0

46.7

-3.7

Europe non EU

13.3

12.4

11.1

-4.7

USA

6.1

7.9

3.3

5.4

China

2.7

-10.7

7.3

-22.3

OPEC

4.7

18.2

8.6

20.1

Total

100.0

3.7

100.0

-5.7

Notes: EU: European Union; EMU: European Monetary Union (euro zone)

Source: Istituto Nazionale di Statistica http://www.istat.it/it/archivio/64824

Table VG-7 provides Italy’s trade balance by regions and countries. Italy had trade deficit of €325 million with the 17 countries of the euro zone (EMU 17) in Apr and deficit of €667 million in Jan-Apr. Depreciation to parity could permit greater competitiveness in improving the trade surpluses of €2469 million in Jan-Apr with Europe non European Union and of €3415 million with the US. There is significant rigidity in the trade deficits in Jan-Apr of €5187 million with China and €8039 million with members of the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC).

Table VG-7, Italy, Trade Balance by Regions and Countries, Millions of Euro 

Regions and Countries

Trade Balance Apr 2012 Millions of Euro

Trade Balance Cumulative Jan-Apr 2012 Millions of Euro

EU

702

3,434

EMU 17

-325

-667

France

848

3,820

Germany

-521

-1,882

Spain

93

834

UK

715

2,855

Non EU

-904

-7,052

Europe non EU

605

2,469

USA

1,279

3,415

China

-1,076

-5,187

OPEC

-1,877

-8,039

Total

-202

-3,617

Notes: EU: European Union; EMU: European Monetary Union (euro zone)

Source: Istituto Nazionale di Statistica http://www.istat.it/it/archivio/64824

VH United Kingdom. Revised annual data in Table VH-UK show the strong impact of the global recession in the UK with decline of GDP of revised 4.4 percent in 2009 after dropping revised 1.1 percent in 2008. Recovery of 2.1 percent in 2010 is relatively low compared to annual growth rates in 2007 and earlier years. Growth was only 0.7 percent in 2011. The bottom part of Table VH-1 provides average growth rates of UK GDP since 1948. The UK economy grew at 2.4 percent on average between 1948 and 2011, which is relatively high for an advanced economy. The growth rate of GDP between 2000 and 2007 is higher at 2.9 percent. Growth in the current cyclical expansion has been only at 1.4 percent as advanced economies struggle with weak internal demand and world trade.

Table VH-UK, UK, Gross Domestic Product, ∆%

 

∆% on Prior Year

1998

3.8

1999

3.7

2000

4.6

2001

3.1

2002

2.6

2003

3.5

2004

2.9

2005

2.0

2006

2.6

2007

3.5

2008

-1.1

2009

-4.4

2010

2.1

2011

0.7

Average ∆% per Year

 

1948-2011

2.4

1948-1959

2.5

1960-1969

2.9

1970-1979

2.4

1980-1989

2.9

1990-1999

2.4

2000-2011

1.5

2000-2007

2.9

2009-2011

1.4

Source: UK Office for National Statistics

http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/rel/naa2/second-estimate-of-gdp/q1-2012/index.html

The Business Activity Index of the Markit/CIPS UK Services PMI® was unchanged at 53.3 in May for 17 consecutive monthly increases but the slowest growth since Nov (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9666). Chris Williamson, Chief Economist at Markit, finds that services continue to expand with encouragement from growth of new business (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9666). The Markit/CIPS UK Manufacturing Purchasing Managers’ Index® (PMI®) fell sharply from 50.2 in Apr to 45.9 in Apr, which is the lowest level in three years and in contraction territory below 50 for the first month since Nov (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9618). The decline of 4.3 points in May is the second sharpest decline in the history of 20 years of the index. Rob Dobson, Senior Economist at Markit and author of the Markit/CIPS Manufacturing PMI®, finds that output contraction originated in sharp decline of new business with developing weakness in the internal market and not only in the euro area (http://www.markiteconomics.com/MarkitFiles/Pages/ViewPressRelease.aspx?ID=9618).Table UK provides the country data table for the UK.

Table UK, UK Economic Indicators

   

CPI

Apr month ∆%: 0.6
Apr 12-month ∆%: 3.0
Blog 5/27/12

Output/Input Prices

Output Prices:
Apr 12-month NSA ∆%: 2.8; excluding food, petroleum ∆%: 2.1
Input Prices:
May 12-month NSA
∆%: 0.1
Excluding ∆%: 1.1
Blog 6/10/12

GDP Growth

IQ2012 prior quarter ∆% minus 0.3; year earlier same quarter ∆%: minus 0.1
Blog 5/27/12

Industrial Production

Apr 2012/Apr 2011 NSA ∆%: Production Industries minus 1.0; Manufacturing minus 0.3
Blog 6/17/12

Retail Sales

Apr month SA ∆%: minus 2.3
Apr 12-month NSA ∆%: minus 2.1
Blog 5/27/12

Labor Market

Jan-Mar Unemployment Rate: 8.2%; Claimant Count 4.9%; Earnings Growth 0.6%
Blog 5/20/12

Trade Balance

Balance Apr minus ₤4421 million
Exports Apr ∆%: -5.1 Mar-Apr ∆%: 0.6
Imports Apr ∆%: -1.4 Mar-Apr ∆%: 5.2
Blog 6/17/12

Links to blog comments in Table UK:

6/10/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/rules-versus-discretionary-authorities_10.html

5/27/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/05/world-financial-turbulence-global_27.html

5/20/12 http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/05/world-inflation-waves-monetary-policy_20.html

The UK Office for National Statistics provides the output of production industries with revisions. Table VH-1 incorporates the revisions released on Oct 11, 2011(http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/rel/iop/index-of-production/august-2011/index.html) and the latest available data for Apr 2012. Manufacturing accounts for 66.6 percent of the production industries of the UK and decreased 0.3 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr. Capital goods industries grew at 4.6 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr 2012 and had been growing at very high rates during the current cyclical recovery but falling from the unsustainable high of 10.0 percent in the 12 months ending in Jan 2011. Mining and quarrying fell 21.2 percent in the 12 months ending in Jan 2012, 9.5 percent in the 12 months ending in Feb, 10.6 percent in the 12 months ending in Mar and 15.0 percent in the 12 months ending in Apr. The 12-month rates of growth of the entire index of production industries registered declines for all 12 months from Mar 2011 to Apr 2012. Energy and mining have been the drivers of decline. The lower part of Table VH-1 provides rates of change of yearly values. Manufacturing output fell 9.6 percent in 2009 after falling 2.6 percent in 2008 but grew at 3.7 percent in the initial phase of the recovery in 2010 and 2.0 percent in 2011.

Table VH-1, UK, Output of the Production Industries, Chained Volume Indices of Gross Value Added, 12-Month ∆%

 

PROD
IND

MNG

MFG

ENGY

CON
DUR

CON
NDUR

CAP

2012

             

Apr

-1.0

-15.0

-0.3

-4.3

1.7

-4.6

4.6

Mar

-2.6

-10.6

-0.9

-8.7

-4.3

-1.6

1.0

Feb

-2.3

-9.5

-1.5

-5.2

-5.4

-0.2

-0.5

Jan

-4.0

-21.2

-0.1

-15.9

-4.9

0.8

3.2

2011

             

Dec

-3.1

-15.4

0.9

-15.9

-3.7

0.1

5.7

Nov

-3.3

-15.0

-1.0

-12.7

0.6

-0.9

4.2

Oct

-2.5

-14.0

-0.4

-11.4

-1.3

-1.4

4.6

Sep

-1.9

-18.0

0.9

-11.9

-1.2

-0.1

6.1

Aug

-1.5

-15.7

0.9

-9.6

-1.5

1.7

3.7

Jul

-1.4

-16.8

1.9

-11.0

1.5

3.2

4.1

Jun

-0.7

-16.5

2.8

-10.1

6.5

2.3

7.1

May

-1.6

-22.3

3.3

-14.2

1.7

3.6

5.9

Apr

-2.0

-16.3

1.9

-12.4

1.1

3.8

4.1

Mar

-0.8

-16.7

2.8

-11.4

0.9

0.4

8.2

Feb

1.3

-12.3

4.7

-8.4

0.4

0.8

10.2

Jan

3.3

-3.2

5.6

-3.3

3.4

-0.3

10.0

2010

             

Dec

3.3

-4.8

4.3

0.8

-4.6

3.1

8.0

Nov

2.7

-6.2

5.1

-3.1

-9.4

1.2

9.5

Oct

2.7

-6.2

5.3

-3.1

-9.5

4.2

7.3

Sep

3.7

2.9

5.2

1.2

-9.0

2.1

9.7

Aug

3.8

0.3

6.2

-1.1

0.2

3.5

12.7

Jul

1.6

-8.9

5.0

-7.1

-1.4

-0.9

12.7

Jun

1.2

-9.5

3.9

-6.6

-6.2

0.5

9.6

May

2.5

-1.0

3.5

-1.4

-2.6

-3.3

12.2

Apr

0.9

-5.9

2.1

-3.6

-3.7

-6.3

10.1

Mar

2.2

-1.4

3.2

-0.9

0.2

-1.7

9.2

Feb

-0.6

-8.4

1.0

-5.9

-1.5

-2.7

7.4

Jan

-1.6

-8.7

-0.4

-5.1

-3.5

-1.4

4.9

2011/ 2010

-1.2

-15.2

2.0

-11.0

0.7

1.1

6.1

2010/
2009

1.9

-4.9

3.7

-3.1

-4.3

-0.2

9.4

2009/ 2008

-9.0

-9.0

-9.6

-6.2

-7.5

-0.8

-10.7

2008/ 2007

-2.8

-6.5

-2.6

-2.9

-5.6

-1.9

-3.0

2007/
2006

0.5

-2.5

0.8

-1.2

1.0

-1.7

2.5

2006/ 2005

0.0

-7.6

1.7

-5.4

0.3

0.7

2.9

Notes: PROD IND: Production Industries; MNG: Mining; MFG: Manufacturing; ENGY: Energy; CON DUR: Consumer Durables; CONS NDUR: Consumer Nondurables; CAP: Capital Goods

Source: http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/rel/iop/index-of-production/april-2012/index.html

Percentage changes in the production industries and major components in the latest month relative to the prior month are shown in Table VH-2. Manufacturing fell in all months from Jun 2011 to Nov 2011 with the exception of no growth in Sep. Manufacturing fell in four of the six months from Nov 2011 to Apr 2012. In Dec, manufacturing grew 1.1 percent but decreased 0.3 percent in Jan 2012 and 1.1 percent in Feb 2012, growing 0.9 percent in Mar 2012 and declining 0.7 percent in Apr 2012. Growth was stronger in the first five months to May 2011 with the exception of decline by 1.3 percent in Apr. Output of consumer durables has fallen sharply from Jul 2011 to Mar 2012 by cumulative 5.5 percent with growth only in Nov by 1.3 percent but jumped 1.2 percent in Jan 2012, declining 1.1 percent in Feb. increasing 1.9 percent in Mar and declining 0.7 in Apr. Output of capital goods fell 0.8 percent in Jul and then another 0.1 percent in Aug but grew strongly by 2.0 percent in Sep but declined slightly by 1.0 percent in Oct, increasing 1.5 percent in Nov and 0.8 percent in Dec. Output of capital goods increased 0.2 percent in Apr 2012 and 2.4 percent in Mar 2012 after declining 1.0 percent in Jan 2012, decreasing 2.1 percent in Feb 2012.

Table VH-2, UK, Output of the Production Industries, Chained Volume Indices of Gross Value Added, Latest Month on Previous Month ∆%

 

PROD
IND

MNG

MFG

ENGY

CON
DUR

CON
NDUR

CAP

2012

             

Apr

0.0

-5.7

-0.7

2.5

5.3

-2.8

0.2

Mar

-0.3

-2.5

0.9

-4.5

1.9

-0.2

2.4

Feb

0.4

4.1

-1.1

5.4

-1.6

-0.7

-2.1

Jan

-0.6

-2.9

-0.3

-1.7

1.2

-0.3

-1.0

2011

             

Dec

0.4

-2.9

1.1

-1.7

-0.6

1.3

0.8

Nov

-0.5

-1.9

-0.1

-1.5

1.3

-0.2

1.5

Oct

-1.1

-0.2

-0.9

-1.8

-0.2

-0.7

-1.0

Sep

-0.2

-1.6

0.0

-1.2

-2.6

-2.2

2.0

Aug

0.2

2.5

-0.4

1.8

-1.8

0.3

-0.1

Jul

-0.4

-0.2

-0.2

-1.2

-2.1

-0.2

-0.8

Jun

0.1

0.7

-0.3

1.1

0.6

0.3

-0.2

May

0.9

-5.1

1.7

-1.1

0.5

0.7

2.8

Apr

-1.6

-0.8

-1.3

-2.2

-0.9

0.3

-3.3

Mar

0.1

-1.3

0.3

-0.8

0.6

1.2

0.9

Feb

-1.4

-9.4

0.3

-6.5

-1.0

0.2

1.6

Jan

0.3

4.3

0.7

-1.8

2.4

-1.0

1.4

2010

             

Dec

0.2

-2.5

-0.7

2.1

3.9

0.2

-0.6

Notes: PROD IND: Production Industries; MNG: Mining; MFG: Manufacturing; ENGY: Electricity, Gas and Water Supply; CON DUR: Consumer Durables; CONS NDUR: Consumer Nondurables; CAP: Capital Goods

Source: http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/rel/iop/index-of-production/april-2012/index.html

The weights of components of the production index and contributions by components to the monthly and 12-month percentage changes of volume are provided in Table VH-3. The 12-month rate of output of the production industries of minus 1.0 percent was driven by negative contribution of 2.03 percentage points of the general component of mining with the subcomponent of oil and gas contributing negative 2.02 percentage points. Manufacturing deducted 0.18 percentage points to growth of the production industries index. The contribution of manufacturing is strong because of its share of 66.6 percent in the production index with growth of minus 0.3 percent in 12 months. The contributions do not add exactly because of rounding. Manufacturing decreased 0.7 percent in Mar, contributing minus 0.50 percentage points. Decline of mining by 5.7 percent contributed minus 0.70 percentage points.

Table VH-3, UK, Weights of Components, Volume 12-Month and Month ∆% and Percentage Point Contributions of Production Industries by Components

 

Weight %

Volume 12-Month ∆% Ending in Apr 2012

% Point
Contrib.

Volume
Month
∆% Apr 2012

% Point
Contrib.

PROD
IND

100.0

-1.0

-0.97

0.0

0.05

MNG

16.4

-15.0

-2.03

-5.7

-0.70

MNG 06

14.1

-18.2

-2.02

-6.4

-0.63

MFG

66.6

-0.3

-0.18

-0.7

-0.50

ELEC

9.3

12.6

1.15

13.6

1.24

WATER
& SEW

7.7

1.1

0.09

0.0

0.00

Notes: Contrib: Contribution; PROD IND: Index of Production; MNG: Mining and Quarrying (of which 14.4 percent of the total weight in oil and gas extraction); MNG 06: Subdivision of Mining including oil and gas extraction; MFG: Manufacturing; ELEC: Electricity, gas, steam and air conditioning; WATER & SEW: water supply, sewerage and waste management

Source: http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/rel/iop/index-of-production/april-2012/index.html

Table VH-4 provides the breakdown of manufacturing 12-month and monthly growth and percentage contributions. The strongest negative contribution to 12-month growth was by manufacture of food products, beverages and tobacco (CA) with 0.78 percentage points and 12-month growth of minus 5.7 percent. The highest positive contribution was 0.65 percentage points by transport equipment (CL), growing 8.8 percent. Electrical products (CJ) added 0.33 percentage points with growth of 16.5 percent.

Table VH-4, UK, Growth Rates of Manufacturing and Percentage Point Contributions to the Index of Production

Sub-sector

% of production

Apr 2012

12-Month Growth %

Contribution to production (% points)

Apr 2012

Month on month growth (%)

Contribution to production (% points)

           

CA

11.2

-5.7

-0.78

-1.7

-0.22

CB

2.1

-2.7

-0.06

1.2

0.03

CC

5.9

-3.5

-0.20

-1.1

-0.06

CD

0.4

-7.1

0.03

-0.5

0.00

CE

5.5

-0.9

-0.05

0.6

0.03

CF

4.9

-3.0

-0.13

-6.0

-0.28

CG

5.0

-5.1

-0.24

-1.8

-0.08

CH

9.3

2.8

0.24

-1.1

-0.10

CI

4.9

6.2

0.29

8.1

0.38

CJ

2.2

16.5

0.33

2.4

0.06

CK

4.4

6.4

0.31

2.2

0.11

CL

5.8

8.8

0.65

-1.1

-0.09

CM

4.9

-9.5

-0.52

-5.1

-0.27

Notes:

CA Manufacture of food products, beverages and tobacco; CB Textiles, wearing apparel and leather products; CC Wood and paper products and printing; CD Coke and refined petroleum products; CE Chemicals and chemical products; CF Basic pharmaceutical products and preparations; CG Rubber and plastic products and nonmetallic mineral products; CH Basic metals and metal products; CI Computer, electronic and optical products; CJ Electrical equipment; CK Machinery and equipment not elsewhere classified; CL Transport equipment; CM Other manufacturing and repair.

