Consumer Prices of the
United States Increased 8.6 percent in 12 Months Ending in May 2022, Which Is
the Highest Since 8.9 percent in Dec 1981, Followed by the Third Highest of 8.4
percent in Jan 1982 and the Second highest of 8.5 percent in Mar 2022, US Consumer
Prices Increased at Annual Equivalent 10.5 Percent in Mar-May 2022 and at 1.0
Percent in May 2022 or 12.7 Percent in Annual Equivalent, Consumer Prices
Excluding Food and Energy Increased at
Annual Equivalent 6.2 Percent in Mar-May 2022 and Increased 0.6 Percent in May
2022 or 7.4 Percent Annual Equivalent, US Current Account Deficit Increased to
4.8 Percent of GDP in IQ2022, Stagflation
Risks, Increasing Risks of Recession, Worldwide Fiscal, Monetary and External
Imbalances, World Cyclical Slow Growth, and Government Intervention in
Globalization
Note: This Blog will post only one indicator of the US
economy while we concentrate efforts in completing a book-length manuscript in
the critically important subject of INFLATION.
Carlos M. Pelaez
© Carlos M.
Pelaez, 2009, 2010, 2011, 2012, 2013, 2014, 2015, 2016, 2017, 2018, 2019, 2020,
2021, 2022.
I United States Inflation
IB Long-term US Inflation
IC Current US Inflation
III World Financial Turbulence
IV Global Inflation
V World Economic Slowdown
VA United States
VB Japan
VC China
VD Euro Area
VE Germany
VF France
VG Italy
VH United Kingdom
VI Valuation of Risk Financial Assets
VII Economic Indicators
VIII Interest Rates
IX Conclusion
References
Appendixes
Appendix I The Great Inflation
IIIB Appendix on Safe Haven Currencies
IIIC Appendix on Fiscal Compact
IIID Appendix on European Central Bank Large Scale Lender of Last
Resort
IIIG Appendix on Deficit Financing of Growth and the Debt Crisis
Preamble. United States total public debt outstanding is $30.4
trillion and debt held by the public $23.9 trillion (https://fiscaldata.treasury.gov/datasets/debt-to-the-penny/debt-to-the-penny). The Net International
Investment Position of the United States, or foreign debt, is $18.1 trillion (https://www.bea.gov/sites/default/files/2022-03/intinv421.pdf https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2022/04/us-consumer-price-index-increased-85.html and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2022/01/increase-in-dec-2021-of-nonfarm-payroll.html). The United States
current account deficit is 4.8 percent of GDP in IQ2022, increasing from 3.7
percent in IVQ2021 (https://www.bea.gov/sites/default/files/2022-06/trans122.pdf). The Treasury deficit of
the United States reached $2.8 trillion in fiscal year 2021 (https://fiscal.treasury.gov/reports-statements/mts/). Total assets of
Federal Reserve Banks reached $8.9 trillion on Jun 22, 2022 and securities held
outright reached $8.5 trillion (https://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h41/current/h41.htm#h41tab1). US GDP nominal NSA
reached $24.4 trillion in IQ2022 (https://apps.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm https://apps.bea.gov/iTable/index_nipa.cfm). Total Treasury
interest-bearing, marketable debt held by private investors increased from
$3635 billion in 2007 to $16,439 billion in Sep 2021 (Fiscal Year 2021) or
increase by 352.2 percent (https://fiscal.treasury.gov/reports-statements/treasury-bulletin/). John Hilsenrath, writing
on “Economists Seek Recession Cues in the Yield Curve,” published in the Wall
Street Journal on Apr 2, 2022, analyzes the inversion of the Treasury yield
curve with the two-year yield at 2.430 on Apr 1, 2022, above the ten-year yield
at 2.374. Hilsenrath argues that inversion appears to signal recession in market
analysis but not in alternative Fed approach.
Chart CPI-H provides 12-month percentage changes of the
consumer price index of the United States with 8.6 percent in May 2022, which
is the highest since 8.9 percent in Dec 1981, followed by the second highest of
8.5 percent in Mar 2022 and the third highest of 8.4 percent in Jan 1982.
Chart CPI-H, US, Consumer
Price Index, 12-Month Percentage Change, NSA, 1981-2022
Source: US Bureau of Labor
Statistics https://www.bls.gov/cpi/data.htm
Chart VII-4 of the Energy Information
Administration provides the price of the Natural Gas Futures Contract
increasing from $2.581 on Jan 4, 2021 to $7.189 per million Btu on Jun 14, 2022
or 178.5 percent. The Natural Gas Continuous Contract NG00 at Nymes settled at
$6.228 on Jun 23, 2022. Several U.S. Energy Information Administration
product releases scheduled for the week of June 20, 2022, will be delayed as
a result of systems issues. (https://www.eia.gov/).
Chart VII-4, US, Natural Gas
Futures Contract 1
Source: US Energy Information
Administration
https://www.eia.gov/dnav/ng/hist/rngc1d.htm
Chart VII-5 of the US Energy Administration provides US field production
of oil decreasing from a peak of 12,966 thousand barrels per day in Nov 2019 to
the final point of 11.655 thousand barrels per day in Mar 2022.
Chart VII-5, US, US, Field Production
of Crude Oil, Thousand Barrels Per Day
Source: US Energy Information
Administration
https://www.eia.gov/dnav/pet/hist/LeafHandler.ashx?n=PET&s=MCRFPUS2&f=M
Chart VI-6 of the US Energy Information
Administration provides imports of crude oil. Imports increased from 245,369
thousand barrels per day in Jan 2021 to 252,916 thousand in Jan 2022,
increasing to 262.282 in Mar 2022.
Chart VII-6, US, US, Imports
of Crude Oil and Petroleum Products, Thousand Barrels
Source: US Energy Information
Administration
https://www.eia.gov/dnav/pet/hist/LeafHandler.ashx?n=PET&s=MTTIMUS1&f=M
Chart VI-7 of
the EIA provides US Petroleum Consumption, Production, Imports, Exports and Net
Imports 1950-2020. There was sharp increase in production in the final segment
that reached consumption in 2020.
Chart VI-7, US
Petroleum Consumption, Production, Imports, Exports and Net Imports 1950-2020,
Million Barrels Per Day
https://www.eia.gov/energyexplained/oil-and-petroleum-products/imports-and-exports.php
Chart VI-8 provides the US
average retail price of electricity at 12.78 cents per kilowatthour in Dec 2020
increasing to 14.47 cents per kilowatthour in Mar 2022 or 13.2 per cent.
Chart VI-8, US
Average Retail Price of Electricity, Monthly, Cents per Kilowatthour,
Chart VII-9
provides the fed funds rate and Three Months, Two-Year and Ten-Year Treasury
Constant Maturity Yields. Unconventional monetary policy of near zero interest
rates is typically followed by financial and economic stress with sharp
increases in interest rates.
Chart VII-9, US Fed Funds
Rate and Three-Month, Two-Year and Ten-Year Treasury Constant Maturity Yields,
Jan 2, 1994 to Jun 23, 2022
Source: Federal Reserve Board
of the Federal Reserve System
https://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/
Chart VI-14
provides the overnight fed funds rate, the yield of the 10-year Treasury
constant maturity bond, the yield of the 30-year constant maturity bond and the
conventional mortgage rate from Jan 1991 to Dec 1996. In Jan 1991, the fed
funds rate was 6.91 percent, the 10-year Treasury yield 8.09 percent, the
30-year Treasury yield 8.27 percent and the conventional mortgage rate 9.64
percent. Before monetary policy tightening in Oct 1993, the rates and yields
were 2.99 percent for the fed funds, 5.33 percent for the 10-year Treasury,
5.94 for the 30-year Treasury and 6.83 percent for the conventional mortgage
rate. After tightening in Nov 1994, the rates and yields were 5.29 percent for
the fed funds rate, 7.96 percent for the 10-year Treasury, 8.08 percent for the
30-year Treasury and 9.17 percent for the conventional mortgage rate.
Chart VI-14,
US, Overnight Fed Funds Rate, 10-Year Treasury Constant Maturity, 30-Year
Treasury Constant Maturity and Conventional Mortgage Rate, Monthly, Jan 1991 to
Dec 1996
Source: Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/update/
Chart VI-15 of
the Bureau of Labor Statistics provides the all items consumer price index from
Jan 1991 to Dec 1996. There does not appear acceleration of consumer prices
requiring aggressive tightening.