Source: http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/rel/iop/index-of-production/april-2012/index.html

The UK’s trade account is shown in Table VH-5. In Apr 2012, the UK ran a deficit in trade of goods and services (total trade) of ₤4421 million. The deficit in trade of goods was ₤10,103 million and ₤8,901 million in goods excluding oil. A surplus in services of ₤5682 million contributed to the smaller overall deficit in goods and services (-₤10,103 million plus ₤5682 equal to -₤4421). Services have contributed to lower trade account deficits and also softened the impact of the global recession on the UK economy. Exports of goods and services decreased 5.1 percent in Apr 2012 and rose 0.6 percent in the quarter Feb-Apr 2012 relative to the same quarter a year earlier with imports decreasing 1.4 percent in Apr and rising 5.2 percent in Feb-Apr 2012 relative to the same quarter a year earlier. Excluding oil, UK exports of goods decreased 9.6 percent in Apr and increased 1.4 percent in Feb-Apr 2012 relative to a year earlier while imports decreased 2.0 percent in Apr and increased 5.2 percent in Feb-Apr 2012 relative to a year earlier. The great advantage of the UK similar to the US is the substantial surplus in services. Services exports increased 0.8 percent in Apr and fell 0.4 percent in Feb-Apr 2012 relative to a year earlier and imports increased 2.3 percent in Apr and increased 2.0 percent Feb-Apr 2012 relative to a year earlier.

Table VH-5, Value of UK Trade in Goods and Services, Balance of Payments Basis, ₤ Million  and ∆%

 

₤ Million SA Apr 2012

Month ∆%   
Apr 2012

Feb-Apr 2012 ∆% Feb-Apr 2011

Total Trade

     

Exports

39,419

-5.1

0.6

Imports

43,480

-1.4

5.2

Balance

-4,421

   

Trade in Goods

     

Exports

23,827

-8.6

1.3

Imports

33,930

-2.5

6.2

Balance

-10,103

   

Trade in Goods Excluding Oil

     

Exports

20,563

-9.6

1.4

Imports

29,464

-2.0

5.2

Balance

-8,901

   

Trade in Services

     

Exports

15,592

0.8

-0.4

Imports

9,910

2.3

2.0

Balance

5,682

   

Source: UK Office for National Statistics http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/dcp171778_267507.pdf

VI Valuation of Risk Financial Assets. The financial crisis and global recession were caused by interest rate and housing subsidies and affordability policies that encouraged high leverage and risks, low liquidity and unsound credit (Pelaez and Pelaez, Financial Regulation after the Global Recession (2009a), 157-66, Regulation of Banks and Finance (2009b), 217-27, International Financial Architecture (2005), 15-18, The Global Recession Risk (2007), 221-5, Globalization and the State Vol. II (2008b), 197-213, Government Intervention in Globalization (2008c), 182-4). Several past comments of this blog elaborate on these arguments, among which: http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/07/causes-of-2007-creditdollar-crisis.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/professor-mckinnons-bubble-economy.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/world-inflation-quantitative-easing.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/treasury-yields-valuation-of-risk.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2010/11/quantitative-easing-theory-evidence-and.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2010/12/is-fed-printing-money-what-are.html 

Table VI-1 shows the phenomenal impulse to valuations of risk financial assets originating in the initial shock of near zero interest rates in 2003-2004 with the fed funds rate at 1 percent, in fear of deflation that never materialized, and quantitative easing in the form of suspension of the auction of 30-year Treasury bonds to lower mortgage rates. World financial markets were dominated by monetary and housing policies in the US. Between 2002 and 2008, the DJ UBS Commodity Index rose 165.5 percent largely because of unconventional monetary policy encouraging carry trades from low US interest rates to long leveraged positions in commodities, exchange rates and other risk financial assets. The charts of risk financial assets show sharp increase in valuations leading to the financial crisis and then profound drops that are captured in Table VI-1 by percentage changes of peaks and troughs. The first round of quantitative easing and near zero interest rates depreciated the dollar relative to the euro by 39.3 percent between 2003 and 2008, with revaluation of the dollar by 25.1 percent from 2008 to 2010 in the flight to dollar-denominated assets in fear of world financial risks and then devaluation of the dollar of 6.0 percent by Fri Jun 15, 2012. Dollar devaluation is a major vehicle of monetary policy in reducing the output gap that is implemented in the probably erroneous belief that devaluation will not accelerate inflation, misallocating resources toward less productive economic activities and disrupting financial markets. The last row of Table VI-1 shows CPI inflation in the US rising from 1.9 percent in 2003 to 4.1 percent in 2007 even as monetary policy increased the fed funds rate from 1 percent in Jun 2004 to 5.25 percent in Jun 2006.

Table VI-1, Volatility of Assets

DJIA

10/08/02-10/01/07

10/01/07-3/4/09

3/4/09- 4/6/10

 

∆%

87.8

-51.2

60.3

 

NYSE Financial

1/15/04- 6/13/07

6/13/07- 3/4/09

3/4/09- 4/16/07

 

∆%

42.3

-75.9

121.1

 

Shanghai Composite

6/10/05- 10/15/07

10/15/07- 10/30/08

10/30/08- 7/30/09

 

∆%

444.2

-70.8

85.3

 

STOXX EUROPE 50

3/10/03- 7/25/07

7/25/07- 3/9/09

3/9/09- 4/21/10

 

∆%

93.5

-57.9

64.3

 

UBS Com.

1/23/02- 7/1/08

7/1/08- 2/23/09

2/23/09- 1/6/10

 

∆%

165.5

-56.4

41.4

 

10-Year Treasury

6/10/03

6/12/07

12/31/08

4/5/10

%

3.112

5.297

2.247

3.986

USD/EUR

6/26/03

7/14/08

6/07/10

6/15/2012

Rate

1.1423

1.5914

1.192

1.2640

CNY/USD

01/03
2000

07/21
2005

7/15
2008

6/15/

2012

Rate

8.2798

8.2765

6.8211

6.3678

New House

1963

1977

2005

2009

Sales 1000s

560

819

1283

375

New House

2000

2007

2009

2010

Median Price $1000

169

247

217

203

 

2003

2005

2007

2010

CPI

1.9

3.4

4.1

1.5

Sources: http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/page/marketsdata.html?mod=WSJ_hps_marketdata

http://www.census.gov/const/www/newressalesindex_excel.html

http://federalreserve.gov/releases/h10/Hist/dat00_eu.htm

ftp://ftp.bls.gov/pub/special.requests/cpi/cpiai.txt

Table VI-2 extracts four rows of Table VI-I with the Dollar/Euro (USD/EUR) exchange rate and Chinese Yuan/Dollar (CNY/USD) exchange rate that reveal pursuit of exchange rate policies resulting from monetary policy in the US and capital control/exchange rate policy in China. The ultimate intentions are the same: promoting internal economic activity at the expense of the rest of the world. The easy money policy of the US was deliberately or not but effectively to devalue the dollar from USD 1.1423/EUR on Jun 26, 2003 to USD 1.5914/EUR on Jul 14, 2008, or by 39.3 percent. The flight into dollar assets after the global recession caused revaluation to USD 1.192/EUR on Jun 7, 2010, or by 25.1 percent. After the temporary interruption of the sovereign risk issues in Europe from Apr to Jul, 2010, shown in Table VI-4 below, the dollar has devalued again to USD 1.2640/EUR on Jun 15, 2012 or by 6.0 percent {[(1.2640/1.192)-1]100}. Yellen (2011AS, 6) admits that Fed monetary policy results in dollar devaluation with the objective of increasing net exports, which was the policy that Joan Robinson (1947) labeled as “beggar-my-neighbor” remedies for unemployment. Risk aversion erodes devaluation of the dollar. China fixed the CNY to the dollar for a long period at a highly undervalued level of around CNY 8.2765/USD subsequently revaluing to CNY 6.8211/USD until Jun 7, 2010, or by 17.6 percent and after fixing it again to the dollar, revalued to CNY 6.3678/USD on Fri Jun 15, 2012, or by an additional 6.6 percent, for cumulative revaluation of 23.1 percent.

Table VI-2, Dollar/Euro (USD/EUR) Exchange Rate and Chinese Yuan/Dollar (CNY/USD) Exchange Rate

USD/EUR

12/26/03

7/14/08

6/07/10

6/15
/2012

Rate

1.1423

1.5914

1.192

1.2640

CNY/USD

01/03
2000

07/21
2005

7/15
2008

6/15/2012

Rate

8.2798

8.2765

6.8211

6.3752

Weekly Rates

5/25/2012

6/1/2012

6/8/2012

6/15/2012

CNY/USD

6.3372

6.3708

6.3752

6.3678

∆% from Earlier Week*

-0.2

-0.5

-0.1

0.1

*Negative sign is depreciation, positive sign is appreciation

Source: http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/public/page/mdc_currencies.html?mod=mdc_topnav_2_3000

http://federalreserve.gov/releases/h10/Hist/dat00_ch.htm

The Dow Jones Newswires informs on Oct 15 that the premier of China Wen Jiabao announced that the Chinese yuan will not be further appreciated to prevent adverse effects on exports (http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052970203914304576632790881396896.html?mod=WSJ_hp_LEFTWhatsNewsCollection). Table VI-2A provides the CNY/USD rate from Oct 28, 2011 to Jun 15, 2012 in selected intervals. The CNY/USD revalued by 0.9 percent from Oct 28, 2012 to Apr 27, 2012 but the magnitude of the revaluation declined to 0.3 percent by May 25, 2012 and only 0.1 percent by Jun 15, 2012. After depreciation of 0.5 percent in the week of Jun 1 and 0.1 percent in the week of Jun 8 but appreciation of 0.1 percent in the week of Jun 15 (see Table VI-2), the CNY has depreciated 0.1 percent relative to Oct 28, 2011, as shown in Table VI-2A. Meanwhile, the Senate of the US is proceeding with a bill on China’s trade that could create a confrontation but may not be approved by the entire Congress. An important statement by the People’s Bank of China (PBC), China’s central bank, on Apr 14, 2012, announced the widening of the daily maximum band of fluctuation of the renminbi (RMB) yuan (http://www.pbc.gov.cn/publish/english/955/2012/20120414090756030448561/20120414090756030448561_.html):

“Along with the development of China’s foreign exchange market, the pricing and risk management capabilities of market participants are gradually strengthening. In order to meet market demands, promote price discovery, enhance the flexibility of RMB exchange rate in both directions, further improve the managed floating RMB exchange rate regime based on market supply and demand with reference to a basket of currencies, the People’s Bank of China has decided to enlarge the floating band of RMB’s trading prices against the US dollar and is hereby making a public announcement as follows:

Effective from April 16, 2012 onwards, the floating band of RMB’s trading prices against the US dollar in the inter-bank spot foreign exchange market is enlarged from 0.5 percent to 1 percent, i.e., on each business day, the trading prices of the RMB against the US dollar in the inter-bank spot foreign exchange market will fluctuate within a band of ±1 percent around the central parity released on the same day by the China Foreign Exchange Trade System. The spread between the RMB/USD selling and buying prices offered by the foreign exchange-designated banks to their customers shall not exceed 2 percent of the central parity, instead of 1 percent, while other provisions in the Circular of the PBC on Relevant Issues Managing the Trading Prices in the Inter-bank Foreign Exchange Market and Quoted Exchange Rates of Exchange-Designated Banks(PBC Document No.[2010]325) remain valid.

In view of the domestic and international economic and financial conditions, the People’s Bank of China will continue to fulfill its mandates in relation to the RMB exchange rate, keeping RMB exchange rate basically stable at an adaptive and equilibrium level based on market supply and demand with reference to a basket of currencies to preserve stability of the Chinese economy and financial markets.”

Table VI-2A, Renminbi Yuan US Dollar Rate

 

CNY/USD

∆% from 10/28/2011

6/15/12

6.3678

-0.1

6/8/2012

6.3752

-0.3

6/1/2012

6.3708

-0.2

4/27/2012

6.3016

0.9

3/23/2012

6.3008

0.9

2/3/2012

6.3030

0.9

12/30/2011

6.2940

1.0

11/25/2011

6.3816

-0.4

10/28/2011

6.3588

-

Source:

http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/public/page/mdc_currencies.html?mod=mdc_topnav_2_3000

http://federalreserve.gov/releases/h10/Hist/dat00_ch.htm

The database of the World Economic Outlook (WEO) of the IMF (http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2012/01/weodata/index.aspx) is used to contract Table VI-3 with fiscal and current account imbalances projected for 2011 and 2015. The WEO finds the need to rebalance external and domestic demand (IMF 2011WEOSep xvii):

“Progress on this front has become even more important to sustain global growth. Some emerging market economies are contributing more domestic demand than is desirable (for example, several economies in Latin America); others are not contributing enough (for example, key economies in emerging Asia). The first set needs to restrain strong domestic demand by considerably reducing structural fiscal deficits and, in some cases, by further removing monetary accommodation. The second set of economies needs significant currency appreciation alongside structural reforms to reduce high surpluses of savings over investment. Such policies would help improve their resilience to shocks originating in the advanced economies as well as their medium-term growth potential.”

The IMF (2012WEOApr, XVII) explains decreasing importance of the issue of global imbalances as follows:

“The latest developments suggest that global current account imbalances are no longer expected to widen again, following their sharp reduction during the Great Recession. This is largely because the excessive consumption growth that characterized economies that ran large external deficits prior to the crisis has been wrung out and has not been offset by stronger consumption in surplus economies. Accordingly, the global economy has experienced a loss of demand and growth in all regions relative to the boom years just before the crisis. Rebalancing activity in key surplus economies toward higher consumption, supported by more market-determined exchange rates, would help strengthen their prospects as well as those of the rest of the world.”

Table VI-3, Fiscal Deficit, Current Account Deficit and Government Debt as % of GDP and 2011 Dollar GDP

 

GDP
$B

2011

FD
%GDP
2011

CAD
%GDP
2011

Debt
%GDP
2011

FD%GDP
2015

CAD%GDP
2015

Debt
%GDP
2015

US

15094

-7.3

-3.1

80.3

-2.3

-3.2

88.3

Japan

5869

-9.1

2.0

126.6

-5.8

2.4

155.0

UK

2418

-5.8

-1.9

78.3

-0.8

-0.4

88.1

Euro

13115

-1.6

0.3

68.4

1.1

1.2

71.3

Ger

3577

0.7

5.7

56.1

1.4

4.3

52.4

France

2776

-2.9

-2.2

80.4

0.3

-0.8

83.8

Italy

2199

0.8

-3.2

99.6

4.4

-1.6

101.5

Can

1737

-4.1

-2.8

33.3

-1.1

-2.5

37.4

China

7298

-1.2

2.7

25.8

-0.1

3.4

14.8

Brazil

2493

3.1

-2.1

36.4

3.1

-3.4

31.9

Note: GER = Germany; Can = Canada; FD = fiscal deficit; CAD = current account deficit

FD is primary except total for China; Debt is net except gross for China

Source: http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2012/01/weodata/weoselgr.aspx

The International Monetary Fund (IMF) provides an international safety net for prevention and resolution of international financial crises. The IMF’s Financial Sector Assessment Program (FSAP) provides analysis of the economic and financial sectors of countries (see Pelaez and Pelaez, International Financial Architecture (2005), 101-62, Globalization and the State, Vol. II (2008), 114-23). Relating economic and financial sectors is a challenging task both for theory and measurement. The IMF (2012WEOApr) provides surveillance of the world economy with its Global Economic Outlook (WEO) (http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2012/01/pdf/text.pdf), of the world financial system with its Global Financial Stability Report (GFSR) (IMF 2012GFSRApr) (http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/gfsr/2012/01/pdf/text.pdf) and of fiscal affairs with the Fiscal Monitor (IMF 2012FMApr) (http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fm/2012/01/pdf/fm1201.pdf). There appears to be a moment of transition in global economic and financial variables that may prove of difficult analysis and measurement. It is useful to consider global economic and financial risks, which are analyzed in the comments of this blog.

Economic risks include the following:

1. China’s Economic Growth. China is lowering its growth target to 7.5 percent per year. Lu Hui, writing on “China lowers GDP target to achieve quality economic growth, on Mar 12, 2012, published in Beijing by Xinhuanet (http://news.xinhuanet.com/english/china/2012-03/12/c_131461668.htm), informs that Premier Jiabao wrote in a government work report that the GDP growth target will be lowered to 7.5 percent to enhance the quality and level of development of China over the long term. The quarterly growth rate of GDP in IQ2012 of 1.8 percent is equivalent to 7.4 percent per year (see subsection VC at http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/04/fractured-labor-market-with-hiring_15.html). There is also ongoing political development in China during a decennial political reorganization. Xinhuanet informs that Premier Wen Jiabao considers the need for macroeconomic stimulus, arguing that “we should continue to implement proactive fiscal policy and a prudent monetary policy, while giving more priority to maintaining growth” (http://news.xinhuanet.com/english/china/2012-05/20/c_131599662.htm). Premier Wen elaborates that “the country should properly handle the relationship between maintaining growth, adjusting economic structures and managing inflationary expectations” (http://news.xinhuanet.com/english/china/2012-05/20/c_131599662.htm).