Chart VI-15,
US, Consumer Price Index All Items, Jan 1991 to Dec 1996
Source: Bureau
of Labor Statistics
https://www.bls.gov/cpi/data.htm
Chart IV-16 of
the Bureau of Labor Statistics provides 12-month percentage changes of the all
items consumer price index from Jan 1991 to Dec 1996. Inflation collapsed
during the recession from Jul 1990 (III) and Mar 1991 (I) and the end of the
Kuwait War on Feb 25, 1991 that stabilized world oil markets. CPI inflation
remained almost the same and there is no valid counterfactual that inflation
would have been higher without monetary policy tightening because of the long lag
in effect of monetary policy on inflation (see Culbertson 1960, 1961, Friedman
1961, Batini and Nelson 2002, Romer and Romer 2004). Policy tightening had
adverse collateral effects in the form of emerging market crises in Mexico and
Argentina and fixed income markets worldwide.
Chart VI-16,
US, Consumer Price Index All Items, Twelve-Month Percentage Change, Jan 1991 to
Dec 1996
Source: Bureau
of Labor Statistics
https://www.bls.gov/cpi/data.htm
In his classic
restatement of the Keynesian demand function in terms of “liquidity preference
as behavior toward risk,” James Tobin (http://www.nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economic-sciences/laureates/1981/tobin-bio.html) identifies
the risks of low interest rates in terms of portfolio allocation (Tobin 1958,
86):
“The assumption
that investors expect on balance no change in the rate of interest has been
adopted for the theoretical reasons explained in section 2.6 rather than for
reasons of realism. Clearly investors do form expectations of changes in
interest rates and differ from each other in their expectations. For the
purposes of dynamic theory and of analysis of specific market situations, the
theories of sections 2 and 3 are complementary rather than competitive. The
formal apparatus of section 3 will serve just as well for a non-zero expected
capital gain or loss as for a zero expected value of g. Stickiness of interest
rate expectations would mean that the expected value of g is a function of the
rate of interest r, going down when r goes down and rising when r goes up. In
addition to the rotation of the opportunity locus due to a change in r itself,
there would be a further rotation in the same direction due to the accompanying
change in the expected capital gain or loss. At low interest rates
expectation of capital loss may push the opportunity locus into the negative
quadrant, so that the optimal position is clearly no consols, all cash. At
the other extreme, expectation of capital gain at high interest rates would
increase sharply the slope of the opportunity locus and the frequency of no
cash, all consols positions, like that of Figure 3.3. The stickier the
investor's expectations, the more sensitive his demand for cash will be to
changes in the rate of interest (emphasis added).”
Tobin (1969)
provides more elegant, complete analysis of portfolio allocation in a general
equilibrium model. The major point is equally clear in a portfolio consisting
of only cash balances and a perpetuity or consol. Let g be the capital
gain, r the rate of interest on the consol and re the
expected rate of interest. The rates are expressed as proportions. The price of
the consol is the inverse of the interest rate, (1+re). Thus,
g = [(r/re) – 1]. The critical analysis of
Tobin is that at extremely low interest rates there is only expectation of
interest rate increases, that is, dre>0, such that there
is expectation of capital losses on the consol, dg<0. Investors move
into positions combining only cash and no consols. Valuations of risk
financial assets would collapse in reversal of long positions in carry trades
with short exposures in a flight to cash. There is no exit from a central bank
created liquidity trap without risks of financial crash and another global
recession. The net worth of the economy depends on interest rates. In theory,
“income is generally defined as the amount a consumer unit could consume (or
believe that it could) while maintaining its wealth intact” (Friedman 1957,
10). Income, Y, is a flow that is obtained by applying a rate of return,
r, to a stock of wealth, W, or Y = rW (Friedman
1957). According to a subsequent statement: “The basic idea is simply that
individuals live for many years and that therefore the appropriate constraint
for consumption is the long-run expected yield from wealth r*W.
This yield was named permanent income: Y* = r*W” (Darby
1974, 229), where * denotes permanent. The simplified relation of income and
wealth can be restated as:
W = Y/r
(1)
Equation (1)
shows that as r goes to zero, r→0, W grows without bound, W→∞.
Unconventional monetary policy lowers interest rates to increase the present
value of cash flows derived from projects of firms, creating the impression of
long-term increase in net worth. An attempt to reverse unconventional monetary
policy necessarily causes increases in interest rates, creating the opposite
perception of declining net worth. As r→∞, W = Y/r
→0. There is no exit from unconventional monetary policy without increasing
interest rates with resulting pain of financial crisis and adverse effects on
production, investment and employment.
Inflation and
unemployment in the period 1966 to 1985 is analyzed by Cochrane (2011Jan, 23)
by means of a Phillips circuit joining points of inflation and unemployment.
Chart VI-1B for Brazil in Pelaez (1986, 94-5) was reprinted in The Economist
in the issue of Jan 17-23, 1987 as updated by the author. Cochrane (2011Jan,
23) argues that the Phillips circuit shows the weakness in Phillips curve
correlation. The explanation is by a shift in aggregate supply, rise in
inflation expectations or loss of anchoring. The case of Brazil in Chart VI-1B
cannot be explained without taking into account the increase in the fed funds
rate that reached 22.36 percent on Jul 22, 1981 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/data.htm) in the
Volcker Fed that precipitated the stress on a foreign debt bloated by financing
balance of payments deficits with bank loans in the 1970s. The loans were used
in projects, many of state-owned enterprises with low present value in long
gestation. The combination of the insolvency of the country because of debt
higher than its ability of repayment and the huge government deficit with
declining revenue as the economy contracted caused adverse expectations on
inflation and the economy. This interpretation is consistent with the
case of the 24 emerging market economies analyzed by Reinhart and Rogoff
(2010GTD, 4), concluding that “higher debt levels are associated with
significantly higher levels of inflation in emerging markets. Median inflation
more than doubles (from less than seven percent to 16 percent) as debt rises
frm the low (0 to 30 percent) range to above 90 percent. Fiscal dominance is a
plausible interpretation of this pattern.”
The reading of
the Phillips circuits of the 1970s by Cochrane (2011Jan, 25) is doubtful about
the output gap and inflation expectations:
“So, inflation
is caused by ‘tightness’ and deflation by ‘slack’ in the economy. This is not
just a cause and forecasting variable, it is the cause, because
given ‘slack’ we apparently do not have to worry about inflation from other
sources, notwithstanding the weak correlation of [Phillips circuits]. These
statements [by the Fed] do mention ‘stable inflation expectations. How does the
Fed know expectations are ‘stable’ and would not come unglued once people look
at deficit numbers? As I read Fed statements, almost all confidence in ‘stable’
or ‘anchored’ expectations comes from the fact that we have experienced a long
period of low inflation (adaptive expectations). All these analyses ignore the
stagflation experience in the 1970s, in which inflation was high even with
‘slack’ markets and little ‘demand, and ‘expectations’ moved quickly. They
ignore the experience of hyperinflations and currency collapses, which happen
in economies well below potential.”
Yellen
(2014Aug22) states that “Historically, slack has accounted for only a small
portion of the fluctuations in inflation. Indeed, unusual aspects of the
current recovery may have shifted the lead-lag relationship between a
tightening labor market and rising inflation pressures in either direction.”
Chart VI-1B
provides the tortuous Phillips Circuit of Brazil from 1963 to 1987. There were
no reliable consumer price index and unemployment data in Brazil for that
period. Chart VI-1B used the more reliable indicator of inflation, the
wholesale price index, and idle capacity of manufacturing as a proxy of
unemployment in large urban centers.
Chart VI1-B,
Brazil, Phillips Circuit, 1963-1987
Source: ©Carlos Manuel Pelaez, O Cruzado
e o Austral: Análise das Reformas Monetárias do Brasil e da Argentina.
São
Paulo: Editora Atlas, 1986, pages 94-5. Reprinted in: Brazil. Tomorrow’s Italy,
The Economist, 17-23 January 1987, page 25.
I D Current US
Inflation. Unconventional monetary policy of zero interest rates and
large-scale purchases of long-term securities for the balance sheet of the
central bank is proposed to prevent deflation. The data of CPI inflation of all
goods and CPI inflation excluding food and energy for the past six decades does
not show even one negative change, as shown in Table CPIEX.