2. United States Economic Growth, Labor Markets and Budget/Debt Quagmire. (i) The US economy grew at 1.7 percent in 2011 (Section I in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/mediocre-recovery-without-jobs.html), 1.7 percent in annual equivalent in the five quarters from IQ2011 to IQ2012 and 2.0 percent in IQ2012 relative to IQ2011 (see Section II http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/mediocre-recovery-without-jobs.html). (ii) The labor market continues fractured with 28.4 million unemployed or underemployed (see Section I http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/mediocre-recovery-without-jobs.html). There are over 10 million fewer full-time jobs and hiring has collapsed (see Section I at http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/05/recovery-without-hiring-ten-million.html and earlier at http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/04/fractured-labor-market-with-hiring.html). (iii) There is a difficult climb from the record deficit of 9.9 percent in 2009 and cumulative deficit of $5178 in four consecutive years of deficits exceeding one trillion dollars from 2009 to 2012 (see Section VA). There is no subsequent jump of debt in US peacetime history as the one from 40.5 percent of GDP in 2008 to 67.7 percent of GDP in 2011 and projected by the Congressional Budget Office (CBO 2012MarBEO, 2) at 73.2 percent in 2012. The CBO (2012MarBEO) must use current law without any changes in the baseline scenario but also calculates another alternative scenario with different assumptions. In the alternative scenario, the debt/GDP ratio rises to 94.2 percent by 2022. The US is facing an unsustainable debt/GDP path. Feldstein (2012Mar19) finds that the most troubling uncertainty in the US is the programmed tax increases projected by the CBO (2012JanBEO) under current law with federal government revenue increasing from $2.4 trillion in fiscal year 2012 to $2.9 trillion in fiscal year 2013. The increase of $512 billion of federal revenue would be about 2.9 percent of GDP, raising the share of federal revenue in GDP from 15.8 percent in fiscal year 2012 to 18.7 percent of GDP in fiscal year 2013. In the analysis of Feldstein (2012Mar19), increasing revenue would originate in higher personal tax rates, payroll tax contributions and taxes on dividends, capital gains and corporate income tax. The share of federal revenue in GDP would increase to 19.8 percent in 2014, remaining above 20 percent during the rest of the decade. Feldstein (2012Mar19) finds that such a shock of sustained tax increases would risk another recession in 2013, requiring preventive legislation to smooth tax increases

3. Economic Growth and Labor Markets in Advanced Economies. Advanced economies are growing slowly. Japan’s GDP fell 0.6 percent in IVQ2011 relative to a year earlier but grew 2.8 percent in IQ2012 relative to a year earlier and 1.2 percent in IQ2012 relative to IVQ2011. The euro zone’s GDP fell 0.3 percent in IVQ2011 and was flat in IQ2012, falling 0.1 percent relative to a year earlier in IQ2011; Germany’s GDP fell 0.2 percent in IVQ2011 but grew 0.5 percent in IQ2012; and the UK’s GDP fell 0.3 percent in IVQ2011 and 0.3 percent in IQ2012. There is still high unemployment in advanced economies

4. World Inflation Waves. Inflation continues in repetitive waves globally (see Section I Inflation Waves and earlier at http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/05/world-inflation-waves-monetary-policy.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/04/fractured-labor-market-with-hiring.html and http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/03/global-financial-and-economic-risk.html)

A list of financial uncertainties includes:

1. Euro Area Survival Risk. The resilience of the euro to fiscal and financial doubts on larger member countries is still an unknown risk. Adjustment programs consist of immediate adoption of economic reforms that would increase future growth permitting fiscal consolidation, which would reduce risk spreads on sovereign debt. Fiscal consolidation is challenging in an environment of weak economic growth as analyzed by Blanchard (2011WEOSep) and consolidation can restrict growth as analyzed by Blanchard (2012WEOApr). Adjustment of countries such as Italy requires depreciation of the currency to parity, as proposed by Caballero and Giavazzi (2012Jan15), but it is not workable within the common currency and zero interest rates in the US. Bailouts of euro area member countries with temporary liquidity challenges cannot be permanently provided by stronger members at the risk of impairing their own sovereign debt credibility

2. Foreign Exchange Wars. Exchange rate struggles continue as zero interest rates in advanced economies induce devaluation. After deep global recession, regulation, trade and devaluation wars were to be expected (Pelaez and Pelaez, Government Intervention in Globalization: Regulation, Trade and Devaluation Wars (2008c), 181): “There are significant grounds for concern on the basis of this experience. International economic cooperation and the international financial framework can collapse during extreme events. It is unlikely that there will be a repetition of the disaster of the Great Depression. However, a milder contraction can trigger regulatory, trade and exchange wars”

3. Valuation of Risk Financial Assets. Valuations of risk financial assets have reached extremely high levels in markets with lower volumes. For example, the DJIA has increased 31.8 percent since the trough of the sovereign debt crisis in Europe on Jul 2, 2010, and the S&P 500 has gained 31.3 percent. It is challenging in theory and practice to assess when variables have peaked but sustained valuations to very high levels could be followed by contractions of valuations. Jonathan Cheng, writing on “Stocks add 66 points, post first-quarter record,” published on Mar 30, 2012, in the Wall Street Journal (http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052702303816504577313123753822852.html?mod=WSJ_Markets_LEFTTopStories&mg=reno64-sec-wsj), finds that the DJIA rose 8.1 percent in IQ2012, which is the highest since 1998, while the S&P 500 gained 12 percent. Paul A. Samuelson remarked that “the stock market has predicted nine of the last five recessions.” Another version of this phrase would be that “the stock market has predicted nine of the last five economic booms.” The tool of analysis of Cochrane (2011Jan, 27, equation (16)) is the government debt valuation equation:

(Mt + Bt)/Pt = Et∫(1/Rt, t+τ)stdτ (1)

Equation (1) expresses the monetary, Mt, and debt, Bt, liabilities of the government, divided by the price level, Pt, in terms of the expected value discounted by the ex-post rate on government debt, Rt, t+τ, of the future primary surpluses st, which are equal to TtGt or difference between taxes, T, and government expenditures, G. Cochrane (2010A) provides the link to a web appendix demonstrating that it is possible to discount by the ex post Rt, t+τ. The present value of the firm can also be expressed as the discounted future value of net cash flows. Equities can inflate beyond sound values if cash flows that depend on economic activity prove to be illusory in continuing mediocre growth

4. Duration Trap of the Zero Bound. The yield of the US 10-year Treasury rose from 2.031 percent on Mar 9, 2012, to 2.294 percent on Mar 16, 2012. Considering a 10-year Treasury with coupon of 2.625 percent and maturity in exactly 10 years, the price would fall from 105.3512 corresponding to yield of 2.031 percent to 102.9428 corresponding to yield of 2.294 percent, for loss in a week of 2.3 percent but far more in a position with leverage of 10:1. Min Zeng, writing on “Treasurys fall, ending brutal quarter,” published on Mar 30, 2012, in the Wall Street Journal (http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052702303816504577313400029412564.html?mod=WSJ_hps_sections_markets), informs that Treasury bonds maturing in more than 20 years lost 5.52 percent in the first quarter of 2012

5. Credibility and Commitment of Central Bank Policy. There is a credibility issue of the commitment of monetary policy. The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) advised on its Apr 25, 2012 statement that: “To support a stronger economic recovery and to help ensure that inflation, over time, is at the rate most consistent with its dual mandate, the Committee expects to maintain a highly accommodative stance for monetary policy. In particular, the Committee decided today to keep the target range for the federal funds rate at 0 to ¼ percent and currently anticipates that economic conditions—including low rates of resource utilization and a subdued outlook for inflation over the medium run—are likely to warrant exceptionally low levels of the federal funds rate at least through late 2014” (http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20120425a.htm). At its meeting on Jan 25, the FOMC began to provide to the public the specific forecasts of interest rates and other economic variables by FOMC members. These forecasts are analyzed in Section IV Global Inflation. Thomas J. Sargent and William L. Silber, writing on “The challenges of the Fed’s bid for transparency,” on Mar 20, published in the Financial Times (http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/778eb1ce-7288-11e1-9c23-00144feab49a.html#axzz1pexRlsiQ), analyze the costs and benefits of transparency by the Fed. In the analysis of Sargent and Silber (2012Mar20), benefits of transparency by the Fed will exceed costs if the Fed is successful in conveying to the public what policies would be implemented and how forcibly in the presence of unforeseen economic events. History has been unkind to policy commitments. The risk in this case is if the Fed would postpone adjustment because of political pressures as has occurred in the past or because of errors of evaluation and forecasting of economic and financial conditions. Both political pressures and errors abounded in the unhappy stagflation of the 1970s also known as the US Great Inflation (see http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/05/slowing-growth-global-inflation-great.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/04/new-economics-of-rose-garden-turned.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/03/is-there-second-act-of-us-great.html and Appendix I The Great Inflation; see Taylor 1993, 1997, 1998LB, 1999, 2012FP, 2012Mar27, 2012Mar28, 2012JMCB and http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/rules-versus-discretionary-authorities.html). The challenge of the Fed, in the view of Sargent and Silber 2012Mar20), is to convey to the public the need to deviate from the commitment to interest rates of zero to ¼ percent because conditions have changed instead of unwarranted inaction or policy changes. Errors have abounded such as a critical cause of the global recession pointed by Sargent and Silber (2012Mar20): “While no president is known to have explicitly pressurized Mr. Bernanke’s predecessor, Alan Greenspan, he found it easy to maintain low interest rates for too long, fuelling the credit boom and housing bubble that led to the financial crisis in 2008.” Sargent and Silber (2012Mar20) also find need of commitment of fiscal authorities to consolidation needed to attain sustainable path of debt.

The analysis by Kydland and Prescott (1977, 447-80, equation 5) uses the “expectation augmented” Phillips curve with the natural rate of unemployment of Friedman (1968) and Phelps (1968), which in the notation of Barro and Gordon (1983, 592, equation 1) is:

Ut = Unt – α(πtπe) α > 0 (1)

Where Ut is the rate of unemployment at current time t, Unt is the natural rate of unemployment, πt is the current rate of inflation and πe is the expected rate of inflation by economic agents based on current information. Equation (1) expresses unemployment net of the natural rate of unemployment as a decreasing function of the gap between actual and expected rates of inflation. The system is completed by a social objective function, W, depending on inflation, π, and unemployment, U:

W = W(πt, Ut) (2)

The policymaker maximizes the preferences of the public, (2), subject to the constraint of the tradeoff of inflation and unemployment, (1). The total differential of W set equal to zero provides an indifference map in the Cartesian plane with ordered pairs (πt, Ut - Un) such that the consistent equilibrium is found at the tangency of an indifference curve and the Phillips curve in (1). The indifference curves are concave to the origin. The consistent policy is not optimal. Policymakers without discretionary powers following a rule of price stability would attain equilibrium with unemployment not higher than with the consistent policy. The optimal outcome is obtained by the rule of price stability, or zero inflation, and no more unemployment than under the consistent policy with nonzero inflation and the same unemployment. Taylor (1998LB) attributes the sustained boom of the US economy after the stagflation of the 1970s to following a monetary policy rule instead of discretion (see Taylor 1993, 1999).

6. Carry Trades. Commodity prices driven by zero interest rates have resumed their increasing path. Some analytical aspects of the carry trade are instructive (Pelaez and Pelaez, Globalization and the State, Vol. I (2008a), 101-5, Pelaez and Pelaez, Globalization and the State, Vol. II (2008b), 202-4), Government Intervention in Globalization: Regulation, Trade and Devaluation Wars (2008c), 70-4). Consider the following symbols: Rt is the exchange rate of a country receiving carry trade denoted in units of domestic currency per dollars at time t of initiation of the carry trade; Rt+τ is the exchange of the country receiving carry trade denoted in units of domestic currency per dollars at time t+τ when the carry trade is unwound; if is the domestic interest rate of the high-yielding country where investment will be made; iusd is the interest rate on short-term dollar debt assumed to be 0.5 percent per year; if >iusd, which expresses the fact that the interest rate on the foreign country is much higher than that in short-term USD (US dollars); St is the dollar value of the investment principal; and π is the dollar profit from the carry trade. The investment of the principal St in the local currency debt of the foreign country provides a profit of:

π = (1 + if)(RtSt)(1/Rt+τ) – (1 + iusd)St (3)

The profit from the carry trade, π, is nonnegative when:

(1 + if)/ (1 + iusd) ≥ Rt+τ/Rt (4)

In words, the difference in interest rate differentials, left-hand side of inequality (4), must exceed the percentage devaluation of the currency of the host country of the carry trade, right hand side of inequality (4). The carry trade must earn enough in the host-country interest rate to compensate for depreciation of the host-country at the time of return to USD. A simple example explains the vulnerability of the carry trade in fixed-income. Let if be 0.10 (10 percent), iusd 0.005 (0.5 percent), St USD100 and Rt CUR 1.00/USD. Adopt the fixed-income rule of months of 30 days and years of 360 days. Consider a strategy of investing USD 100 at 10 percent for 30 days with borrowing of USD 100 at 0.5 percent for 30 days. At time t, the USD 100 are converted into CUR 100 and invested at [(30/360)10] equal to 0.833 percent for thirty days. At the end of the 30 days, assume that the rate Rt+30 is still CUR 1/USD such that the return amount from the carry trade is USD 0.833. There is still a loan to be paid [(0.005)(30/360)USD100] equal to USD 0.042. The investor receives the net amount of USD 0.833 minus USD 0.042 or US 0.791. The rate of return on the investment of the USD 100 is 0.791 percent, which is equivalent to the annual rate of return of 9.49 percent {(0.791)(360/30)}. This is incomparably better than earning 0.5 percent. There are alternatives of hedging by buying forward the exchange for conversion back into USD.

Research by the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis finds that the dollar declined on average by 6.56 percent in the events of quantitative easing, ranging from depreciation of 10.8 percent relative to the Japanese yen to 3.6 percent relative to the pound sterling (http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/2010/2010-018.pdf). A critical assumption of Rudiger Dornbusch (1976) in his celebrated analysis of overshooting (Rogoff 2002MF http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2001/kr/112901.pdf) is “that exchange rates and asset markets adjust fast relative to goods markets” (Rudiger Dornbusch 1976, 1162). The market response of a monetary expansion is “to induce an immediate depreciation in the exchange rate and accounts therefore for fluctuations in the exchange rate and the terms of trade. During the adjustment process, rising prices may be accompanied by an appreciating exchange rate so that the trend behavior of exchange rates stands potentially in strong contrast with the cyclical behavior of exchange rates and prices” (Dornbusch 1976, 1162). The volatility of the exchange rate “is needed to temporarily equilibrate the system in response to monetary shocks, because underlying national prices adjust so slowly” (Rogoff 2002MF http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2001/kr/112901.pdf 3). The exchange rate “is identified as a critical channel for the transmission of monetary policy to aggregate demand for domestic output” (Dornbusch 1976, 1162).

In a world of exchange wars, depreciation of the host-country currency can move even faster such that the profits from the carry trade may become major losses. Depreciation is the percentage change in instants against which the interest rate of a day is in the example [(10)(1/360)] or 0.03 percent. Exchange rates move much faster in the real world as in the overshooting model of Dornbusch (1976). Profits in carry trades have greater risks but equally greater returns when the short position in zero interest rates, or borrowing, and on the dollar, are matched with truly agile financial risk assets such as commodities and equities. A simplified analysis could consider the portfolio balance equations Aij = f(r, x) where Aij is the demand for i = 1,2,∙∙∙n assets from j = 1,2, ∙∙∙m sectors, r the 1xn vector of rates of return, ri, of n assets and x a vector of other relevant variables. Tobin (1969) and Brunner and Meltzer (1973) assume imperfect substitution among capital assets such that the own first derivatives of Aij are positive, demand for an asset increases if its rate of return (interest plus capital gains) is higher, and cross first derivatives are negative, demand for an asset decreases if the rate of return of alternative assets increases. Theoretical purity would require the estimation of the complete model with all rates of return. In practice, it may be impossible to observe all rates of return such as in the critique of Roll (1976). Policy proposals and measures by the Fed have been focused on the likely impact of withdrawals of stocks of securities in specific segments, that is, of effects of one or several specific rates of return among the n possible rates. In fact, the central bank cannot influence investors and arbitrageurs to allocate funds to assets of desired categories such as asset-backed securities that would lower the costs of borrowing for mortgages and consumer loans. Floods of cheap money may simply induce carry trades in arbitrage of opportunities in fast moving assets such as currencies, commodities and equities instead of much lower returns in fixed income securities (see http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/07/causes-of-2007-creditdollar-crisis.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/professor-mckinnons-bubble-economy.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/world-inflation-quantitative-easing.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/treasury-yields-valuation-of-risk.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2010/11/quantitative-easing-theory-evidence-and.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2010/12/is-fed-printing-money-what-are.html).