Table CPIEX,
Annual Percentage Changes of the CPI All Items Excluding Food and Energy
Year |
Annual ∆% |
1958 |
2.4 |
1959 |
2.0 |
1960 |
1.3 |
1961 |
1.3 |
1962 |
1.3 |
1963 |
1.3 |
1964 |
1.6 |
1965 |
1.2 |
1966 |
2.4 |
1967 |
3.6 |
1968 |
4.6 |
1969 |
5.8 |
1970 |
6.3 |
1971 |
4.7 |
1972 |
3.0 |
1973 |
3.6 |
1974 |
8.3 |
1975 |
9.1 |
1976 |
6.5 |
1977 |
6.3 |
1978 |
7.4 |
1979 |
9.8 |
1980 |
12.4 |
1981 |
10.4 |
1982 |
7.4 |
1983 |
4.0 |
1984 |
5.0 |
1985 |
4.3 |
1986 |
4.0 |
1987 |
4.1 |
1988 |
4.4 |
1989 |
4.5 |
1990 |
5.0 |
1991 |
4.9 |
1992 |
3.7 |
1993 |
3.3 |
1994 |
2.8 |
1995 |
3.0 |
1996 |
2.7 |
1997 |
2.4 |
1998 |
2.3 |
1999 |
2.1 |
2000 |
2.4 |
2001 |
2.6 |
2002 |
2.4 |
2003 |
1.4 |
2004 |
1.8 |
2005 |
2.2 |
2006 |
2.5 |
2007 |
2.3 |
2008 |
2.3 |
2009 |
1.7 |
2010 |
1.0 |
2011 |
1.7 |
2012 |
2.1 |
2013 |
1.8 |
2014 |
1.7 |
2015 |
1.8 |
2016 |
2.2 |
2017 |
1.8 |
2018 |
2.1 |
2019 |
2.2 |
2020 |
1.7 |
2021 |
3.6 |
Source: US
Bureau of Labor Statistics https://www.bls.gov/cpi/data
Chart I-12 provides the consumer price index NSA from 1913
to 2022. The dominating characteristic is the increase in slope during the
Great Inflation from the middle of the 1960s through the 1970s. There is
long-term inflation in the US and no evidence of deflation risks.
Chart I-12, US, Consumer
Price Index, NSA, 1913-2022
Source: US Bureau of Labor
Statistics https://www.bls.gov/cpi/data.htm
Chart
I-13 provides 12-month percentage changes of the consumer price index from 1914
to 2022. The only episode of deflation after 1950 is in 2009, which is
explained by the reversal of speculative commodity futures carry trades that
were induced by interest rates driven to zero in a shock of monetary policy in
2008. The only persistent case of deflation is from 1930 to 1933, which has
little if any relevance to the contemporary United States economy. There are
actually three waves of inflation in the second half of the 1960s, in the
mid-1970s and again in the late 1970s. Inflation rates then stabilized in a
range with only two episodes above 5 percent.
Chart I-13, US, Consumer
Price Index, All Items, 12- Month Percentage Change 1914-2022
Source: US Bureau of Labor
Statistics
https://www.bls.gov/cpi/data.htm
Table I-2
provides annual percentage changes of United States consumer price inflation
from 1914 to 2021. There have been only cases of annual declines of the CPI
after wars:
- World War I minus 10.5 percent in 1921 and minus 6.1
percent in 1922 following cumulative increases of 83.5 percent in four
years from 1917 to 1920 at the average of 16.4 percent per year
- World War II: minus 1.2 percent in 1949 following
cumulative 33.9 percent in three years from 1946 to 1948 at average 10.2
percent per year
- Minus 0.4 percent in 1955 two years after the end of
the Korean War
- Minus 0.4 percent in 2009.
- The decline of 0.4 percent in 2009 followed increase of
3.8 percent in 2008 and is explained by the reversal of speculative carry
trades into commodity futures that were created in 2008 as monetary policy
rates were driven to zero. The reversal occurred after misleading
statement on toxic assets in banks in the proposal for TARP (Cochrane and
Zingales 2009).
There were
declines of 1.7 percent in both 1927 and 1928 during the episode of revival of
rules of the gold standard. The only persistent deflationary period since 1914
was during the Great Depression in the years from 1930 to 1933 and again in
1938-1939. Consumer prices increased only 0.1 percent in 2015 because of the
collapse of commodity prices from artificially high levels induced by zero
interest rates. Consumer prices increased 1.3 percent in 2016, increasing at
2.1 percent in 2017. Consumer prices increased 2.4 percent in 2018, increasing
at 1.8 percent in 2019. Consumer prices increased 1.2 percent in 2020. Consumer
prices increased 4.7 percent in 2021 during fiscal, monetary, and external
imbalances. Fear of deflation based on that experience does not justify
unconventional monetary policy of zero interest rates that has failed to stop
deflation in Japan. Financial repression causes far more adverse effects on
allocation of resources by distorting the calculus of risk/returns than alleged
employment-creating effects or there would not be current recovery without jobs
and hiring after zero interest rates since Dec 2008 and intended now forever in
a self-imposed forecast growth and employment mandate of monetary policy.
Unconventional monetary policy drives wide swings in allocations of positions
into risk financial assets that generate instability instead of intended
pursuit of prosperity without inflation. There is insufficient knowledge and
imperfect tools to maintain the gap of actual relative to potential output
constantly at zero while restraining inflation in an open interval of (1.99,
2.0). Symmetric targets appear to have been abandoned in favor of a
self-imposed single jobs mandate of easing monetary policy even with the
economy growing at or close to potential output that is actually a target of
growth forecast. The impact on the overall economy and the financial system of
errors of policy are magnified by large-scale policy doses of trillions of
dollars of quantitative easing and zero interest rates. The US economy has been
experiencing financial repression as a result of negative real rates of
interest during nearly a decade and programmed in monetary policy statements
until 2015 or, for practical purposes, forever. The essential calculus of
risk/return in capital budgeting and financial allocations has been distorted.
If economic perspectives are doomed until 2015 such as to warrant zero interest
rates and open-ended bond-buying by “printing” digital bank reserves (http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2010/12/is-fed-printing-money-what-are.html; see Shultz et
al 2012), rational investors and consumers will not invest and consume until
just before interest rates are likely to increase. Monetary policy statements
on intentions of zero interest rates for another three years or now virtually
forever discourage investment and consumption or aggregate demand that can
increase economic growth and generate more hiring and opportunities to increase
wages and salaries. The doom scenario used to justify monetary policy
accentuates adverse expectations on discounted future cash flows of potential
economic projects that can revive the economy and create jobs. If it were
possible to project the future with the central tendency of the monetary policy
scenario and monetary policy tools do exist to reverse this adversity, why the
tools have not worked before and even prevented the financial crisis? If there
is such thing as “monetary policy science”, why it has such poor record and
current inability to reverse production and employment adversity? There is no
excuse of arguing that additional fiscal measures are needed because they were
deployed simultaneously with similar ineffectiveness. Jon Hilsenrath, writing
on “New view into Fed’s response to crisis,” on Feb 21, 2014, published in the
Wall Street Journal (http://online.wsj.com/news/articles/SB10001424052702303775504579396803024281322?mod=WSJ_hp_LEFTWhatsNewsCollection), analyzes
1865 pages of transcripts of eight formal and six emergency policy meetings at
the Fed in 2008 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/fomchistorical2008.htm). If there
were an infallible science of central banking, models and forecasts would
provide accurate information to policymakers on the future course of the
economy in advance. Such forewarning is essential to central bank science
because of the long lag between the actual impulse of monetary policy and the
actual full effects on income and prices many months and even years ahead
(Romer and Romer 2004, Friedman 1961, 1953, Culbertson 1960, 1961, Batini and
Nelson 2002). Jon Hilsenrath, writing on “New view into Fed’s response to
crisis,” on Feb 21, 2014, published in the Wall Street Journal (http://online.wsj.com/news/articles/SB10001424052702303775504579396803024281322?mod=WSJ_hp_LEFTWhatsNewsCollection), analyzed
1865 pages of transcripts of eight formal and six emergency policy meetings at
the Fed in 2008 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/fomchistorical2008.htm). Jon
Hilsenrath demonstrates that Fed policymakers frequently did not understand the
current state of the US economy in 2008 and much less the direction of income
and prices. The conclusion of Friedman (1953) that monetary impulses increase
financial and economic instability because of lags in anticipating needs of
policy, taking policy decisions and effects of decisions. This a fortiori true
when untested unconventional monetary policy in gargantuan doses shocks the
economy and financial markets.