It is in this context of economic and financial uncertainties that decisions on portfolio choices of risk financial assets must be made. There is a new carry trade that learned from the losses after the crisis of 2007 or learned from the crisis how to avoid losses. The sharp rise in valuations of risk financial assets shown in Table VI-1 after the first policy round of near zero fed funds and quantitative easing by the equivalent of withdrawing supply with the suspension of the 30-year Treasury auction was on a smooth trend with relatively subdued fluctuations. The credit crisis and global recession have been followed by significant fluctuations originating in sovereign risk issues in Europe, doubts of continuing high growth and accelerating inflation in China now complicated by political developments, events such as in the Middle East and Japan and legislative restructuring, regulation, insufficient growth, falling real wages, depressed hiring and high job stress of unemployment and underemployment in the US now with realization of growth standstill. The “trend is your friend” motto of traders has been replaced with a “hit and realize profit” approach of managing positions to realize profits without sitting on positions. There is a trend of valuation of risk financial assets driven by the carry trade from zero interest rates with fluctuations provoked by events of risk aversion or the “sharp shifts in risk appetite” of Blanchard (2012WEOApr, XIII). Table VI-4, which is updated for every comment of this blog, shows the deep contraction of valuations of risk financial assets after the Apr 2010 sovereign risk issues in the fourth column “∆% to Trough.” There was sharp recovery after around Jul 2010 in the last column “∆% Trough to 6/15/12,” which has been recently stalling or reversing amidst profound risk aversion. “Let’s twist again” monetary policy during the week of Sep 23 caused deep worldwide risk aversion and selloff of risk financial assets (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/imf-view-of-world-economy-and-finance.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/09/collapse-of-household-income-and-wealth.html). Monetary policy was designed to increase risk appetite but instead suffocated risk exposures. There has been rollercoaster fluctuation in risk aversion and financial risk asset valuations: surge in the week of Dec 2, mixed performance of markets in the week of Dec 9, renewed risk aversion in the week of Dec 16, end-of-the-year relaxed risk aversion in thin markets in the weeks of Dec 23 and Dec 30, mixed sentiment in the weeks of Jan 6 and Jan 13 2012 and strength in the weeks of Jan 20, Jan 27 and Feb 3 followed by weakness in the week of Feb 10 but strength in the weeks of Feb 17 and 24 followed by uncertainty on financial counterparty risk in the weeks of Mar 2 and Mar 9. All financial values have fluctuated with events such as the surge in the week of Mar 16 on favorable news of Greece’s bailout even with new risk issues arising in the week of Mar 23 but renewed risk appetite in the week of Mar 30 because of the end of the quarter and the increase in the firewall of support of sovereign debts in the euro area. New risks developed in the week of Apr 6 with increase of yields of sovereign bonds of Spain and Italy, doubts on Fed policy and weak employment report. Asia and financial entities are experiencing their own risk environments. Financial markets were under stress in the week of Apr 13 because of the large exposure of Spanish banks to lending by the European Central Bank and the annual equivalent growth rate of China’s GDP of 7.4 percent in IQ2012 [(1.018)4]. There was strength again in the week of Apr 20 because of the enhanced IMF firewall and Spain placement of debt, continuing into the week of Apr 27. Risk aversion returned in the week of May 4 because of the expectation of elections in Europe and the new trend of deterioration of job creation in the US. Europe’s sovereign debt crisis and the fractured US job market continued to influence risk aversion in the week of May 11. Politics in Greece and banking issues in Spain were important factors of sharper risk aversion in the week of May 18. Risk aversion continued during the week of May 25 and exploded in the week of Jun 1. Expectations of stimulus by central banks caused valuation of risk financial assets in the week of Jun 8 and in the week of Jun 15. The highest valuations in column “∆% Trough to 6/15/12” are by US equities indexes: DJIA 31.8 percent and S&P 500 31.3 percent, driven by stronger earnings and economy in the US than in other advanced economies but with doubts on the relation of business revenue to the weakening economy and fractured job market. The DJIA reached 13,331.77 in intraday trading on Mar 16, which is the highest level in 52 weeks (http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/public/page/marketsdata.html?mod=WSJ_PRO_hps_marketdata). The carry trade from zero interest rates to leveraged positions in risk financial assets had proved strongest for commodity exposures but US equities have regained leadership. Before the current round of risk aversion, almost all assets in the column “∆% Trough to 6/15/12” had double digit gains relative to the trough around Jul 2, 2010 but now most valuations of equity indexes show increase of less than 10 percent: China’s Shanghai Composite is 3.2 percent below the trough; STOXX 50 of Europe is 1.0 percent above the trough; Japan’s Nikkei Average is 2.9 percent below the trough; DJ Asia Pacific TSM is 1.8 percent above the trough; Dow Global is 5.1 percent above the trough; and NYSE Financial is 2.6 percent above the trough. DJ UBS Commodities is 3.9 percent above the trough. DAX is 9.9 percent above the trough. Japan’s Nikkei Average is 2.9 percent below the trough on Aug 31, 2010 and 24.8 percent below the peak on Apr 5, 2010. The Nikkei Average closed at 8569.32 on Fri Jun 15, 2012 (http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/public/page/marketsdata.html?mod=WSJ_PRO_hps_marketdata), which is 16.4 percent lower than 10,254.43 on Mar 11, 2011, on the date of the Tōhoku or Great East Japan Earthquake/tsunami. Global risk aversion erased the earlier gains of the Nikkei. The dollar depreciated by 6.0 percent relative to the euro and even higher before the new bout of sovereign risk issues in Europe. The column “∆% week to 6/15/12” in Table VI-4 shows that there were increases of all valuations of risk financial assets in the week of Jun 15, 2012 such as 2.2 percent for DJ Asia Pacific, 1.3 percent for Nikkei Average, 1.1 percent for the Shanghai Composite and 1.8 percent for STOXX 50. DJ UBS Commodities remained flat. Other valuations also increased such as 1.7 percent for DJIA, 1.3 percent for S&P 500, 1.9 percent for NYSE Financial, 1.7 percent for Dow Global and 1.6 percent for DAX. There are still high uncertainties on European sovereign risks, US and world growth slowdown and China’s growth tradeoffs. Sovereign problems in the “periphery” of Europe and fears of slower growth in Asia and the US cause risk aversion with trading caution instead of more aggressive risk exposures. There is a fundamental change in Table VI-4 from the relatively upward trend with oscillations since the sovereign risk event of Apr-Jul 2010. Performance is best assessed in the column “∆% Peak to 6/15/12” that provides the percentage change from the peak in Apr 2010 before the sovereign risk event to Jun 8, 2012. Most risk financial assets had gained not only relative to the trough as shown in column “∆% Trough to 6/15/12” but also relative to the peak in column “∆% Peak to 6/15/12.” There are now only two equity indexes above the peak in Table VI-4: DJIA 13.9 percent and S&P 500 10.3 percent. There are several indexes below the peak: NYSE Financial Index (http://www.nyse.com/about/listed/nykid.shtml) by 18.3 percent, Nikkei Average by 24.8 percent, Shanghai Composite by 27.1 percent, DJ Asia Pacific by 10.9 percent, STOXX 50 by 14.4 percent, DAX by 1.6 percent and Dow Global by 14.3 percent. DJ UBS Commodities Index is now 11.2 percent below the peak. The factors of risk aversion have adversely affected the performance of risk financial assets. The performance relative to the peak in Apr 2010 is more important than the performance relative to the trough around early Jul 2010 because improvement could signal that conditions have returned to normal levels before European sovereign doubts in Apr 2010. An intriguing issue is the difference in performance of valuations of risk financial assets and economic growth and employment. Paul A. Samuelson (http://www.nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economics/laureates/1970/samuelson-bio.html) popularized the view of the elusive relation between stock markets and economic activity in an often-quoted phrase “the stock market has predicted nine of the last five recessions.” In the presence of zero interest rates forever, valuations of risk financial assets are likely to differ from the performance of the overall economy. The interrelations of financial and economic variables prove difficult to analyze and measure.

Table VI-4, Stock Indexes, Commodities, Dollar and 10-Year Treasury  

 

Peak

Trough

∆% to Trough

∆% Peak to 6/15

/12

∆% Week 6/15/ 12

∆% Trough to 6/15

12

DJIA

4/26/
10

7/2/10

-13.6

13.9

1.7

31.8

S&P 500

4/23/
10

7/20/
10

-16.0

10.3

1.3

31.3

NYSE Finance

4/15/
10

7/2/10

-20.3

-18.3

1.9

2.6

Dow Global

4/15/
10

7/2/10

-18.4

-14.3

1.7

5.1

Asia Pacific

4/15/
10

7/2/10

-12.5

-10.9

2.2

1.8

Japan Nikkei Aver.

4/05/
10

8/31/
10

-22.5

-24.8

1.3

-2.9

China Shang.

4/15/
10

7/02
/10

-24.7

-27.1

1.1

-3.2

STOXX 50

4/15/10

7/2/10

-15.3

-14.4

1.8

1.0

DAX

4/26/
10

5/25/
10

-10.5

-1.6

1.6

9.9

Dollar
Euro

11/25 2009

6/7
2010

21.2

16.5

-1.0

-6.0

DJ UBS Comm.

1/6/
10

7/2/10

-14.5

-11.2

0.0

3.9

10-Year T Note

4/5/
10

4/6/10

3.986

1.584

   

T: trough; Dollar: positive sign appreciation relative to euro (less dollars paid per euro), negative sign depreciation relative to euro (more dollars paid per euro)

Source: http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/page/marketsdata.html?mod=WSJ_hps_marketdata

Bernanke (2010WP) and Yellen (2011AS) reveal the emphasis of monetary policy on the impact of the rise of stock market valuations in stimulating consumption by wealth effects on household confidence. Table VI-5 shows a gain by Apr 29, 2011 in the DJIA of 14.3 percent and of the S&P 500 of 12.5 percent since Apr 26, 2010, around the time when sovereign risk issues in Europe began to be acknowledged in financial risk asset valuations. The last row of Table VI-5 for Jun 15, 2012, shows that the S&P 500 is now 10.8 percent above the Apr 26, 2010 level and the DJIA is 13.9 percent above the level on Apr 26, 2010. Multiple rounds of risk aversion eroded earlier gains, showing that risk aversion can destroy market value even with zero interest rates. Relaxed risk aversion has contributed to recovery of valuations. Much the same as zero interest rates and quantitative easing have not had any effects in recovering economic activity while distorting financial markets and resource allocation.

Table VI-5, Percentage Changes of DJIA and S&P 500 in Selected Dates

2010

∆% DJIA from  prior date

∆% DJIA from
Apr 26

∆% S&P 500 from prior date

∆% S&P 500 from
Apr 26

Apr 26

       

May 6

-6.1

-6.1

-6.9

-6.9

May 26

-5.2

-10.9

-5.4

-11.9

Jun 8

-1.2

-11.3

2.1

-12.4

Jul 2

-2.6

-13.6

-3.8

-15.7

Aug 9

10.5

-4.3

10.3

-7.0

Aug 31

-6.4

-10.6

-6.9

-13.4

Nov 5

14.2

2.1

16.8

1.0

Nov 30

-3.8

-3.8

-3.7

-2.6

Dec 17

4.4

2.5

5.3

2.6

Dec 23

0.7

3.3

1.0

3.7

Dec 31

0.03

3.3

0.07

3.8

Jan 7

0.8

4.2

1.1

4.9

Jan 14

0.9

5.2

1.7

6.7

Jan 21

0.7

5.9

-0.8

5.9

Jan 28

-0.4

5.5

-0.5

5.3

Feb 4

2.3

7.9

2.7

8.1

Feb 11

1.5

9.5

1.4

9.7

Feb 18

0.9

10.6

1.0

10.8

Feb 25

-2.1

8.3

-1.7

8.9

Mar 4

0.3

8.6

0.1

9.0

Mar 11

-1.0

7.5

-1.3

7.6

Mar 18

-1.5

5.8

-1.9

5.5

Mar 25

3.1

9.1

2.7

8.4

Apr 1

1.3

10.5

1.4

9.9

Apr 8

0.03

10.5

-0.3

9.6

Apr 15

-0.3

10.1

-0.6

8.9

Apr 22

1.3

11.6

1.3

10.3

Apr 29

2.4

14.3

1.9

12.5

May 6

-1.3

12.8

-1.7

10.6

May 13

-0.3

12.4

-0.2

10.4

May 20

-0.7

11.7

-0.3

10.0

May 27

-0.6

11.0

-0.2

9.8

Jun 3

-2.3

8.4

-2.3

7.3

Jun 10

-1.6

6.7

-2.2

4.9

Jun 17

0.4

7.1

0.04

4.9

Jun 24

-0.6

6.5

-0.2

4.6

Jul 1

5.4

12.3

5.6

10.5

Jul 8

0.6

12.9

0.3

10.9

Jul 15

-1.4

11.4

-2.1

8.6

Jul 22

1.6

13.2

2.2

10.9

Jul 29

-4.2

8.4

-3.9

6.6

Aug 05

-5.8

2.1

-7.2

-1.0

Aug 12

-1.5

0.6

-1.7

-2.7

Aug 19

-4.0

-3.5

-4.7

-7.3

Aug 26

4.3

0.7

4.7

-2.9

Sep 02

-0.4

0.3

-0.2

-3.1

Sep 09

-2.2

-1.9

-1.7

-4.8

Sep 16

4.7

2.7

5.4

0.3

Sep 23

-6.4

-3.9

-6.5

-6.2

Sep 30

1.3

-2.6

-0.4

-6.7

Oct 7

1.7

-0.9

2.1

-4.7

Oct 14

4.9

3.9

5.9

1.0

Oct 21

1.4

5.4

1.1

2.2

Oct 28

3.6

9.2

3.8

6.0

Nov 04

-2.0

6.9

-2.5

3.4

Nov 11

1.4

8.5

0.8

4.3

Nov 18

-2.9

5.3

-3.8

0.3

Nov 25

-4.8

0.2

-4.7

-4.4

Dec 02

7.0

7.3

7.4

2.7

Dec 09

1.4

8.7

0.9

3.6

Dec 16

-2.6

5.9

-2.8

0.6

Dec 23

3.6

9.7

3.7

4.4

Dec 30

-0.6

9.0

-0.6

3.8

Jan 6 2012

1.2

10.3

1.6

5.4

Jan 13

0.5

10.9

0.9

6.4

Jan 20

2.4

13.5

2.0

8.5

Jan 27

-0.5

13.0

0.1

8.6

Feb 3

1.6

14.8

2.2

11.0

Feb 10

-0.5

14.2

-0.2

10.8

Feb 17

1.2

15.6

1.4

12.3

Feb 24

0.3

15.9

0.3

12.7

Mar 2

0.0

15.8

0.3

13.0

Mar 9

-0.4

15.3

0.1

13.1

Mar 16

2.4

18.1

2.4

15.9

Mar 23

-1.1

16.7

-0.5

15.3

Mar 30

1.0

17.9

0.8

16.2

Apr 6

-1.1

16.6

-0.7

15.3

Apr 13

-1.6

14.7

-2.0

13.1

Apr 20

1.4

16.3

0.6

13.7

Apr 27

1.5

18.1

1.8

15.8

May 4

-1.4

16.4

-2.3

12.9

May 11

-1.7

14.4

-1.1

11.7

May 18

-3.5

10.4

-4.3

6.4

May 25

0.7

11.2

1.7

8.7

Jun 1

-2.7

8.2

-3.0

5.4

Jun 8

3.6

12.0

3.7

9.4

Jun 15

1.7

13.9

1.3

10.8

Source: http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/public/page/mdc_us_stocks.html?mod=mdc_topnav_2_3014

Table VI-6, updated with every blog comment, shows that exchange rate valuations affect a large variety of countries, in fact, almost the entire world, in magnitudes that cause major problems for domestic monetary policy and trade flows. Dollar devaluation is expected to continue because of zero fed funds rate, expectations of rising inflation, large budget deficit of the federal government (http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052748703907004576279321350926848.html?mod=WSJ_hp_LEFTWhatsNewsCollection) and now zero interest rates indefinitely but with interruptions caused by risk aversion events. Such an event actually occurred in the week of Sep 23 reversing the devaluation of the dollar in the form of sharp appreciation of the dollar relative to other currencies from all over the world including the offshore Chinese yuan market. Column “Peak” in Table VI-6 shows exchange rates during the crisis year of 2008. There was a flight to safety in dollar-denominated government assets as a result of the arguments in favor of TARP (Cochrane and Zingales 2009). This is evident in various exchange rates that depreciated sharply against the dollar such as the South African rand (ZAR) at the peak of depreciation of ZAR 11.578/USD on Oct 22, 2008, subsequently appreciating to the trough of ZAR 7.238/USD by Aug 15, 2010 but now depreciating by 15.5 percent to ZAR 8.3609/USD on Jun 15, 2012, which is still 27.8 percent stronger than on Oct 22, 2008. An example from Asia is the Singapore Dollar (SGD) highly depreciated at the peak of SGD 1.553/USD on Mar 3, 2009 but subsequently appreciating by 13.2 percent to the trough of SGD 1.348/USD on Aug 9, 2010 but is now only 4.8 percent stronger at SGD 1.2706/USD on Jun 15, 2012 relative to the trough of depreciation but still stronger by 18.2 percent relative to the peak of depreciation on Mar 3, 2009. Another example is the Brazilian real (BRL) that depreciated at the peak to BRL 2.43/USD on Dec 5, 2008 but appreciated 28.5 percent to the trough at BRL 1.737/USD on Apr 30, 2010, showing depreciation of 16.5 percent relative to the trough to BRL 2.0528/USD on Jun 15, 2012 but still stronger by 15.5 percent relative to the peak on Dec 5, 2008. At one point in 2011 the Brazilian real traded at BRL 1.55/USD and in the week of Sep 23 surpassed BRL 1.90/USD in intraday trading for depreciation of more than 20 percent. The Banco Central do Brasil, Brazil’s central bank, lowered its policy rate SELIC by 50 basis points for the sixth consecutive meeting of its monetary policy committee, COPOM (http://www.bcb.gov.br/textonoticia.asp?codigo=3554&IDPAI=NEWS):

“Copom reduces the Selic rate to 8.5 percent

30/05/2012 8:04:00 PM

Brasília - Continuing the adjustment process of monetary conditions, the Copom unanimously decided to reduce the Selic rate to 8.50 percent.”