Table I-2, US,
Annual CPI Inflation ∆% 1914-2021
Year |
Annual ∆% |
1914 |
1.0 |
1915 |
1.0 |
1916 |
7.9 |
1917 |
17.4 |
1918 |
18.0 |
1919 |
14.6 |
1920 |
15.6 |
1921 |
-10.5 |
1922 |
-6.1 |
1923 |
1.8 |
1924 |
0.0 |
1925 |
2.3 |
1926 |
1.1 |
1927 |
-1.7 |
1928 |
-1.7 |
1929 |
0.0 |
1930 |
-2.3 |
1931 |
-9.0 |
1932 |
-9.9 |
1933 |
-5.1 |
1934 |
3.1 |
1935 |
2.2 |
1936 |
1.5 |
1937 |
3.6 |
1938 |
-2.1 |
1939 |
-1.4 |
1940 |
0.7 |
1941 |
5.0 |
1942 |
10.9 |
1943 |
6.1 |
1944 |
1.7 |
1945 |
2.3 |
1946 |
8.3 |
1947 |
14.4 |
1948 |
8.1 |
1949 |
-1.2 |
1950 |
1.3 |
1951 |
7.9 |
1952 |
1.9 |
1953 |
0.8 |
1954 |
0.7 |
1955 |
-0.4 |
1956 |
1.5 |
1957 |
3.3 |
1958 |
2.8 |
1959 |
0.7 |
1960 |
1.7 |
1961 |
1.0 |
1962 |
1.0 |
1963 |
1.3 |
1964 |
1.3 |
1965 |
1.6 |
1966 |
2.9 |
1967 |
3.1 |
1968 |
4.2 |
1969 |
5.5 |
1970 |
5.7 |
1971 |
4.4 |
1972 |
3.2 |
1973 |
6.2 |
1974 |
11.0 |
1975 |
9.1 |
1976 |
5.8 |
1977 |
6.5 |
1978 |
7.6 |
1979 |
11.3 |
1980 |
13.5 |
1981 |
10.3 |
1982 |
6.2 |
1983 |
3.2 |
1984 |
4.3 |
1985 |
3.6 |
1986 |
1.9 |
1987 |
3.6 |
1988 |
4.1 |
1989 |
4.8 |
1990 |
5.4 |
1991 |
4.2 |
1992 |
3.0 |
1993 |
3.0 |
1994 |
2.6 |
1995 |
2.8 |
1996 |
3.0 |
1997 |
2.3 |
1998 |
1.6 |
1999 |
2.2 |
2000 |
3.4 |
2001 |
2.8 |
2002 |
1.6 |
2003 |
2.3 |
2004 |
2.7 |
2005 |
3.4 |
2006 |
3.2 |
2007 |
2.8 |
2008 |
3.8 |
2009 |
-0.4 |
2010 |
1.6 |
2011 |
3.2 |
2012 |
2.1 |
2013 |
1.5 |
2014 |
1.6 |
2015 |
0.1 |
2016 |
1.3 |
2017 |
2.1 |
2018 |
2.4 |
2019 |
1.8 |
2020 |
1.2 |
2021 |
4.7 |
Source: US
Bureau of Labor Statistics https://www.bls.gov/cpi/data.htm
Chart
I-14 provides the consumer price index excluding food and energy from 1957 to
2022. There is long-term inflation in the US without episodes of persistent
deflation.
Chart I-14, US, Consumer
Price Index Excluding Food and Energy, NSA, 1957-2022
Source: US Bureau of Labor
Statistics https://www.bls.gov/cpi/data.htm
Chart
I-15 provides 12-month percentage changes of the consumer price index excluding
food and energy from 1958 to 2022. There are three waves of inflation in the
1970s during the Great Inflation. There is no episode of deflation.
Chart I-15, US, Consumer
Price Index Excluding Food and Energy, 12-Month Percentage Change, NSA,
1958-2022
Source: US Bureau of Labor
Statistics https://www.bls.gov/cpi/data.htm
The
consumer price index of housing is in Chart I-16. There was also acceleration
during the Great Inflation of the 1970s. The index flattens after the global
recession in IVQ2007 to IIQ2009. Housing prices collapsed under the weight of
construction of several times more housing than needed. Surplus housing
originated in subsidies and artificially low interest rates in the shock of
unconventional monetary policy in 2003 to 2004 in fear of deflation.
Chart I-16, US, Consumer
Price Index Housing, NSA, 1967-2022
Source: US Bureau of Labor
Statistics https://www.bls.gov/cpi/data.htm
Chart
I-17 provides 12-month percentage changes of the housing CPI. The Great
Inflation also had extremely high rates of housing inflation. Housing is
considered as potential hedge of inflation.
Chart I-17, US, Consumer
Price Index, Housing, 12- Month Percentage Change, NSA, 1968-2022
Source: US Bureau of Labor
Statistics https://www.bls.gov/cpi/data.htm
ID Current
US Inflation. Consumer price inflation has fluctuated in recent months.
Table I-3 provides 12-month consumer price inflation in May 2022 and annual
equivalent percentage changes for the months from Mar 2022 to May 2022 of the
CPI and the core CPI. The final column provides inflation from Apr 2022 to May
2022. CPI inflation increased 8.6 percent in the 12 months ending in May 2022.
The annual equivalent rate from Mar 2022 to May 2022 was 10.5 percent in the
new episode of reversal and renewed positions of carry trades from zero
interest rates to commodities exposures with increasing fiscal imbalances; and
the monthly inflation rate of 1.0 percent annualizes at 12.7 percent with
oscillating carry trades at the margin. These inflation rates fluctuate in
accordance with inducement of risk appetite or frustration by risk aversion of
carry trades from zero interest rates to commodity futures. At the margin, the
decline in commodity prices in sharp recent risk aversion in commodities
markets caused lower inflation worldwide (with return in some countries in Dec
2012 and Jan-Feb 2013) that followed a jump in Aug-Sep 2012 because of the
relaxed risk aversion resulting from the bond-buying program of the European
Central Bank or Outright Monetary Transactions (OMT) (https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/pr/date/2012/html/pr120906_1.en.html). Carry trades moved away
from commodities into stocks with resulting weaker commodity prices and
stronger equity valuations. There is reversal of exposures in commodities but
with preferences of equities by investors. Geopolitical events in Eastern
Europe and the Middle East together with economic conditions worldwide are
inducing risk concerns in commodities at the margin. With zero or very low
interest rates, commodity prices would increase again in an environment of risk
appetite, as shown in past oscillating inflation. Excluding food and energy,
core CPI inflation was 6.0 percent in the 12 months ending in May 2022, 5.7
percent in annual equivalent from Mar 2022 to May 2022 and 0.6 percent in May
2022, which annualizes at 7.4 percent. There is no deflation in the US economy
that could justify further unconventional monetary policy, which is now
open-ended or forever with very low interest rates and cessation of bond-buying
by the central bank but with reinvestment of interest and principal, or QE→∞
even if the economy
grows back to potential. The FOMC is engaged in increases in the Fed balance
sheet. Financial repression of very low interest rates is constituted
protracted distortion of resource allocation by clouding risk/return decisions,
preventing the economy from expanding along its optimal growth path. On
Aug 27, 2020, the Federal Open Market Committee changed its Longer-Run Goals
and Monetary Policy Strategy, including the following (https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/review-of-monetary-policy-strategy-tools-and-communications-statement-on-longer-run-goals-monetary-policy-strategy.htm):
“The Committee judges that
longer-term inflation expectations that are well anchored at 2 percent foster
price stability and moderate long-term interest rates and enhance the
Committee's ability to promote maximum employment in the face of significant
economic disturbances. In order to anchor longer-term inflation expectations at
this level, the Committee seeks to achieve inflation that averages 2 percent
over time, and therefore judges that, following periods when inflation has been
running persistently below 2 percent, appropriate monetary policy will likely
aim to achieve inflation moderately above 2 percent for some time.” The new
policy can affect relative exchange rates depending on relative inflation rates
and country risk issues. On Mar 6, 2022, the FOMC increased interest rates with
the following guidance (https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20220615a.htm): “The Committee seeks to achieve
maximum employment and inflation at the rate of 2 percent over the longer run.
In support of these goals, the Committee decided to raise the target range for
the federal funds rate to 1‑1/2 to 1-3/4 percent and anticipates that ongoing
increases in the target range will be appropriate. In addition, the Committee
will continue reducing its holdings of Treasury securities and agency debt and
agency mortgage-backed securities, as described in the Plans for Reducing the
Size of the Federal Reserve's Balance Sheet that were issued in May. The
Committee is strongly committed to returning inflation to its 2 percent
objective.”
In his classic
restatement of the Keynesian demand function in terms of “liquidity preference
as behavior toward risk,” James Tobin (http://www.nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economic-sciences/laureates/1981/tobin-bio.html) identifies
the risks of low interest rates in terms of portfolio allocation (Tobin 1958,
86):
“The assumption
that investors expect on balance no change in the rate of interest has been
adopted for the theoretical reasons explained in section 2.6 rather than for reasons
of realism. Clearly investors do form expectations of changes in interest rates
and differ from each other in their expectations. For the purposes of dynamic
theory and of analysis of specific market situations, the theories of sections
2 and 3 are complementary rather than competitive. The formal apparatus of
section 3 will serve just as well for a non-zero expected capital gain or loss
as for a zero expected value of g. Stickiness of interest rate expectations
would mean that the expected value of g is a function of the rate of interest
r, going down when r goes down and rising when r goes up. In addition to the
rotation of the opportunity locus due to a change in r itself, there would be a
further rotation in the same direction due to the accompanying change in the
expected capital gain or loss. At low interest rates expectation of capital
loss may push the opportunity locus into the negative quadrant, so that the
optimal position is clearly no consols, all cash. At the other extreme,
expectation of capital gain at high interest rates would increase sharply the
slope of the opportunity locus and the frequency of no cash, all consols
positions, like that of Figure 3.3. The stickier the investor's expectations,
the more sensitive his demand for cash will be to changes in the rate of
interest (emphasis added).”
Tobin (1969)
provides more elegant, complete analysis of portfolio allocation in a general
equilibrium model. The major point is equally clear in a portfolio consisting
of only cash balances and a perpetuity or consol. Let g be the capital
gain, r the rate of interest on the consol and re the
expected rate of interest. The rates are expressed as proportions. The price of
the consol is the inverse of the interest rate, (1+re). Thus,
g = [(r/re) – 1]. The critical analysis of
Tobin is that at extremely low interest rates there is only expectation of
interest rate increases, that is, dre>0, such that there
is expectation of capital losses on the consol, dg<0. Investors move
into positions combining only cash and no consols. Valuations of risk
financial assets would collapse in reversal of long positions in carry trades
with short exposures in a flight to cash. There is no exit from a central bank
created liquidity trap without risks of financial crash and another global
recession. The net worth of the economy depends on interest rates. In theory,
“income is generally defined as the amount a consumer unit could consume (or
believe that it could) while maintaining its wealth intact” (Friedman 1957,
10). Income, Y, is a flow that is obtained by applying a rate of return,
r, to a stock of wealth, W, or Y = rW (Friedman
1957). According to a subsequent statement: “The basic idea is simply that
individuals live for many years and that therefore the appropriate constraint
for consumption is the long-run expected yield from wealth r*W.
This yield was named permanent income: Y* = r*W” (Darby
1974, 229), where * denotes permanent. The simplified relation of income and
wealth can be restated as:
W = Y/r
(1)
Equation (1) shows that as r goes to zero, r→0, W
grows without bound, W→∞. Unconventional monetary policy lowers interest
rates to increase the present value of cash flows derived from projects of
firms, creating the impression of long-term increase in net worth. An attempt
to reverse unconventional monetary policy necessarily causes increases in interest
rates, creating the opposite perception of declining net worth. As r→∞, W
= Y/r →0. There is no exit from unconventional monetary policy
without increasing interest rates with resulting pain of financial crisis and
adverse effects on production, investment and employment.
Table I-3, US,
Consumer Price Index Percentage Changes 12 months NSA and Annual Equivalent ∆%
|
% RI |
∆% 12 Months
May 2022/May |
∆% Annual
Equivalent Mar 2022 to May 2022 SA |
∆% May
2022/Apr 2022 SA |
CPI All Items |
100.000 |
8.6 |
10.5 |
1.1 |
CPI ex Food
and Energy |
78.324 |
6.0 |
6.2 |
0.6 |
% RI: Percent
Relative Importance
Source: US
Bureau of Labor Statistics https://www.bls.gov/cpi/
Table
I-4 provides relative important components of the consumer price index. The
relative important weights for May 2022 are in Table I-3.
Table I-4, US,
Relative Importance, 2009-2010 Weights, of Components in the Consumer Price
Index, US City Average, Dec 2012
All Items |
100.000 |
Food and
Beverages |
15.261 |
Food |
14.312 |
Food
at home |
8.898 |
Food
away from home |
5.713 |
Housing |
41.021 |
Shelter |
31.681 |
Rent
of primary residence |
6.545 |
Owners’ equivalent rent |
22.622 |
Apparel |
3.564 |
Transportation |
16.846 |
Private Transportation |
15.657 |
New
vehicles |
3.189 |
Used
cars and trucks |
1.844 |
Motor
fuel |
5.462 |
Gasoline |
5.274 |
Medical Care |
7.163 |
Medical care commodities |
1.714 |
Medical care services |
5.448 |
Recreation |
5.990 |
Education and
Communication |
6.779 |
Other Goods
and Services |
3.376 |
Refers to all
urban consumers, covering approximately 87 percent of the US population (see http://www.bls.gov/cpi/cpiovrvw.htm#item1). Source: US
Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/cpi/cpiri2011.pdf http://www.bls.gov/cpi/cpiriar.htm http://www.bls.gov/cpi/cpiri2012.pdf
Chart
I-18 provides the US consumer price index for housing from 2001 to 2022.
Housing prices rose sharply during the decade until the bump of the global
recession and increased again in 2011-2012 with some stabilization in 2013.
There is renewed increase in 2014 followed by stabilization and renewed
increase in 2015-2022. The CPI excluding housing would likely show much higher
inflation. The commodity carry trades resulting from unconventional monetary
policy have compressed income remaining after paying for indispensable shelter.
Chart I-18, US, Consumer
Price Index, Housing, NSA, 2001-2022
Source: US Bureau of Labor
Statistics https://www.bls.gov/cpi/data.htm
Chart I-19 provides 12-month
percentage changes of the housing CPI. Percentage changes collapsed during the
global recession but have been rising into positive territory in 2011 and
2012-2013 but with the rate declining and then increasing into 2014. There is
decrease into 2015 followed by stability and marginal increase in 2016-2019
followed by initial decline in the global recession, with output in the US
reaching a high in Feb 2020 (https://www.nber.org/research/data/us-business-cycle-expansions-and-contractions), in the lockdown of economic
activity in the COVID-19 event and the through in Apr 2020 (https://www.nber.org/news/business-cycle-dating-committee-announcement-july-19-2021) with sharp recovery.
Chart I-19, US, Consumer
Price Index, Housing, 12-Month Percentage Change, NSA, 2001-2022
Source: US Bureau of Labor
Statistics https://www.bls.gov/cpi/data.htm
There
have been waves of consumer price inflation in the US in 2011 and into 2022 (https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2022/03/accelerating-inflation-throughout-world.html and earlier https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2022/02/us-gdp-growing-at-saar-of-70-percent-in.html) that are illustrated in
Table I-5. The first wave occurred in Jan-Apr 2011 and was caused by the
carry trade of commodity prices induced by unconventional monetary policy of
zero interest rates. Cheap money at zero opportunity cost in environment of
risk appetite was channeled into financial risk assets, causing increases in
commodity prices. The annual equivalent rate of increase of the all-items CPI
in Jan-Apr 2011 was 4.9 percent and the CPI excluding food and energy increased
at annual equivalent rate of 1.8 percent. The second wave occurred
during the collapse of the carry trade from zero interest rates to exposures in
commodity futures because of risk aversion in financial markets created by the
sovereign debt crisis in Europe. The annual equivalent rate of increase of the
all-items CPI dropped to 1.8 percent in May-Jun 2011 while the annual
equivalent rate of the CPI excluding food and energy increased at 2.4 percent.