Jeffrey T. Lewis, writing on “Brazil steps up battle to curb real’s rise,” on Mar 1, 2012, published in the Wall Street Journal (http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052970203986604577255793224099580.html?mod=WSJ_hp_LEFTWhatsNewsCollection), analyzes new measures by Brazil to prevent further appreciation of its currency, including the extension of the tax on foreign capital for three years terms, subsequently broadened to five years, and intervention in the foreign exchange market by the central bank. Unconventional monetary policy of zero interest rates and quantitative easing creates trends such as the depreciation of the dollar followed by Table VI-6 but with abrupt reversals during risk aversion. The main effects of unconventional monetary policy are on valuations of risk financial assets and not necessarily on consumption and investment or aggregate demand.

Table VI-6, Exchange Rates

 

Peak

Trough

∆% P/T

Jun 15, 2012

∆% T

Jun 15, 2012

∆% P

Jun 15,

2012

EUR USD

7/15
2008

6/7 2010

 

6/15

2012

   

Rate

1.59

1.192

 

1.2640

   

∆%

   

-33.4

 

5.7

-25.8

JPY USD

8/18
2008

9/15
2010

 

6/15

2012

   

Rate

110.19

83.07

 

78.71

   

∆%

   

24.6

 

5.2

28.6

CHF USD

11/21 2008

12/8 2009

 

6/15

2012

   

Rate

1.225

1.025

 

0.9502

   

∆%

   

16.3

 

7.3

22.4

USD GBP

7/15
2008

1/2/ 2009

 

6/15 2012

   

Rate

2.006

1.388

 

1.5715

   

∆%

   

-44.5

 

11.7

-27.6

USD AUD

7/15 2008

10/27 2008

 

6/15
2012

   

Rate

1.0215

1.6639

 

1.0081

   

∆%

   

-62.9

 

40.4

2.9

ZAR USD

10/22 2008

8/15
2010

 

6/15 2012

   

Rate

11.578

7.238

 

8.3609

   

∆%

   

37.5

 

-15.5

27.8

SGD USD

3/3
2009

8/9
2010

 

6/15
2012

   

Rate

1.553

1.348

 

1.2706

   

∆%

   

13.2

 

5.7

18.2

HKD USD

8/15 2008

12/14 2009

 

6/15
2012

   

Rate

7.813

7.752

 

7.7598

   

∆%

   

0.8

 

-0.1

0.7

BRL USD

12/5 2008

4/30 2010

 

6/15

2012

   

Rate

2.43

1.737

 

2.0528

   

∆%

   

28.5

 

-18.2

15.5

CZK USD

2/13 2009

8/6 2010

 

6/15
2012

   

Rate

22.19

18.693

 

20.113

   

∆%

   

15.7

 

-7.6

9.4

SEK USD

3/4 2009

8/9 2010

 

6/15

2012

   

Rate

9.313

7.108

 

6.9996

   

∆%

   

23.7

 

1.6

24.8

CNY USD

7/20 2005

7/15
2008

 

6/15
2012

   

Rate

8.2765

6.8211

 

6.3678

   

∆%

   

17.6

 

6.6

23.1

Symbols: USD: US dollar; EUR: euro; JPY: Japanese yen; CHF: Swiss franc; GBP: UK pound; AUD: Australian dollar; ZAR: South African rand; SGD: Singapore dollar; HKD: Hong Kong dollar; BRL: Brazil real; CZK: Czech koruna; SEK: Swedish krona; CNY: Chinese yuan; P: peak; T: trough

Note: percentages calculated with currencies expressed in units of domestic currency per dollar; negative sign means devaluation and no sign appreciation

Source: http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/public/page/mdc_currencies.html?mod=mdc_topnav_2_3000

http://federalreserve.gov/releases/h10/Hist/dat00_ch.htm

Chart VI-1 of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System provides indexes of the dollar from 2010 to 2012. The dollar depreciates during episodes of risk appetite but appreciate during risk aversion as funds seek dollar-denominated assets in avoiding financial risk.

clip_image032

Chart VI-1, US Dollar Currency Indexes

Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

http://www.federalreserve.gov/DataDownload/Chart.aspx?rel=H10&series=122e3bcb627e8e53f1bf72a1a09cfb81&lastObs=260&from=&to=&filetype=csv&label=include&layout=seriescolumn&pp=Download&names=%7bH10/H10/JRXWTFB_N.B,H10/H10/JRXWTFN_N.B,H10/H10/JRXWTFO_N.B%7d

Chart VI-2 of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System provides the exchange rate of the US relative to the euro, or USD/EUR. During maintenance of the policy of zero fed funds rates the dollar appreciates during periods of significant risk aversion such as the flight into US government obligations in late 2008 and early 2009 and during the various fears generated by the European sovereign debt crisis.

clip_image034

Chart VI-2, US Dollars per Euro, 2009-2012

Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

http://www.federalreserve.gov/DataDownload/Chart.aspx?rel=H10&series=e85cfb140ce469e13bec458013262fa1&lastObs=780&from=&to=&filetype=csv&label=include&layout=seriescolumn&pp=Download&names=%7bH10/H10/RXI$US_N.B.EU%7d

Table VI-7, updated with every blog comment, provides in the second column the yield at the close of market of the 10-year Treasury note on the date in the first column. The price in the third column is calculated with the coupon of 2.625 percent of the 10-year note current at the time of the second round of quantitative easing after Nov 3, 2010 and the final column “∆% 11/04/10” calculates the percentage change of the price on the date relative to that of 101.2573 at the close of market on Nov 4, 2010, one day after the decision on quantitative easing by the Fed on Nov 3, 2010. Prices with new coupons such as 2.0 percent in recent auctions (http://www.treasurydirect.gov/RI/OFAuctions?form=extended&cusip=912828RR3) are not comparable to prices in Table VI-7. The highest yield in the decade was 5.510 percent on May 1, 2001 that would result in a loss of principal of 22.9 percent relative to the price on Nov 4. Monetary policy has created a “duration trap” of bond prices. Duration is the percentage change in bond price resulting from a percentage change in yield or what economists call the yield elasticity of bond price. Duration is higher the lower the bond coupon and yield, all other things constant. This means that the price loss in a yield rise from low coupons and yields is much higher than with high coupons and yields. Intuitively, the higher coupon payments offset part of the price loss. Prices/yields of Treasury securities were affected by the combination of Fed purchases for its program of quantitative easing and also by the flight to dollar-denominated assets because of geopolitical risks in the Middle East, subsequently by the tragic Great East Japan Earthquake and Tsunami and now again by the sovereign risk doubts in Europe and the growth recession in the US and the world. The yield of 1.548 percent at the close of market on Fri Jun 15, 2012 would be equivalent to price of 109.5924 in a hypothetical bond maturing in 10 years with coupon of 2.625 percent for price gain of 8.2 percent relative to the price on Nov 4, 2010, one day after the decision on the second program of quantitative easing, as shown in the first to the last row of Table VI-7. The price loss between Jun 1, 2012 and Jun 8, 2012 would have been 1.6 percent, in just a week, and much higher with leverage of 10:1 as typical in Treasury positions. The price loss between Mar 9, 2012 and Mar 16, 2012 is 2.3 percent but much higher when using common leverage of 10:1. These losses defy annualizing. If inflation accelerates, yields of Treasury securities may rise sharply. Yields are not observed without special yield-lowering effects such as the flight into dollars caused by the events in the Middle East, continuing purchases of Treasury securities by the Fed, the tragic Tōhoku or Great East Earthquake and Tsunami of Mar 11, 2011 affecting Japan, recurring fears on European sovereign credit issues and worldwide risk aversion in the week of Sep 30 caused by “let’s twist again” monetary policy. The realization of a growth standstill recession is also influencing yields. Important causes of the earlier rise in yields shown in Table VI-7 are expectations of rising inflation and US government debt estimated to be around 70 percent of GDP in 2012 (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/02/thirty-one-million-unemployed-or.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/08/united-states-gdp-growth-standstill.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/02/policy-inflation-growth-unemployment.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/04/budget-quagmire-fed-commodities_10.html), rising from 40.5 percent of GDP in 2008, 54.1 percent in 2009 (Table IV-1 at http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/02/thirty-one-million-unemployed-or.html and Table 2 in http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/04/budget-quagmire-fed-commodities_10.html) and 67.7 percent in 2011. On Jun 13, 2012, the line “Reserve Bank credit” in the Fed balance sheet stood at $2852 billion, or $2.8 trillion, with portfolio of long-term securities of $2594 billion, or $2.6 trillion, consisting of $1566 billion Treasury nominal notes and bonds, $67 billion of notes and bonds inflation-indexed, $93 billion Federal agency debt securities and $868 billion mortgage-backed securities; reserve balances deposited with Federal Reserve Banks reached $1565 billion or $1.6 trillion (http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h41/current/h41.htm#h41tab1). There is no simple exit of this trap created by the highest monetary policy accommodation in US history together with the highest deficits and debt in percent of GDP since World War II. Risk aversion from various sources, discussed in section III World Financial Turbulence, has been affecting financial markets for several months. The risk is that in a reversal of risk aversion that has been typical in this cyclical expansion of the economy yields of Treasury securities may back up sharply.

Table VI-7, Yield, Price and Percentage Change to November 4, 2010 of Ten-Year Treasury Note

Date

Yield

Price

∆% 11/04/10

05/01/01

5.510

78.0582

-22.9

06/10/03

3.112

95.8452

-5.3

06/12/07

5.297

79.4747

-21.5

12/19/08

2.213

104.4981

3.2

12/31/08

2.240

103.4295

2.1

03/19/09

2.605

100.1748

-1.1

06/09/09

3.862

89.8257

-11.3

10/07/09

3.182

95.2643

-5.9

11/27/09

3.197

95.1403

-6.0

12/31/09

3.835

90.0347

-11.1

02/09/10

3.646

91.5239

-9.6

03/04/10

3.605

91.8384

-9.3

04/05/10

3.986

88.8726

-12.2

08/31/10

2.473

101.3338

0.08

10/07/10

2.385

102.1224

0.8

10/28/10

2.658

99.7119

-1.5

11/04/10

2.481

101.2573

-

11/15/10

2.964

97.0867

-4.1

11/26/10

2.869

97.8932

-3.3

12/03/10

3.007

96.7241

-4.5

12/10/10

3.324

94.0982

-7.1

12/15/10

3.517

92.5427

-8.6

12/17/10

3.338

93.9842

-7.2

12/23/10

3.397

93.5051

-7.7

12/31/10

3.228

94.3923

-6.7

01/07/11

3.322

94.1146

-7.1

01/14/11

3.323

94.1064

-7.1

01/21/11

3.414

93.4687

-7.7

01/28/11

3.323

94.1064

-7.1

02/04/11

3.640

91.750

-9.4

02/11/11

3.643

91.5319

-9.6

02/18/11

3.582

92.0157

-9.1

02/25/11

3.414

93.3676

-7.8

03/04/11

3.494

92.7235

-8.4

03/11/11

3.401

93.4727

-7.7

03/18/11

3.273

94.5115

-6.7

03/25/11

3.435

93.1935

-7.9

04/01/11

3.445

93.1129

-8.0

04/08/11

3.576

92.0635

-9.1

04/15/11

3.411

93.3874

-7.8

04/22/11

3.402

93.4646

-7.7

04/29/11

3.290

94.3759

-6.8

05/06/11

3.147

95.5542

-5.6

05/13/11

3.173

95.3387

-5.8

05/20/11

3.146

95.5625

-5.6

05/27/11

3.068

96.2089

-4.9

06/03/11

2.990

96.8672

-4.3

06/10/11

2.973

97.0106

-4.2

06/17/11

2.937

97.3134

-3.9

06/24/11

2.872

97.8662

-3.3

07/01/11

3.186

95.2281

-5.9

07/08/11

3.022

96.5957

-4.6

07/15/11

2.905

97.5851

-3.6

07/22/11

2.964

97.0847

-4.1

07/29/11

2.795

98.5258

-2.7

08/05/11

2.566

100.5175

-0.7

08/12/11

2.249

103.3504

2.1

08/19/11

2.066

105.270

3.7

08/26/11

2.202

103.7781

2.5

09/02/11

1.992

105.7137

4.4

09/09/11

1.918

106.4055

5.1

09/16/11

2.053

101.5434

0.3

09/23/11

1.826

107.2727

5.9

09/30/11

1.912

106.4602

5.1

10/07/11

2.078

104.9161

3.6

10/14/11

2.251

103.3323

2.0

10/21/11

2.220

103.6141

2.3

10/28/11

2.326

102.6540

1.4

11/04/11

2.066

105.0270

3.7

11/11/11

2.057

105.1103

3.8

11/18/11

2.003

105.6113

4.3

11/25/11

1.964

105.9749

4.7

12/02/11

2.042

105.2492

3.9

12/09/11

2.065

105.0363

3.7

12/16/11

1.847

107.0741

5.7

12/23/11

2.027

105.3883

4.1

12/30/11

1.871

106.8476

5.5

01/06/12

1.957

106.0403

4.7

01/13/12

1.869

106.8664

5.5

01/20/12

2.026

105.3976

4.1

01/27/12

1.893

106.6404

5.3

02/03/12

1.923

106.3586

5.0

02/10/12

1.974

105.8815

4.6

02/17/12

2.000

105.6392

4.3

02/24/12

1.977

105.8535

4.5

03/02/12

1.977

105.8535

4.5

03/09/12

2.031

105.3512

4.0

03/16/12

2.294

102.9428

1.7

03/23/12

2.234

103.4867

2.2

03/30/12

2.214

103.6687

2.4

04/06/12

2.058

105.1010

3.8

04/13/12

1.987

105.7603

4.4

04/20/12

1.959

106.0216

4.7

04/27/12

1.931

106.2836

5.0

05/04/12

1.876

106.8004

5.5

05/11/12

1.845

107.0930

5.8

05/18/12

1.714

108.3393

7.0

05/25/12

1.738

108.1098

6.8

06/01/12

1.454

110.8618

9.5

06/08/12

1.635

109.0989

7.7

06/15/12

1.584

109.5924

8.2

Note: price is calculated for an artificial 10-year note paying semi-annual coupon and maturing in ten years using the actual yields traded on the dates and the coupon of 2.625% on 11/04/10

Source:

http://professional.wsj.com/mdc/public/page/mdc_bonds.html?mod=mdc_topnav_2_3000

VII Economic Indicators. Crude oil input in refineries increased 0.9 percent to 15,311 thousand barrels per day on average in the four weeks ending on Jun 8, 2012 from 15,167 thousand barrels per day in the four weeks ending on Jun 1, 2012, as shown in Table VII-1. The rate of capacity utilization in refineries continues at a relatively high level of 90.0 percent on Jun 8, 2012, which is higher than 86.4 percent on Jun 10, 2011 and higher than 89.1 percent on Jun 1, 2012. Imports of crude oil increased 0.7 percent from 8,830 thousand barrels per day on average in the four weeks ending on Jun 1 to 8,889 thousand barrels per day in the week of Jun 8. The Energy Information Administration (EIA) informs that “US crude oil imports averaged 9.1 million barrels per day last week, up by 160 thousand barrels per day from the previous week [Jun 1]” (http://www.eia.gov/pub/oil_gas/petroleum/data_publications/weekly_petroleum_status_report/current/pdf/highlights.pdf). Increasing utilization in refineries with increasing imports at the margin in the prior week resulted in decrease of commercial crude oil stocks by 0.2 million barrels from 384.6 million barrels on Jun 1 to 384.4 million barrels on Jun 8. Motor gasoline production increased 1.2 percent to 9,176 thousand barrels per day in the week of Jun 8 from 9,063 thousand barrels per day on average in the week of Jun 1. Gasoline stocks decreased 1.7 million barrels and stocks of fuel oil were unaltered. Supply of gasoline decreased from 9,247 thousand barrels per day on Jun 10, 2011, to 8,836 thousand barrels per day on Jun 8, 2012, or by 4.4 percent, while fuel oil supply decreased 4.6 percent. Part of the fall in consumption of gasoline is due to high prices and part to the growth recession. WTI crude oil price traded at $84.08/barrel on Jun 8, 2012, decreasing 15.3 percent relative to $99.30/barrel on Jun 10, 2011. Gasoline prices fell 3.8 percent from Jun 13, 2011 to Jun 11, 2012. Increases in prices of crude oil and gasoline relative to a year earlier are moderating because year earlier prices are already reflecting the commodity price surge and commodity prices have been declining recently during worldwide risk aversion. Gasoline prices had been increasing to the highest levels at this time of the year.