In the third wave in Jul-Sep 2011, annual equivalent CPI inflation rose
to 3.2 percent while the core CPI increased at 2.4 percent. The fourth wave
occurred in the form of increase of the CPI all-items annual equivalent rate to
1.8 percent in Oct-Nov 2011 with the annual equivalent rate of the CPI
excluding food and energy remaining at 2.4 percent. The fifth wave
occurred in Dec 2011 to Jan 2012 with annual equivalent headline inflation of
1.8 percent and core inflation of 2.4 percent. In the sixth wave,
headline CPI inflation increased at annual equivalent 2.4 percent in Feb-Apr
2012 and 2.0 percent for the core CPI. The seventh wave in May-Jul
occurred with annual equivalent inflation of minus 1.2 percent for the headline
CPI in May-Jul 2012 and 2.0 percent for the core CPI. The eighth wave is
with annual equivalent inflation of 6.8 percent in Aug-Sep 2012 but 5.7 percent
including Oct. In the ninth wave, annual equivalent inflation in Nov
2012 was minus 2.4 percent under the new shock of risk aversion and 0.0 percent
in Dec 2012 with annual equivalent of 0.0 percent in Nov 2012-Jan 2013 and 2.0
percent for the core CPI. In the tenth wave, annual equivalent of the
headline CPI was 6.2 percent in Feb 2013 and 1.2 percent for the core CPI. In
the eleventh wave, annual equivalent was minus 3.0 percent in Mar-Apr
2013 and 0.6 percent for the core index. In the twelfth wave, annual
equivalent inflation was 1.4 percent in May-Sep 2013 and 2.2 percent for the
core CPI. In the thirteenth wave, annual equivalent CPI inflation in
Oct-Nov 2013 was 1.8 percent and 1.8 percent for the core CPI. Inflation
returned in the fourteenth wave at 2.4 percent for the headline CPI
index and 1.8 percent for the core CPI in annual equivalent for Dec 2013 to Mar
2014. In the fifteenth wave, inflation moved to annual equivalent 1.8
percent for the headline index in Apr-Jul 2014 and 2.1 percent for the core
index. In the sixteenth wave, annual equivalent inflation was 0.0
percent in Aug 2014 and 1.2 percent for the core index. In the seventeenth
wave, annual equivalent inflation was 0.0 percent for the headline CPI and
2.4 percent for the core in Sep-Oct 2014. In the eighteenth wave, annual
equivalent inflation was minus 4.3 percent for the headline index in Nov
2014-Jan 2015 and 1.2 percent for the core. In the nineteenth wave,
annual equivalent inflation was 3.2 percent for the headline index and 2.2
percent for the core index in Feb-Jun 2015. In the twentieth wave,
annual equivalent inflation was at 2.4 percent in Jul 2015 for the headline and
core indexes. In the twenty-first wave, headline consumer prices
decreased at 1.2 percent in annual equivalent in Aug-Sep 2015 while core prices
increased at annual equivalent 1.8 percent. In the twenty-second wave,
consumer prices increased at annual equivalent 1.2 percent for the central
index and 2.4 percent for the core in Oct-Nov 2015. In the twenty-third wave,
annual equivalent inflation was minus 0.6 percent for the headline CPI in Dec
2015 to Jan 2016 and 1.8 percent for the core. In the twenty-fourth wave,
annual equivalent was minus 1.2 percent and 2.4 percent for the core in Feb
2016. In the twenty-fifth wave, annual equivalent inflation was at 4.3
percent for the central index in Mar-Apr 2016 and at 3.0 percent for the core
index. In the twenty-sixth wave, annual equivalent inflation was 3.0
percent for the central CPI in May-Jun 2016 and 2.4 percent for the core CPI.
In the twenty-seventh wave, annual equivalent inflation was minus 1.2
percent for the central CPI and 1.2 percent for the core in Jul 2016. In the twenty-eighth
wave, annual equivalent inflation was 2.4 percent for the headline CPI in
Aug 2016 and 2.4 percent for the core. In the twenty-ninth wave, CPI
prices increased at annual equivalent 3.0 percent in Sep-Oct 2016 while the
core CPI increased at 1.8 percent. In the thirtieth wave, annual
equivalent CPI prices increased at 2.4 percent in Nov-Dec 2016 while the core
CPI increased at 1.8 percent. In the thirty-first wave, CPI prices
increased at annual equivalent 4.9 percent in Jan 2017 while the core index
increased at 2.4 percent. In the thirty-second wave, CPI prices changed
at annual equivalent 2.4 percent in Feb 2017 while the core increased at 2.4
percent. In the thirty-third wave, CPI prices changed at annual
equivalent 0.0 percent in Mar 2017 while the core index changed at 0.0 percent.
In the thirty-fourth wave, CPI prices increased at 1.2 percent annual
equivalent in Apr 2017 while the core index increased at 1.2 percent. In the thirty-fifth
wave, CPI prices changed at 0.0 annual equivalent in May-Jun 2017 while
core prices increased at 1.2 percent. In the thirty-sixth wave, CPI
prices changed at annual equivalent 0.0 percent in Jul 2017 while core prices
increased at 1.2 percent. In the thirty-seventh wave, CPI prices
increased at annual equivalent 5.5 percent in Aug-Sep 2017 while core prices
increased at 1.8 percent. In the thirty-eighth wave, CPI prices
increased at 2.4 percent annual equivalent in Oct-Nov 2017 while core prices
increased at 2.4 percent. In the thirty-ninth wave, CPI prices increased
at 3.7 percent annual equivalent in Dec 2017-Feb 2018 while core prices
increased at 2.8 percent. In the fortieth wave, CPI prices increased at
1.2 percent annual equivalent in Mar 2018 while core prices increased at 2.4
percent. In the forty-first wave, CPI prices increased at 3.0 percent
annual equivalent in Apr-May 2018 while core prices increased at 2.4 percent.
In the forty-second wave, CPI prices increased at 1.8 percent in Jun-Sep
2018 while core prices increased at 1.8 percent. In the forty-third wave,
CPI prices increased at annual equivalent 2.4 percent in Oct 2018 while core
prices increased at 2.4 percent. In the forty-fourth wave, CPI prices
changed at minus 0.4 percent annual equivalent in Nov 2018-Jan 2019 while core
prices increased at 2.4 percent. In the forty-fifth wave, CPI prices
increased at 4.5 percent annual equivalent in Feb-Apr 2019 while core prices
increased at 2.0 percent. In the forty-sixth wave, CPI prices increased
at 0.6 percent annual equivalent in May-Jun 2019 while core prices increased at
1.8 percent. In the forty-seventh wave, CPI prices increased at 2.4
percent annual equivalent in Jul 2019 while core prices increased at 2.4
percent. In the forty-eighth wave, CPI prices increased at 1.8 percent
annual equivalent in Aug-Sep 2019 while core prices increased at 2.4 percent.
In the forty-ninth wave, CPI prices increased at 2.8 percent annual
equivalent in Oct-Dec 2019 while core prices increased at 2.0 percent. In the fiftieth
wave, CPI prices increased at 1.8 percent annual equivalent in Jan-Feb 2020
and core prices at 3.0 percent. In the fifty-first wave, CPI prices
decreased at annual equivalent 4.7 percent in Mar-May 2020 while core prices
decreased at 2.4 percent. In the fifty-second wave, CPI prices increased
at 6.2 percent annual equivalent in Jun-Jul 2020 and core prices increased at
4.9 percent. In the fifty-third wave, CPI prices increased at annual
equivalent 3.7 percent and core prices increased at 3.7 percent in Aug-Sep
2020. In the fifty-fourth wave, CPI prices increased at 1.2 percent
annual equivalent and core prices at 1.2 percent in Oct 2020. In the fifty-fifth
wave, CPI prices increased at 2.4 percent annual equivalent in Nov 2020-Jan
2021 and core prices at 1.2 percent. In the fifty-sixth wave, CPI prices
increased at annual equivalent 6.2 percent in Feb-Mar 2021 and core prices at
3.0 percent. In the fifty-seventh wave, CPI prices increased at annual
equivalent 9.2 percent in Apr-Jun 2021 and core prices at 10.0 percent. In the fifty-eight
wave, CPI prices increased at annual equivalent 4.9 percent in Jul-Sep 2021
and core prices at 3.2 percent. In the fifty-ninth wave, CPI prices
increased at annual equivalent 10.0 percent in Oct-Nov 2021 while core prices
increased at 6.8 percent. In the sixtieth wave, CPI prices increased at
annual equivalent 8.3 percent and core prices increased at 7.0 percent in Dec
2021-Feb 2022. In the sixty-first wave, CPI prices increased at annual
equivalent 15.4 percent and core prices at 3.7 percent in Mar 2022. In the sixty-second
wave, CPI prices increased at annual equivalent 3.7 percent in Apr 2022 and
core prices at 7.4 percent. In the sixty-third wave, CPI prices
increased at annual equivalent 12.7 percent in May 2022 and core prices at 7.4
percent. The conclusion is that inflation accelerates and decelerates in
unpredictable fashion because of shocks or risk aversion and portfolio
reallocations in carry trades from zero interest rates to commodity
derivatives.
Table I-5, US,
Headline and Core CPI Inflation Monthly SA and 12 Months NSA ∆%
|
All
Items SA Month |
All Items NSA
12 month |
Core SA |
Core NSA |
May 2022 |
1.0 |
8.6 |
0.6 |
6.0 |
AE May |
12.7 |
|
7.4 |
|
Apr |
0.3 |
8.3 |
0.6 |
6.2 |
AE Apr |
3.7 |
|
7.4 |
|
Mar |
1.2 |
8.5 |
0.3 |
6.5 |
AE Mar |
15.4 |
|
3.7 |
|
Feb |
0.8 |
7.9 |
0.5 |
6.4 |
Jan |
0.6 |
7.5 |
0.6 |
6.0 |
Dec 2021 |
0.6 |
7.0 |
0.6 |
5.5 |
AE Dec-Feb |
8.3 |
|
7.0 |
|
Nov |
0.7 |
6.8 |
0.5 |
4.9 |
Oct |
0.9 |
6.2 |
0.6 |
4.6 |
AE Oct-Nov |
10.0 |
|
6.8 |
|
Sep |
0.4 |
5.4 |
0.3 |
4.0 |
Aug |
0.3 |
5.3 |
0.2 |
4.0 |
Jul |
0.5 |
5.4 |
0.3 |
4.3 |
AE Jul-Sep |
4.9 |
|
3.2 |
|
Jun |
0.9 |
5.4 |
0.8 |
4.5 |
May |
0.7 |
5.0 |
0.7 |
3.8 |
Apr |
0.6 |
4.2 |
0.9 |
3.0 |
AE Apr-Jun |
9.2 |
|
10.0 |
|
Mar |
0.6 |
2.6 |
0.3 |
1.6 |
Feb |
0.4 |
1.7 |
0.2 |
1.3 |
AE ∆% Feb-Mar |
6.2 |
|
3.0 |
|
Jan |
0.2 |
1.4 |
0.0 |
1.4 |
Dec 2020 |
0.3 |
1.4 |
0.1 |
1.6 |
Nov |
0.1 |
1.2 |
0.2 |
1.6 |
AE ∆% Nov-Jan |
2.4 |
|
1.2 |
|
Oct |
0.1 |
1.2 |
0.1 |
1.6 |
AE ∆% Oct |
1.2 |
|
1.2 |
|
Sep |
0.2 |
1.4 |
0.2 |
1.7 |
Aug |
0.4 |
1.3 |
0.4 |
1.7 |
AE ∆% Aug-Sep |
3.7 |
|
3.7 |
|
Jul |
0.5 |
1.0 |
0.6 |
1.6 |
Jun |
0.5 |
0.6 |
0.2 |
1.2 |
AE ∆% Jun-Jul |
6.2 |
|
4.9 |
|
May |
-0.1 |
0.1 |
-0.1 |
1.2 |
Apr |
-0.8 |
0.3 |
-0.4 |
1.4 |
Mar |
-0.3 |
1.5 |
-0.1 |
2.1 |
AE ∆% Mar-May |
-4.7 |
|
-2.4 |
|
Feb |
0.1 |
2.3 |
0.2 |
2.4 |
Jan |
0.2 |
2.5 |
0.3 |
2.3 |
AE ∆% Jan-Feb |
1.8 |
|
3.0 |
|
Dec 2019 |
0.2 |
2.3 |
0.1 |
2.3 |
Nov |
0.2 |
2.1 |
0.2 |
2.3 |
Oct |
0.3 |
1.8 |
0.2 |
2.3 |
AE ∆% Oct-Dec |
2.8 |
|
2.0 |
|
Sep |
0.2 |
1.7 |
0.2 |
2.4 |
Aug |
0.1 |
1.7 |
0.2 |
2.4 |
AE ∆% Aug-Sep |
1.8 |
|
2.4 |
|
Jul |
0.2 |
1.8 |
0.2 |
2.2 |
AE ∆% Jul |
2.4 |
|
2.4 |
|
Jun |
0.0 |
1.6 |
0.2 |
2.1 |
May |
0.1 |
1.8 |
0.1 |
2.0 |
AE ∆% May-Jun |
0.6 |
|
1.8 |
|
Apr |
0.4 |
2.0 |
0.2 |
2.1 |
Mar |
0.4 |
1.9 |
0.2 |
2.0 |
Feb |
0.3 |
1.5 |
0.1 |
2.1 |
AE ∆% Feb-Apr |
4.5 |
|
2.0 |
|
Jan |
0.0 |
1.6 |
0.2 |
2.2 |
Dec 2018 |
0.0 |
1.9 |
0.2 |
2.2 |
Nov |
-0.1 |
2.2 |
0.2 |
2.2 |
AE ∆% Nov-Jan |
-0.4 |
|
2.4 |
|
Oct |
0.2 |
2.5 |
0.2 |
2.1 |
AE ∆% Oct |
2.4 |
|
2.4 |
|
Sep |
0.2 |
2.3 |
0.2 |
2.2 |
Aug |
0.2 |
2.7 |
0.1 |
2.2 |
Jul |
0.1 |
2.9 |
0.2 |
2.4 |
Jun |
0.1 |
2.9 |
0.1 |
2.3 |
AE ∆% Jun-Sep |
1.8 |
|
1.8 |
|
May |
0.3 |
2.8 |
0.2 |
2.2 |
Apr |
0.2 |
2.5 |
0.2 |
2.1 |
AE ∆% Apr-May |
3.0 |
|
2.4 |
|
Mar |
0.1 |
2.4 |
0.2 |
2.1 |
AE ∆% Mar |
1.2 |
|
2.4 |
|
Feb |
0.3 |
2.2 |
0.2 |
1.8 |
Jan |
0.4 |
2.1 |
0.3 |
1.8 |
Dec 2017 |
0.2 |
2.1 |
0.2 |
1.8 |
AE ∆% Dec-Feb |
3.7 |
|
2.8 |
|
Nov |
0.3 |
2.2 |
0.1 |
1.7 |
Oct |
0.1 |
2.0 |
0.3 |
1.8 |
AE ∆% Oct-Nov |
2.4 |
|
2.4 |
|
Sep |
0.5 |
2.2 |
0.1 |
1.7 |
Aug |
0.4 |
1.9 |
0.2 |
1.7 |
AE ∆% Aug-Sep |
5.5 |
|
1.8 |
|
Jul |
0.0 |
1.7 |
0.1 |
1.7 |
AE ∆% Jul |
0.0 |
|
1.2 |
|
Jun |
0.1 |
1.6 |
0.1 |
1.7 |
May |
-0.1 |
1.9 |
0.1 |
1.7 |
AE ∆% May-Jun |
0.0 |
|
1.2 |
|
Apr |
0.1 |
2.2 |
0.1 |
1.9 |
AE ∆% Apr |
1.2 |
|
1.2 |
|
Mar |
0.0 |
2.4 |
0.0 |
2.0 |
AE ∆% Mar |
0.0 |
|
0.0 |
|
Feb |
0.2 |
2.7 |
0.2 |
2.2 |
AE ∆% Feb |
2.4 |
|
2.4 |
|
Jan |
0.4 |
2.5 |
0.2 |
2.3 |
AE ∆% Jan |
4.9 |
|
2.4 |
|
Dec 2016 |
0.3 |
2.1 |
0.2 |
2.2 |
Nov |
0.1 |
1.7 |
0.1 |
2.1 |
AE ∆% Nov-Dec |
2.4 |
|
1.8 |
|
Oct |
0.2 |
1.6 |
0.1 |
2.1 |
Sep |
0.3 |
1.5 |
0.2 |
2.2 |
AE ∆% Sep-Oct |
3.0 |
|
1.8 |
|
Aug |
0.2 |
1.1 |
0.2 |
2.3 |
AE ∆ Aug |
2.4 |
|
2.4 |
|
Jul |
-0.1 |
0.8 |
0.1 |
2.2 |
AE ∆% Jul |
-1.2 |
|
1.2 |
|
Jun |
0.3 |
1.0 |
0.2 |
2.2 |
May |
0.2 |
1.0 |
0.2 |
2.2 |
AE ∆% May-Jun |
3.0 |
|
2.4 |
|
Apr |
0.4 |
1.1 |
0.3 |
2.1 |
Mar |
0.3 |
0.9 |
0.2 |
2.2 |
AE ∆% Mar-Apr |
4.3 |
|
3.0 |
|
Feb |
-0.1 |
1.0 |
0.2 |
2.3 |
AE ∆% Feb |
-1.2 |
|
2.4 |
|
Jan |
0.0 |
1.4 |
0.2 |
2.2 |
Dec 2015 |
-0.1 |
0.7 |
0.1 |
2.1 |
AE ∆% Dec-Jan |
-0.6 |
|
1.8 |
|
Nov |
0.1 |
0.5 |
0.2 |
2.0 |
Oct |
0.1 |
0.2 |
0.2 |
1.9 |
AE ∆% Oct-Nov |
1.2 |
|
2.4 |
|
Sep |
-0.2 |
0.0 |
0.2 |
1.9 |
Aug |
0.0 |
0.2 |
0.1 |
1.8 |
AE ∆% Aug-Sep |
-1.2 |
|
1.8 |
|
Jul |
0.2 |
0.2 |
0.2 |
1.8 |
AE ∆% Jul |
2.4 |
|
2.4 |