Table VII-1, US, Energy Information Administration Weekly Petroleum Status Report

Four Weeks Ending Thousand Barrels/Day

6/8/12

6/1/12

6/10/11

Crude Oil Refineries Input

15,311

Week       ∆%: 0.9

15,167

14,918

Refinery Capacity Utilization %

90.0

89.1

86.4

Motor Gasoline Production

9,176

Week      ∆%: 1.2

9,063

9,402

Distillate Fuel Oil Production

4,627

Week     ∆%: 1.2

4,572

4,317

Crude Oil Imports

8,889

Week        ∆%: 0.7

8,830

8,963

Motor Gasoline Supplied

8,836

∆% 2012/2011=

-4.4%

8,796

9,247

Distillate Fuel Oil Supplied

3,633

∆% 2012/2011

= -4.6%

3,624

3,809

 

6/8/12

6/1/12

6/10/11

Crude Oil Stocks
Million B

384.4     ∆= -0.2 MB

384.6

365.6

Motor Gasoline Million B

201.8  

∆= -1.7 MB

203.5

215.1

Distillate Fuel Oil Million B

120.0
∆= 0.0 MB

120.0

140.8

WTI Crude Oil Price $/B

84.08

∆% 2012/2011

-15.3

83.17

99.30

 

6/11/12

6/4/12

6/13/11

Regular Motor Gasoline $/G

3.572

∆% 2012/2011
-3.8

3.612

3.713

B: barrels; G: gallon

Source: US Energy Information Administration

http://www.eia.gov/pub/oil_gas/petroleum/data_publications/weekly_petroleum_status_report/current/pdf/highlights.pdf

Chart VII-1 of the US Energy Information Administration shows commercial stocks of crude oil of the US. There have been fluctuations around an upward trend since 2005. Crude oil stocks trended downwardly during a few weeks but with fluctuations followed by several sharp weekly increases.

clip_image036

Chart VII-1, US, Weekly Crude Oil Ending Stocks

Source: US Energy Information Administration

http://www.eia.gov/dnav/pet/hist/LeafHandler.ashx?n=PET&s=WCESTUS1&f=W

Chart VII-2 provides the evolution of motor gasoline stocks in the US. After prolonged decline, there is an upward change in weekly stocks for Jun 1, 2012 but decline for Jun 8, 2012.

clip_image037

Chart VII-2, US, Motor Gasoline Stocks

Source: US Energy Information Administration

http://www.eia.gov/petroleum/

Chart VII-3 of the US Energy Information Administration shows the price of WTI crude oil since the 1980s. Chart VII-3 captures commodity price shocks during the past decade. The costly mirage of deflation was caused by the decline in oil prices during the recession of 2001. The upward trend after 2003 was promoted by the carry trade from near zero interest rates. The jump above $140/barrel during the global recession in 2008 can only be explained by the carry trade promoted by monetary policy of zero fed funds rate. After moderation of risk aversion, the carry trade returned with resulting sharp upward trend of crude prices. Risk aversion resulted in another drop in recent weeks.

clip_image039

Chart VII-3, US, Crude Oil Futures Contract

Source: US Energy Information Administration

http://www.eia.gov/dnav/pet/hist/LeafHandler.ashx?n=PET&s=RCLC1&f=D

There is typically significant difference between initial claims for unemployment insurance adjusted and not adjusted for seasonality provided in Table VII-2. Seasonally adjusted claims increased 6,000 from 380,000 on Jun 2, 2012, to 386,000 on Jun 9. Claims not adjusted for seasonality increased 49,155 from 324,385 on Jun 2, 2012 to 373,540 on Jun 9. Strong seasonality is preventing clear analysis of labor markets.

Table VII-2, US, Initial Claims for Unemployment Insurance

 

SA

NSA

4-week MA SA

June 9, 12

386,000

373,540

382,000

June 2, 12

380,000

324,385

378,500

Change

+6,000

+49,155

+3,500

May 26, 12

389,000

346,260

376,000

Prior Year

418,000

400,608

422,750

Note: SA: seasonally adjusted; NSA: not seasonally adjusted; MA: moving average

Source: http://www.dol.gov/opa/media/press/eta/ui/current.htm

Table VII-3 provides seasonally and not seasonally adjusted claims in the comparable week for the years from 2001 to 2012. Seasonally adjusted claims typically are lower than claims not adjusted for seasonality. Claims not seasonally adjusted have declined from 581.092 on Jun 6, 2009 to 366,816 on Jun 4, 2011, and 373,540 on Jun 9, 2012. There is strong indication of significant decline in the level of layoffs in the US but some doubts at the margin after the high increase in unadjusted claims in the week of Jun 9, 2012. Hiring has not recovered (see Section IA Hiring Collapse at http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/05/recovery-without-hiring-ten-million.html and earlier at http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/04/fractured-labor-market-with-hiring.html).

Table VII-3, US, Unemployment Insurance Weekly Claims

 

Not Seasonally Adjusted Claims

Seasonally Adjusted Claims

Jun 9, 2001

397,015

411,000

Jun 8, 2002

378,613

388,000

Jun 7, 2003

421,190

429,000

Jun 5, 2004

308,229

355,000

Jun 4, 2005

289,914

338,000

Jun 3, 2006

260,263

307,000

Jun 9, 2007

302,368

313,000

Jun 7, 2008

373,033

383,000

Jun 6, 2009

581,092

596,000

Jun 5, 2010

398,864

460,000

Jun 4, 2011

366,816

425,000

Jun 9, 2012

373,540

386,000

Source: http://workforcesecurity.doleta.gov/unemploy/claims.asp

VIII Interest Rates. It is quite difficult to measure inflationary expectations because they tend to break abruptly from past inflation. There could still be an influence of past and current inflation in the calculation of future inflation by economic agents. Table VIII-1 provides inflation of the CPI. In the four months Jan to May 2012, CPI inflation for all items seasonally adjusted was 1.4 percent in annual equivalent, that is, compounding inflation in Jan-May 2012 and assuming it would be repeated for a full year. In the 12 months ending in May, CPI inflation of all items not seasonally adjusted was 1.7 percent. Inflation in May 2012 not seasonally adjusted was minus 0.1 percent relative to Apr 2012 and minus 0.3 percent seasonally adjusted (http://www.bls.gov/cpi/). The second row provides the same measurements for the CPI of all items excluding food and energy: 2.3 percent in 12 months and 2.2 percent in annual equivalent Jan-May 2012. Bloomberg provides the yield curve of US Treasury securities (http://www.bloomberg.com/markets/rates-bonds/government-bonds/us/). The lowest yield is 0.09 percent for three months, 0.14 percent for six months, 0.16 percent for 12 months, 0.27 percent for two years, 0.37 percent for three years, 0.67 percent for five years, 1.04 percent for seven years, 1.58 percent for ten years and 2.68 percent for 30 years. The Irving Fisher definition of real interest rates is approximately the difference between nominal interest rates, which are those estimated by Bloomberg, and the rate of inflation expected in the term of the security, which could behave as in Table VIII-1. May inflation is low because of the unwinding of carry trades from zero interest rates to commodity futures prices but could ignite again with subdued risk aversion. Real interest rates in the US have been negative during substantial periods in the past decade while monetary policy pursues a policy of attaining its “dual mandate” of (http://www.federalreserve.gov/aboutthefed/mission.htm):

“Conducting the nation's monetary policy by influencing the monetary and credit conditions in the economy in pursuit of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates”

Negative real rates of interest distort calculations of risk and returns from capital budgeting by firms, through lending by financial intermediaries to decisions on savings, housing and purchases of households. Inflation on near zero interest rates misallocates resources away from their most productive uses and creates uncertainty of the future path of adjustment to higher interest rates that inhibit sound decisions.

Table VIII-1, US, Consumer Price Index Percentage Changes 12 months NSA and Annual Equivalent ∆%

 

∆% 12 Months May 2012/May
2011 NSA

∆% Annual Equivalent Jan-May 2012 SA

CPI All Items

1.7

1.4

CPI ex Food and Energy

2.3

2.2

Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/cpi/

IX Conclusion. Table IX-1 provides the data required for broader comparison of the cyclical expansions of IQ1983 to IVQ1985 and the current one from 2009 to 2012. First, in the 13 quarters from IQ1983 to IVQ1985, GDP increased 19.6 percent at the annual equivalent rate of 5.7 percent; real disposable personal income (RDPI) increased 14.5 percent at the annual equivalent rate of 4.3 percent; RDPI per capita increased 11.5 percent at the annual equivalent rate of 3.4 percent; and population increased 2.7 percent at the annual equivalent rate of 0.8 percent. Second, in the 11 quarters of the current cyclical expansion from IIIQ2009 to IQ2012, GDP increased 6.7 percent at the annual equivalent rate of 2.4 percent; real disposable personal income (RDPI) increased 2.5 percent at the annual equivalent rate of 0.9 percent; RDPI per capita increased 0.3 percent at the annual equivalent rate of 0.1 percent; and population increased 2.1 percent at the annual equivalent rate of 0.8 percent. Real disposable personal income is the actual take home pay after inflation and taxes and real disposable income per capita is what is left per inhabitant. The current cyclical expansion is the worst in the period after World War II in terms of growth of economic activity and income. The United States grew during its history at high rates of per capita income that made its economy the largest in the world. That dynamism is disappearing.

Table IX-1, US, GDP, Real Disposable Personal Income, Real Disposable Income per Capita and Population in 1983-85 and 2007-2011, %

 

# Quarters

∆%

∆% Annual Equivalent

IQ1983 to IVQ1985

13

   

GDP

 

19.6

5.7

RDPI

 

14.5

4.3

RDPI Per Capita

 

11.5

3.4

Population

 

2.7

0.8

IIIQ2009 to IQ2012

11

   

GDP

 

6.7

2.4

RDPI

 

2.5

0.9

RDPI per Capita

 

0.3

0.1

Population

 

2.1

0.8

RDPI: Real Disposable Personal Income

Source: US Bureau of Economic Analysis

http://www.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm

References

Abraham, Katharine G., John C. Haltiwanger, Kristin Sandusky and James Spletzer. 2009. Exploring differences in employment between household and establishment data. Cambridge, MA, National Bureau of Economic Research, Mar 2009.

Allen, William R. 1993. Irving Fisher and the 100 percent reserve proposal. Journal of Law and Economics 36 (2, Oct): 703-17.

Asso, Pier Francesco, George A. Kahn and Robert Leeson. 2007. The Taylor Rule and the transformation of monetary policy. Kansas City: Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City RWP 07-II, Dec.

Asso, Pier Francesco, George A. Kahn and Robert Leeson. 2010. The Taylor Rule and the practice of central banking. Kansas City: Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, RWP 10-05, Feb.

Bagehot, Walter. 1873. Lombard Street, 14th edn. London: Kegan, Paul & Co, 1917.

Ball, Laurence and N. Gregory Mankiw. 2002. The NAIRU in theory and practice. Journal of Economic Perspectives 16 (4, Autumn): 115-36.

Bank of Japan. 2012Feb14APP. Amendment to “Principal Terms and Conditions for the Asset Purchase Program.” Tokyo, Bank of Japan, Feb 14 http://www.boj.or.jp/en/announcements/release_2012/rel120214a.pdf

Bank of Japan. 2012Feb14PSG. The price stability goal in the medium to long term. Tokyo, Bank of Japan, Feb 14 http://www.boj.or.jp/en/announcements/release_2012/k120214b.pdf

Bank of Japan. 2012Feb14EME. Enhancement of monetary easing. Tokyo, Bank of Japan, Feb 14 http://www.boj.or.jp/en/announcements/release_2012/k120214a.pdf

Barbosa, Fernando de Holanda. 1987. Domestic and international sources of Brazilian inflation: 1947-80. In Luigi L. Pasinetti and P.J. Lloyd, eds. Structural change, economic interdependence and world development. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

Barro, Robert J. and David B. Gordon. 1983a. Rules, discretion and reputation in a model of monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 12 (1): 101-121.

Barro, Robert J. and David B. Gordon. 1983b. A positive theory of monetary policy in a natural rate model. Journal of Political Economy 91 (4, Aug): 589-610.

Barsky, Robert B. and Lutz Kilian. 2004. Oil and the macroeconomy since the 1970s. Journal of Economic Perspectives 18 (4, Autumn): 115-34.

Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. 2011Jun. Basel II: a global regulatory framework for more resilient banks and banking systems. Basel, Switzerland: BIS, Jun 2011 http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs189.pdf

Batini, Nicoletta and Edward Nelson. 2002. The lag from monetary policy actions to inflation: Friedman revisited. London, Bank of England, External MPC Unit Discussion Paper No. 6, Jan.

Beim, David O. 2011Oct9. Can the euro be saved? New York City, Columbia University, Oct 9 http://www1.gsb.columbia.edu/mygsb/faculty/research/pubfiles/5573/Can%20the%20Euro%20be%20Saved.pdf

Bernanke, Ben S. 2002. Deflation: making sure “it” doesn’t happen here. Washington, DC, National Economists Club, Nov 21 http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2002/20021121/default.htm

Bernanke, Ben S. 2000. Japanese monetary policy: a case of self-induced paralysis? In Ryoichi Mikitani and Adam S. Posen, Japan’s financial crisis and its parallels to US experience. Washington, DC, Institute for International Economics, Special Report 13, Sep 2000.

Bernanke, Ben S. 2003. A perspective on inflation targeting. Business Economics 38 (3, Jul): 7–15.

Bernanke, Ben S. 2010WP. What the Fed did and why: supporting the recovery and sustaining price stability. Washington Post, Nov 4. http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/article/2010/11/03/AR2010110307372_pf.html

Bernanke, Ben S. 2011Oct4JEC. Statement. Washington, DC, Joint Economic Committee, US Congress, Oct 4 http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/bernanke20111004a.pdf

Bernanke, Ben S. 2012Apr25. Transcript of Chairman Bernanke’s press conference April 25, 2012. Washington, DC, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Apr 25 http://www.federalreserve.gov/mediacenter/files/FOMCpresconf20120425.pdf

Bernanke, Ben S. and Frederic S. Mishkin. 1997. Inflation targeting: a new framework for monetary policy? Journal of Economic Perspectives 11 (2, Spring): 97–116.

Black, Fischer and Myron Scholes. 1973. The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. Journal of Political Economy 81 (May/June): 637-54.

Blanchard, Olivier. 2011WEOSep. Foreword to IMF 2011WEOSep: XIII-XIV.

Blanchard, Olivier. 2012WEOApr. Foreword to IMF 2012WEOApr: XIII-XIV

Blanchard, Olivier and Lawrence F. Katz. 1997. What we know and do not know about the natural rate of unemployment. Journal of Economic Perspectives 11 (1, Winter): 51-72.

Bordo, Michael D. and Hugh Rockoff. 2011. The influence of Irving Fisher on Milton Friedman’s monetary economics. Denver, CO, AEA Session on Irving Fisher and Modern Economics: 100 years after the Purchasing Power of Money, Jan 8 www.aeaweb.org/aea/2011conference/program/retrieve.php?pdfid

Bricker, Jesse, Arthur B. Kennickell, Kevin B. Moore and John Sabelhaus. 2012. Changes in US family finances from 2007 to 2010: evidence from the Survey of Consumer Finances. Federal Reserve Bulletin 98 (2, Jun): 2-80 http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/bulletin/2012/PDF/scf12.pdf

Buiter, Willem. 2011Oct31. EFSF needs bigger bazooka to maximize its firepower. Financial Times, Oct 31 http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/c4886f7a-03d3-11e1-bbc5-00144feabdc0.html#axzz1cMoq63R5

Brunner, Karl and Allan H. Meltzer. 1973. Mr. Hicks and the “monetarists.” Economica NS 40 (157, Feb): 44-59.

Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2011Feb11. Overview of seasonal adjustment of the current employment statistics program. Washington, Feb 11, 2011 http://www.bls.gov/ces/cessa_oview.pdf

Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2012Feb3. Seasonal adjustment files and documentation. Washington, BLD, Feb 3 http://www.bls.gov/web/empsit/cesseasadj.htm

Caballero, Ricardo and Francsco Giavazzi. 2012Jan15. Parity may be euro’s last chance. Bloomberg, Jan 15 http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2012-01-16/dollar-parity-may-be-euro-salvation-commentary-by-caballero-and-giavazzi.html

Cagan, Phillip. 1965. Determinants and effects of changes in the stock of money, 1875-1960. New York: Columbia University Press.

Cameron, Rondo E. 1961. France and the economic development of Europe 1800-1914: conquests of peace and seeds of war. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Cameron, Rondo E. 1967. Banking in the early stages of industrialization. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Cameron, Rondo E. 1972. Banking and economic development. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Cameron, Rondo E., V.I. Bovkyn, Richard Sylla, Mira Wilkins, Boris Anan’ich, and A. A. Fursenko, eds. 1992. International Banking 1870-1914. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

CBO. 2012JanBEO. The budget and economic outlook: fiscal years 2012 to 2022. Washington, DC: Congressional Budget Office, Jan http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/126xx/doc12699/01-31-2012_Outlook.pdf

CBO. 2012MarBEO. Updated budget projections: fiscal years 2012 to 2022. Washington, DC: Congressional Budget Office, Mar http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/attachments/March2012Baseline.pdf

CBO. 2012LTBO. The 2012 long-term budget outlook. Washington, DC: Congressional Budget Office, Jun http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/attachments/06-05-Long-Term_Budget_Outlook.pdf

Cline, William. 2001. The role of the private sector in resolving financial crises in emerging markets. Cambridge, MA, NBER, Jun.

Cline, William. 2002. Private sector involvement: definition, measurement and implementation. London, Bank of England Conference, Jul-23-4.

Cobet, Aaron E. and Gregory A. Wilson. 2002. Comparing 50 years of labor productivity in US and foreign manufacturing. Monthly Labor Review (Jun): 51-65.

Cochrane, John A. 2010A. The government debt valuation equation. An appendix to “Understanding policy.” http://faculty.chicagobooth.edu/john.cochrane/research/Papers/

Cochrane, John H. 2011Jan. Understanding policy in the great recession: some unpleasant fiscal arithmetic. European Economic Review 55 (1, Jan): 2-30.

Cochrane, John H. and Luigi Zingales. 2009. Lehman and the financial crisis. Wall Street Journal, Sep 15.

Cole, Harold L. and Lee E. Ohanian. 1999. The Great Depression in the United States from a neoclassical perspective. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 23 (1, Winter): 2-24.

Contador, Cláudio R. and Haddad, Cláudio L. 1975. Produto real, moeda e preços. Revista Brasileira de Estatística 36(143, jul/set): 407-40.

Culbertson, J. M. 1960. Friedman on the lag in effect of monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy 68 (6, Dec): 617-21.

Culbertson, J. M. 1961. The lag in effect of monetary policy: reply. Journal of Political Economy 69 (5, Oct): 467-77.

Darby, Michael R. Darby. 1974. The permanent income theory of consumption—a restatement. Quarterly Journal of Economics (88, 2): 228-50.

De Long, J. Bradford. 1997. America’s peacetime inflation: the 1970s. In Christina D. Romer and David H. Romer, eds. Reducing inflation: motivation and strategy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1997.

Draghi, Mario. 2011Dec1. Introductory statement by Mario Draghi, President of the ECB. Brussels, Hearing before the Plenary of the European Parliament, Dec 1 http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2011/html/sp111201.en.html

Draghi, Mario. 2011Dec8. Introductory statement to the press conference. Frankfurt am Main, ECB, Dec 8 http://www.ecb.int/press/pressconf/2011/html/is111208.en.html

Duffie, Darell and Kenneth J. Singleton. 2003. Credit risk: pricing, measurement and management. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

European Council. 2011Dec9. Statements by the euro area heads of state or government. Brussels, European Union, Dec 9 http://www.consilium.europa.eu/uedocs/cms_Data/docs/pressdata/en/ec/126658.pdf

De Long, J. Bradford. 1997. America’s peacetime inflation: the 1970s. In Christina D. Romer and David H. Romer, eds. Reducing inflation: motivation and strategy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1997.

Diamond, Douglas W. and Philip H. Dybvig. 1983. Bank runs, deposit insurance and liquidity. Journal of Political Economy 91 (3, Jun): 401-49.

Diamond, Douglas W. and Philip H. Dybvig. 1986. Banking theory, deposit insurance and bank regulation. Journal of Business 59 (1, Jan): 55-68.

Diamond, Douglas W. and Raghuram G. Rajan. 2000. A theory of bank capital. Journal of Finance 55 (6, Dec): 2431-65.

Diamond, Douglas W. and Raghuram G. Rajan. 2001a. Banks and liquidity. American Economic Review 91 (2, May): 422-5.

Diamond, Douglas W. and Raghuram G. Rajan. 2001b. Banks and liquidity. American Economic Review 91 (2, May): 422-5.

Dornbusch, Rudiger. 1976. Expectations and exchange rate dynamics. Journal of Political Economy 84 (6, Dec): 1161-76.

Draghi, Mario. 2011Dec15. The euro, monetary stability and the design of a fiscal compact. Berlin, Dec 15 http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2011/html/sp111215.en.html

Draghi, Mario. 2012May3. Introductory statement to the press conference. Barcelona, May 3 http://www.ecb.int/press/pressconf/2012/html/is120503.en.html

Draghi, Mario. 2012Jun15. President’s address at the 14th ECB and its Watchers Conference. Frankfurt am Main, European Central Bank, Jun 15 http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2012/html/sp120615.en.html

Economides, Nicholas, Yannis Ioannides, Emmanuel Petrakis, Christopher Pissarides and Thanasis Stengos. 2012. What’s at stake in the Greek vote. Wall Street Journal, Jun 14 http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052702303822204577466541312448940.html?mod=WSJ_hps_sections_opinion

European Central Bank. 2011MBDec. Editorial. Monthly Bulletin December 2011, 5-9 http://www.ecb.int/pub/pdf/mobu/mb201112en.pdf

European Commission. 2011Oct26SS. Euro summit statement. Brussels, European Commission, Oct 26 http://ec.europa.eu/news/economy/111027_en.htm

European Commission. 2011Oct26MRES. Main results of Euro Summit. Brussels, European Commission, Oct 26 http://www.consilium.europa.eu/uedocs/cms_Data/docs/pressdata/en/ec/125645.pdf

European Council. 2011Dec9. Statements by the euro area heads of state or government. Brussels, European Union, Dec 9 http://www.consilium.europa.eu/uedocs/cms_Data/docs/pressdata/en/ec/126658.pdf

Fisher, Irving. 100% Money. 1936. New York: Adelphi Company

Feldstein, Martin. 2012Mar19. Obama’s tax hikes threaten a new US recession. Financial Times, Mar 19 http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/0d0e7acc-6f7d-11e1-9c57-00144feab49a.html#axzz1pexRlsiQ

Friedman, Milton. 1953. The effects of a full-employment policy on economic stability: a formal analysis. In Milton Friedman, Essays on positive economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Friedman, Milton. 1957. A Theory of the Consumption Function. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Friedman, Milton. 1961. The lag in effect of monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy 69 (5, Oct): 447-66.

Friedman, Milton. 1968. The role of monetary policy. American Economic Review 58 (1, Mar): 1-17.

Friedman, Milton. 1970. Controls on interest rates paid by banks. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 2 (1, Feb): 15-32.

Friedman, Milton. 1982. Monetary policy: theory and practice. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 14 (1, Feb): 98-118.

Friedman, Milton and Anna Jacobson Schwartz. 1963. A monetary history of the United States, 1867-1960. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Friedman, Milton and Anna Jacobson Schwartz. 1970. Monetary statistics of the United States: estimates, sources, and methods. New York: Columbia University Press.

FOMC. 2006Dec12. Meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee December 12, 2006. Washington, DC, Federal Reserve, Dec 12 http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/FOMC20061212meeting.pdf

Gorton, Gary. 2009EFM. The subprime panic. European Financial Management 15 (1): 10-46.

Graham, Frank D. 1936. Partial reserve money and the 100 per cent proposal. American Economic Review (26, 3): 428-40.

Greenspan, Alan. 2004. Risk and uncertainty in monetary policy. American Economic Review 94 (2, May): 33-40. Also available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2004/20040103/default.htm

Haddad, Cláudio L. 1974. Growth of Brazilian real output. Chicago, Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Chicago, Jun.

Hamilton, Alexander. 1780. The national Bank. In Henry Cabot Lodge, ed. The works of Alexander Hamilton. New York and London: G. P. Putnam & Sons, 1904: 319-45. http://oll.libertyfund.org/?option=com_staticxt&staticfile=show.php%3Ftitle=1380&chapter=64319&layout=html#a_1594266

Harris, Jennifer M. 2011BA. Benchmark article. Washington, DC, Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/ces/cesbmart.pdf

Hicks, John R. 1975. The scope and status of welfare economics. Oxford Economic Papers 27 (3): 307-26.

Hobbs, Frank and Nicole Stoops. 2002. Demographic trends in the 20th century. Washington, DC, US Government Printing Office http://www.census.gov/prod/2002pubs/censr-4.pdf

IMF. 2011WEOSep. World economic outlook Sep 11: slowing growth, rising risks. Washington, DC, IMF Sep http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2011/02/pdf/text.pdf

IMF. 2011JSRNov23. Japan sustainability report. Washington, DC, IMF, Nov 23 http://www.imf.org/external/np/country/2011/mapjapanpdf.pdf

IMF. 2012GFSRJan24. Global Financial Stability Report: market update. Washington, DC, IMF, Jan 24 http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fmu/eng/2012/01/index.htm

IMF. 2012FMJan24. Fiscal Monitor Update. Washington, DC, IMF, Jan 24 http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fm/2012/update/01/fmindex.htm

IMF. 2012WEOJan24. World Economic Outlook Update: an update of the key WEO projections. Washington, DC, IMF, Jan 24 http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2012/update/01/index.htm

IMF. 2012WEOApr. World Economic Outlook April 2012: growth resuming, dangers remains. Washington, DC, IMF, 2012, Apr http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2012/01/pdf/text.pdf

IMF. 2012GFSRApr. Global financial stability report: the quest for lasting stability. Washington, DC, IMF 2012, Apr http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/gfsr/2012/01/pdf/text.pdf

IMF. 2012FMApr. Fiscal monitor: balancing fiscal policy risks. Washington, DC, IMF, Apr

http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fm/2012/01/pdf/fm1201.pdf

IMFC. 2012Apr20. Joint Statement of the International Monetary and Financial Committee and the Group of 20 Finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors on IMF Resources. Washington, DC, IMF, Apr 20 http://www.imf.org/external/np/sec/pr/2012/pr12144.htm

IMFC. 2012Apr21. Communiqué of the Twenty-Fifth Meeting of the IMFC. Washington, DC, IMF, Apr 21 http://www.imf.org/external/np/sec/pr/2012/pr12145.htm

IMF. 2012FSAPJun8. Spain: Financial Stability Assessment. Washington, DC, International Monetary Fund, Jun http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/scr/2012/cr12137.pdf

Ingersoll, Jonathan. 1987. Theory of Financial Decision Making. New Jersey: Rowman.

Ireland, Peter N. 1999. Does the time-consistency problem explain the behavior of inflation in the United States. Journal of Monetary Economics 44 (2): 279-91.

Ito, Takatoshi. Interventions and Japanese economic recovery. YenMacro, Michigan 2004 1 http://www.fordschool.umich.edu/rsie/Conferences/CGP/Oct2004Papers/Ito.pdf

Jensen, Michael C. 1993. The modern industrial revolution, exit and the failure of internal control systems. Journal of Finance 48 (3, Jul): 831-80.

Kahil, Raouf. 1973. Inflation and economic development in Brazil. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

Kohn, Donald L. 2009Apr18. Monetary policy in the financial crisis. Nashville, TN, Conference in Honor of Dewey Daane, Apr 18 http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/kohn20090418a.htm

Kohn, Donald L. 2009Sep10. Comments on “Interpreting the Unconventional US Monetary policy of 2007-2009.” Washington, Brookings Institution, Sep 10 http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/kohn20090910a.htm

Krugman, Paul. 1998. It’s baaack: Japan’s slump and the return of the liquidity trap. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2 (1998): 137-205.

Krugman, Paul. 2012Apr24. Earth to Ben Bernanke: chairman Bernanke should listen to Professor Bernanke. New York Times Magazine, Apr 24 http://www.nytimes.com/2012/04/29/magazine/chairman-bernanke-should-listen-to-professor-bernanke.html?pagewanted=all

Kydland, Finn E. and Edward C. Prescott. 1977. Rules rather than discretion: the inconsistency of optimal plans. Journal of Political Economy 85 (3, Jun): 473-92.

Lazear, Edward P. 2012Jan19. The jobs picture is still far from rosy. Wall Street Journal, Jan 19 http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052970204468004577165292033648810.html

Lazear, Edward P. and James R. Spletzer. 2012Mar. Hiring, churn and the business cycle. Cambridge, MA, NBER, Mar http://www.nber.org/papers/w17910

Leff, Nathaniel H. 1975. Review of Inflation and Economic Development in Brazil, 1946-1963 by Raouf Kahil. Journal of Economic Literature 12 (2, Jun): 510-11.

Levin, Andrew and John B. Taylor. 2009. Falling behind the curve: a positive analysis of stop-start monetary policies and the Great Inflation. Cambridge, MA, NBER, Dec.

McCallum, Bennett. 1999. Issues in the design of monetary policy rules. In John B. Taylor and Michael Woodford, eds. Handbook of Macroeconomics Volume 1A. Amsterdam: Elsevier North Holland.

McKinnon, Ronald I. 1973. Money and Capital in Economic Development. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

McKinnon, Ronald I. 2011Dec18. Oh, for Alexander Hamilton to save Europe! Financial Times, Dec 18 http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/811611d6-273a-11e1-b7ec-00144feabdc0.html#axzz1gzoHXOj6

Meltzer, Allan H. 2005. Origins of the Great Inflation. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 87 (2, Part 2, Mar/Apr): 145-72.

Meltzer, Allan H. 2010a. A history of the Federal Reserve, Volume 2, Book 1, 1951-1969. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Meltzer, Allan H. 2010b. A history of the Federal Reserve, Volume 2, Book 2, 1970-1986. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Metzler, Lloyd A. The nature and stability of inventory cycles. 1941. Review of Economics and Statistics 23 (3, Aug): 113-29.

Merton, Robert C. 1973. Theory of rational option pricing. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 4 (1, Spring): 141-83.

Merton, Robert C. 1974. On the pricing of corporate debt: the risk structure of interest rates. Journal of Finance 29 (2, May): 449-70.

Merton, Robert C. 1998. Applications of option-pricing theory: twenty-five years later. American Economic Review 88 (3): 323-49.

Pelaez, Carlos A. 2008. The reform of Alexander Hamilton. Philadelphia, University of Pennsylvania Law School, Unpublished manuscript.

Pelaez, Carlos M. and Carlos A. Pelaez. 2005. International Financial Architecture. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. http://us.macmillan.com/QuickSearchResults.aspx?search=pelaez%2C+carlos&ctl00%24ctl00%24cphContent%24ucAdvSearch%24imgGo.x=26&ctl00%24ctl00%24cphContent%24ucAdvSearch%24imgGo.y=14 http://www.amazon.com/Carlos-Manuel-Pel%C3%A1ez/e/B001HCUT10

Pelaez, Carlos M. and Carlos A. Pelaez. 2007. The Global Recession Risk. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. http://www.amazon.com/Carlos-Manuel-Pel%C3%A1ez/e/B001HCUT10

Pelaez, Carlos M. and Carlos A. Pelaez. 2008a. Globalization and the State: Vol. I. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. http://www.amazon.com/Carlos-Manuel-Pel%C3%A1ez/e/B001HCUT10

Pelaez, Carlos M. and Carlos A. Pelaez. 2008b. Globalization and the State: Vol. II. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

Pelaez, Carlos M. and Carlos A. Pelaez. 2008c. Government Intervention in Globalization. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. http://www.amazon.com/Carlos-Manuel-Pel%C3%A1ez/e/B001HCUT10

Pelaez, Carlos M. and Carlos A. Pelaez. 2009a. Financial Regulation after the Global Recession. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. http://www.amazon.com/Carlos-Manuel-Pel%C3%A1ez/e/B001HCUT10

Pelaez, Carlos M. and Carlos A. Pelaez. 2009b. Regulation of Banks and Finance. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.http://www.amazon.com/Carlos-Manuel-Pel%C3%A1ez/e/B001HCUT10

Pelaez, Carlos Manuel. 1974. Long-run Monetary Behavior and Institutions in an Underdeveloped Economy, 1800-1971. Copenhaguen, Paper Presented at the VI International Congress on Economic History, Session on Monetary Inflation in Historical Perspective, International Economic History Association, Aug 22.

Pelaez, Carlos Manuel. 1975. The Establishment of Banking Institutions in a Backward Economy: Brazil, 1800-1851. Business History Review 49 (4, Winter): 446-472.

Pelaez, Carlos Manuel. 1976a. The Theory and Reality of Imperialism in the Coffee Economy of Nineteenth-Century Brazil. Economic History Review 29, Second Series (May): 276-294.

Pelaez, Carlos Manuel. 1976b. A Comparison of Long-term Monetary Behavior and Institutions in Brazil, Europe and the United States. Journal of European Economic History 5 (2, Fall): 439-450.

Pelaez, Carlos Manuel. 1977. World War I and the Economy of Brazil: Some Evidence from Monetary Statistics. Journal of Interdisciplinary History (7, Apr): 683-680.

Pelaez, Carlos Manuel. 1979. História Econômica do Brasil. São Paulo: Editora Atlas.

Pelaez, Carlos Manuel and Wilson Suzigan. 1978. Economia Monetária. São Paulo, Atlas.

Pelaez, Carlos Manuel and Wilson Suzigan. 1981. História Monetária do Brasil Segunda Edição. Coleção Temas Brasileiros. Brasília: Universidade de Brasília.

Phelps, Edmund S. 1968. Money-wage dynamics and labor market equilibrium. Journal of Political Economy 76 (4, 2, Jul-Aug): 678-711.

Reinhart, Carmen M. and Kenneth Rogoff. 2010GTD. Growth in a time of debt. American Economic Review 100 (2): 1-9.

Rajan, Raghuram G. 2004. Remarks. Sydney, Australia, Australasian Finance and Banking Conference, Dec 15.

Rajan, Raghuram G. 2005. Has financial development made the world riskier? Jackson Hole, WY, Symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City. http://www.kc.frb.org/publicat/sympos/2005/PDF/Rajan2005.pdf

Rajan, Raghuram G. 2012May8. Stop beating up on Ben Bernanke. Financial Times, May 8 http://blogs.ft.com/the-a-list/2012/05/08/stop-beating-up-on-ben-bernanke/

Rajan, Raghuram G. 2012FA. The true lessons of the recession: the West can’t borrow and spend its way to recovery. Foreign Affairs 91 (May/June, 3): 69-79.

Rajan, Raghuram G. and Luigi Zingales. 2001. The influence of the financial revolution on the nature of the firm. American Economic Review 91 (2): 206-11.

Robinson, Joan. 1947. Beggar-my-neighbour remedies for unemployment. In Joan Robinson, Essays in the Theory of Employment, Oxford, Basil Blackwell, 1947.

Rogoff, Kenneth. 2002MF. Dornbusch’s overshooting model after twenty-five years. Washington, DC, IMF, Mundell-Fleming Lecture http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2001/kr/112901.pdf

Roll, Richard. 1977. A critique of the asset pricing theory’s tests. Part I: on past and potential testability of the theory. Journal of Financial Economics 4 (2, Mar): 129-76.

Romer, Christina D. and David H. Romer. 2004. A new measure of monetary shocks: derivation and implications. American Economic Review 94 (4, Sep): 1055-84.

Samuelson, Paul A. 1974. Lessons from the current economic expansion. American Economic Review 64 (2, May): 75-7.

Sargent, Thomas J. 1983. The end of four big inflations. In Robert E. Hall, ed. Inflation: causes and effects. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

Sargent, Thomas J. and Neil Wallace. 1973. The stability of models of money and growth with perfect foresight. Econometrica 41 (6, Nov): 1043-8.

Sargent, Thomas J. and Neil Wallace. 1981. Some unpleasant monetarist arithmetic. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 5 (3, Fall): 1-17.

Sargent, Thomas J. and William L. Silber. 2012Mar20. The challenges of the Fed’s bid for transparency. Financial Times, Mar 20 http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/778eb1ce-7288-11e1-9c23-00144feab49a.html#axzz1pexRlsiQ

Seers, Dudley. 1962. A theory of inflation and growth in under-developed economies based on the experience of Latin America. Oxford Economic Papers New Series 14 (Jun, 2): 173-95.

Shaw, Edward S. 1973. Financial Deepening in Economic Development. New York: Oxford University Press.

Simons, Henry C. 1936. Rules versus authorities in monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy 44 (1, Feb): 1-30.

Simons, Henry C. 1948. Economic Policy for a free society. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Sims, Christopher A. 1972. Money, income and causality. American Economic Review 62 (4, Sep): 540-52.

Standard & Poor’s Rating Services (S&PRS). 2012Jan13. Standard & Poor’s takes various rating actions on 16 eurozone sovereign governments. Frankfurt, S&P Rating Services, Jan 13 http://www.standardandpoors.com/ratings/articles/en/us/?articleType=HTML&assetID=1245327294763

Standard & Poor’s Rating Services (S&PRS). 2012Jan16. European Financial Stability Facility long-term Ratings Cut to ‘AA+’; short-term ratings affirmed; outlook developing. Frankfurt, S&P Rating Services, Jan 16 http://www.standardandpoors.com/ratings/articles/en/us/?articleType=HTML&assetID=1245327337060

Svensson, Lars E. 2003. What is wrong with Taylor rules? Using judgment in monetary policy through targeting rules. Journal of Economic Literature 41 (2 Jun): 426–77.

Taylor, John B. 1993. Discretion versus policy rules in practice. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 39 (1993): 195-214.

Taylor, John B. 1997. Comment. In Christina Romer and David Romer, eds. Reducing inflation: motivation and strategy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Taylor, John B. 1998LB. Monetary policy and the long boom. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review (Nov-Dec): 3-11.

Taylor, John B. 1999. An historical analysis of monetary policy rules. In John B. Taylor, ed. Monetary policy rules. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Taylor, John B. 2012FP. First principles: five keys to restoring America’s prosperity. New York: W. W. Norton.

Taylor, John B. 2012Mar27. Testimony before the Joint Economic Committee at the Hearing on “Monetary Policy Going Forward: Why a Sound Dollar Boosts Growth and Employment.” Washington, DC, JEC, Mar 27 http://jec.senate.gov/republicans/public/?a=Files.Serve&File_id=f002b5f0-9fc0-45f9-9d53-e563137c040e

Taylor, John B. 2012Mar28. The dangers of an interventionist Fed. Wall Street Journal, Mar 28 http://professional.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052702303816504577307403971824094.html?mod=WSJ_hps_sections_opinion

Taylor, John B. 2012JMCB. Monetary policy rules work and discretion doesn’t: a tale of two eras. Palo Alto, CA, Stanford University, Mar 2012, forthcoming in the Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 2012 http://www.stanford.edu/~johntayl/JMCB%20lecture.pdf

Taylor, John B. and John C. Williams. 2010. Simple and robust rules for monetary policy. In Benjamin Friedman and Michael Woodford, eds. Handbook of monetary economics Volume 3B. Amsterdam: Elsevier North Holland.

Tobin, James. 1969. A general equilibrium approach to monetary theory. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 1 (1, Feb): 15-29.

Tobin, James. 1974. Monetary policy in 1974 and beyond. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1 (1974): 219-32.

Villela, Annibal V. and Wilson Suzigan. 1973. Política do governo e crescimento da economia brasileira. Rio de Janeiro: IPEA/INPES.

Williams, David, C.A. E. Goodhart and D. H. Gowland. 1976. Money, income and causality: the UK experience. American Economic Review 66 (3, Jun): 417-23.

Wriston, Walter B. 1982. Banking against disaster. New York Times, Sep 14.

Yellen, Janet L. 2011AS. The Federal’s Reserve’s asset purchase program. Denver, Colorado, Allied Social Science Association Annual Meeting, Jan 8 http://federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20110108a.pdf

Zingales, Luigi. 2000. In search of new foundations. Journal of Finance 55 (4, Aug): 1623-54.

© Carlos M. Pelaez, 2010, 2011, 2012

Appendix I. The Great Inflation

Inflation and unemployment in the period 1966 to 1985 is analyzed by Cochrane (2011Jan, 23) by means of a Phillips circuit joining points of inflation and unemployment. Chart I1 for Brazil in Pelaez (1986, 94-5) was reprinted in The Economist in the issue of Jan 17-23, 1987 as updated by the author. Cochrane (2011Jan, 23) argues that the Phillips circuit shows the weakness in Phillips curve correlation. The explanation is by a shift in aggregate supply, rise in inflation expectations or loss of anchoring. The case of Brazil in Chart I1 cannot be explained without taking into account the increase in the fed funds rate that reached 22.36 percent on Jul 22, 1981 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/data.htm) in the Volcker Fed that precipitated the stress on a foreign debt bloated by financing balance of payments deficits with bank loans in the 1970s; the loans were used in projects, many of state-owned enterprises with low present value in long gestation. The combination of the insolvency of the country because of debt higher than its ability of repayment and the huge government deficit with declining revenue as the economy contracted caused adverse expectations on inflation and the economy.  This interpretation is consistent with the case of the 24 emerging market economies analyzed by Reinhart and Rogoff (2010GTD, 4), concluding that “higher debt levels are associated with significantly higher levels of inflation in emerging markets. Median inflation more than doubles (from less than seven percent to 16 percent) as debt rises from the low (0 to 30 percent) range to above 90 percent. Fiscal dominance is a plausible interpretation of this pattern.”

The reading of the Phillips circuits of the 1970s by Cochrane (2011Jan, 25) is doubtful about the output gap and inflation expectations:

“So, inflation is caused by ‘tightness’ and deflation by ‘slack’ in the economy. This is not just a cause and forecasting variable, it is the cause, because given ‘slack’ we apparently do not have to worry about inflation from other sources, notwithstanding the weak correlation of [Phillips circuits]. These statements [by the Fed] do mention ‘stable inflation expectations. How does the Fed know expectations are ‘stable’ and would not come unglued once people look at deficit numbers? As I read Fed statements, almost all confidence in ‘stable’ or ‘anchored’ expectations comes from the fact that we have experienced a long period of low inflation (adaptive expectations). All these analyses ignore the stagflation experience in the 1970s, in which inflation was high even with ‘slack’ markets and little ‘demand, and ‘expectations’ moved quickly. They ignore the experience of hyperinflations and currency collapses, which happen in economies well below potential.”

Chart I1, Brazil, Phillips Circuit 1963-1987

clip_image040

©Carlos Manuel Pelaez, O cruzado e o austral. São Paulo: Editora Atlas, 1986, pages 94-5. Reprinted in: Brazil. Tomorrow’s Italy, The Economist, 17-23 January 1987, page 25.

DeLong (1997, 247-8) shows that the 1970s were the only peacetime period of inflation in the US without parallel in the prior century. The price level in the US drifted upward since 1896 with jumps resulting from the two world wars: “on this scale, the inflation of the 1970s was as large an increase in the price level relative to drift as either of this century’s major wars” (DeLong, 1997, 248). Monetary policy focused on accommodating higher inflation, with emphasis solely on the mandate of promoting employment, has been blamed as deliberate or because of model error or imperfect measurement for creating the Great Inflation (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/05/slowing-growth-global-inflation-great.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/04/new-economics-of-rose-garden-turned.html http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/03/is-there-second-act-of-us-great.html). As DeLong (1997) shows, the Great Inflation began in the mid 1960s, well before the oil shocks of the 1970s (see also the comment to DeLong 1997 by Taylor 1997, 276-7). TableI1 provides the change in GDP, CPI and the rate of unemployment from 1960 to 1990. There are three waves of inflation (1) in the second half of the 1960s; (2) from 1973 to 1975; and (3) from 1978 to 1981. In one of his multiple important contributions to understanding the Great Inflation, Meltzer (2005) distinguishes between one-time price jumps, such as by oil shocks, and a “maintained” inflation rate. Meltzer (2005) uses a dummy variable to extract the one-time oil price changes, resulting in a maintained inflation rate that was never higher than 8 to 10 percent in the 1970s. There is revealing analysis of the Great Inflation and its reversal by Meltzer (2005, 2010a, 2010b).

Table I1, US Annual Rate of Growth of GDP and CPI and Unemployment Rate 1960-1982

 

∆% GDP

∆% CPI

UNE

1960

2.5

1.4

6.6

1961

2.3

0.7

6.0

1962

6.1

1.3

5.5

1963

4.4

1.6

5.5

1964

5.8

1.0

5.0

1965

6.4

1.9

4.0

1966

6.5

3.5

3.8

1967

2.5

3.0

3.8

1968

4.8

4.7

3.4

1969

3.1

6.2

3.5

1970

0.2

5.6

6.1

1971

3.4

3.3

6.0

1972

5.3

3.4

5.2

1973

5.8

8.7

4.9

1974

-0.6

12.3

7.2

1975

-0.2

6.9

8.2

1976

5.4

4.9

7.8

1977

4.6

6.7

6.4

1978

5.6

9.0

6.0

1979

3.1

13.3

6.0

1980

-0.3

12.5

7.2

1981

2.5

8.9

8.5

1982

-1.9

3.8

10.8

1983

4.5

3.8

8.3

1984

7.2

3.9

7.3

1985

4.1

3.8

7.0

1986

3.5

1.1

6.6

1987

3.2

4.4

5.7

1988

4.1

4.4

5,3

1989

3.6

4.6

5.4

1990

1.9

6.1

6.3

Note: GDP: Gross Domestic Product; CPI: consumer price index; UNE: rate of unemployment; CPI and UNE are at year end instead of average to obtain a complete series

Source: ftp://ftp.bls.gov/pub/special.requests/cpi/cpiai.txt

http://www.bea.gov/national/nipaweb/TableView.asp?SelectedTable=2&ViewSeries=NO&Java=no&Request3Place=N&3Place=N&FromView=YES&Freq=Year&FirstYear=2009&LastYear=2010&3Place=N&Update=Update&JavaBox=no

http://www.bls.gov/web/empsit/cpseea01.htm

http://data.bls.gov/pdq/SurveyOutputServlet

There is a false impression of the existence of a monetary policy “science,” measurements and forecasting with which to steer the economy into “prosperity without inflation.” Market participants are remembering the Great Bond Crash of 1994 shown in Table I2 when monetary policy pursued nonexistent inflation, causing trillions of dollars of losses in fixed income worldwide while increasing the fed funds rate from 3 percent in Jan 1994 to 6 percent in Dec. The exercise in Table I2 shows a drop of the price of the 30-year bond by 18.1 percent and of the 10-year bond by 14.1 percent. CPI inflation remained almost the same and there is no valid counterfactual that inflation would have been higher without monetary policy tightening because of the long lag in effect of monetary policy on inflation (see Culbertson 1960, 1961, Friedman 1961, Batini and Nelson 2002, Romer and Romer 2004). The pursuit of nonexistent deflation during the past ten years has resulted in the largest monetary policy accommodation in history that created the 2007 financial market crash and global recession and is currently preventing smoother recovery while creating another financial crash in the future. The issue is not whether there should be a central bank and monetary policy but rather whether policy accommodation in doses from zero interest rates to trillions of dollars in the fed balance sheet endangers economic stability.

Table I2, Fed Funds Rates, Thirty and Ten Year Treasury Yields and Prices, 30-Year Mortgage Rates and 12-month CPI Inflation 1994

1994

FF

30Y

30P

10Y

10P

MOR

CPI

Jan

3.00

6.29

100

5.75

100

7.06

2.52

Feb

3.25

6.49

97.37

5.97

98.36

7.15

2.51

Mar

3.50

6.91

92.19

6.48

94.69

7.68

2.51

Apr

3.75

7.27

88.10

6.97

91.32

8.32

2.36

May

4.25

7.41

86.59

7.18

88.93

8.60

2.29

Jun

4.25

7.40

86.69

7.10

90.45

8.40

2.49

Jul

4.25

7.58

84.81

7.30

89.14

8.61

2.77

Aug

4.75

7.49

85.74

7.24

89.53

8.51

2.69

Sep

4.75

7.71

83.49

7.46

88.10

8.64

2.96

Oct

4.75

7.94

81.23

7.74

86.33

8.93

2.61

Nov

5.50

8.08

79.90

7.96

84.96

9.17

2.67

Dec

6.00

7.87

81.91

7.81

85.89

9.20

2.67

Notes: FF: fed funds rate; 30Y: yield of 30-year Treasury; 30P: price of 30-year Treasury assuming coupon equal to 6.29 percent and maturity in exactly 30 years; 10Y: yield of 10-year Treasury; 10P: price of 10-year Treasury assuming coupon equal to 5.75 percent and maturity in exactly 10 years; MOR: 30-year mortgage; CPI: percent change of CPI in 12 months

Sources: yields and mortgage rates http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/data.htm CPI ftp://ftp.bls.gov/pub/special.requests/cpi/cpiai.t

© Carlos M. Pelaez, 2010, 2011, 2012

No comments:

Post a Comment