|
Jun |
0.3 |
0.1 |
0.2 |
1.8 |
May |
0.3 |
0.0 |
0.1 |
1.7 |
Apr |
0.1 |
-0.2 |
0.2 |
1.8 |
Mar |
0.3 |
-0.1 |
0.2 |
1.8 |
Feb |
0.3 |
0.0 |
0.2 |
1.7 |
AE ∆% Feb-Jun |
3.2 |
|
2.2 |
|
Jan |
-0.6 |
-0.1 |
0.1 |
1.6 |
Dec 2014 |
-0.3 |
0.8 |
0.1 |
1.6 |
Nov |
-0.2 |
1.3 |
0.1 |
1.7 |
AE ∆% Nov-Jan |
-4.3 |
|
1.2 |
|
Oct |
0.0 |
1.7 |
0.2 |
1.8 |
Sep |
0.0 |
1.7 |
0.2 |
1.7 |
AE ∆% Sep-Oct |
0.0 |
|
2.4 |
|
Aug |
0.0 |
1.7 |
0.1 |
1.7 |
AE ∆% Aug |
0.0 |
|
1.2 |
|
Jul |
0.1 |
2.0 |
0.2 |
1.9 |
Jun |
0.1 |
2.1 |
0.1 |
1.9 |
May |
0.2 |
2.1 |
0.2 |
2.0 |
Apr |
0.2 |
2.0 |
0.2 |
1.8 |
AE ∆% Apr-Jul |
1.8 |
|
2.1 |
|
Mar |
0.2 |
1.5 |
0.2 |
1.7 |
Feb |
0.1 |
1.1 |
0.1 |
1.6 |
Jan |
0.2 |
1.6 |
0.1 |
1.6 |
Dec 2013 |
0.3 |
1.5 |
0.2 |
1.7 |
AE ∆% Dec-Mar |
2.4 |
|
1.8 |
|
Nov |
0.2 |
1.2 |
0.2 |
1.7 |
Oct |
0.1 |
1.0 |
0.1 |
1.7 |
AE ∆% Oct-Nov |
1.8 |
|
1.8 |
|
Sep |
0.0 |
1.2 |
0.2 |
1.7 |
Aug |
0.2 |
1.5 |
0.2 |
1.8 |
Jul |
0.2 |
2.0 |
0.2 |
1.7 |
Jun |
0.2 |
1.8 |
0.2 |
1.6 |
May |
0.0 |
1.4 |
0.1 |
1.7 |
AE ∆% May-Sep |
1.4 |
|
2.2 |
|
Apr |
-0.2 |
1.1 |
0.0 |
1.7 |
Mar |
-0.3 |
1.5 |
0.1 |
1.9 |
AE ∆% Mar-Apr |
-3.0 |
|
0.6 |
|
Feb |
0.5 |
2.0 |
0.1 |
2.0 |
AE ∆% Feb |
6.2 |
|
1.2 |
|
Jan |
0.2 |
1.6 |
0.2 |
1.9 |
Dec 2012 |
0.0 |
1.7 |
0.2 |
1.9 |
Nov |
-0.2 |
1.8 |
0.1 |
1.9 |
AE ∆% Nov-Jan |
0.0 |
|
2.0 |
|
Oct |
0.3 |
2.2 |
0.2 |
2.0 |
Sep |
0.5 |
2.0 |
0.2 |
2.0 |
Aug |
0.6 |
1.7 |
0.1 |
1.9 |
AE ∆% Aug-Oct |
5.7 |
|
2.0 |
|
Jul |
0.0 |
1.4 |
0.2 |
2.1 |
Jun |
-0.1 |
1.7 |
0.2 |
2.2 |
May |
-0.2 |
1.7 |
0.1 |
2.3 |
AE ∆% May-Jul |
-1.2 |
|
2.0 |
|
Apr |
0.2 |
2.3 |
0.2 |
2.3 |
Mar |
0.2 |
2.7 |
0.2 |
2.3 |
Feb |
0.2 |
2.9 |
0.1 |
2.2 |
AE ∆% Feb-Apr |
2.4 |
|
2.0 |
|
Jan |
0.3 |
2.9 |
0.2 |
2.3 |
Dec 2011 |
0.0 |
3.0 |
0.2 |
2.2 |
AE ∆% Dec-Jan |
1.8 |
|
2.4 |
|
Nov |
0.2 |
3.4 |
0.2 |
2.2 |
Oct |
0.1 |
3.5 |
0.2 |
2.1 |
AE ∆% Oct-Nov |
1.8 |
|
2.4 |
|
Sep |
0.2 |
3.9 |
0.1 |
2.0 |
Aug |
0.3 |
3.8 |
0.3 |
2.0 |
Jul |
0.3 |
3.6 |
0.2 |
1.8 |
AE ∆% Jul-Sep |
3.2 |
|
2.4 |
|
Jun |
0.0 |
3.6 |
0.2 |
1.6 |
May |
0.3 |
3.6 |
0.2 |
1.5 |
AE ∆%
May-Jun |
1.8 |
|
2.4 |
|
Apr |
0.5 |
3.2 |
0.1 |
1.3 |
Mar |
0.5 |
2.7 |
0.1 |
1.2 |
Feb |
0.3 |
2.1 |
0.2 |
1.1 |
Jan |
0.3 |
1.6 |
0.2 |
1.0 |
AE ∆%
Jan-Apr |
4.9 |
|
1.8 |
|
Dec 2010 |
0.4 |
1.5 |
0.1 |
0.8 |
Nov |
0.3 |
1.1 |
0.1 |
0.8 |
Oct |
0.3 |
1.2 |
0.1 |
0.6 |
Sep |
0.2 |
1.1 |
0.1 |
0.8 |
Aug |
0.1 |
1.1 |
0.1 |
0.9 |
Jul |
0.2 |
1.2 |
0.1 |
0.9 |
Jun |
0.0 |
1.1 |
0.1 |
0.9 |
May |
-0.1 |
2.0 |
0.1 |
0.9 |
Apr |
0.0 |
2.2 |
0.0 |
0.9 |
Mar |
0.0 |
2.3 |
0.0 |
1.1 |
Feb |
-0.1 |
2.1 |
0.0 |
1.3 |
Jan |
0.1 |
2.6 |
-0.1 |
1.6 |
Note: Core:
excluding food and energy; AE: annual equivalent
Source: US
Bureau of Labor Statistics https://www.bls.gov/cpi/
The behavior of the US
consumer price index NSA from 2001 to 2022 is in Chart I-20. Inflation in the
US is very dynamic without deflation risks that would justify symmetric
inflation targets. The hump in 2008 originated in the carry trade from interest
rates dropping to zero into commodity futures. There is no other explanation
for the increase of the Cushing OK Crude Oil Future Contract 1 from
$55.64/barrel on Jan 9, 2007 to $145.29/barrel on July 3, 2008 during deep
global recession, collapsing under a panic of flight into government
obligations and the US dollar to $37.51/barrel on Feb 13, 2009 and then rising
by carry trades to $113.93/barrel on Apr 29, 2012, collapsing again and then
recovering again to $105.23/barrel, all during mediocre economic recovery with
peaks and troughs influenced by bouts of risk appetite and risk aversion (data
from the US Energy Information Administration EIA, https://www.eia.gov/). The unwinding of the carry
trade with the TARP announcement of toxic assets in banks channeled cheap money
into government obligations (see Cochrane and Zingales 2009). There is sharp
increase in 2021 and into 2022.
Chart I-20, US, Consumer
Price Index, NSA, 2001-2022
Source: US Bureau of Labor
Statistics https://www.bls.gov/cpi/data.htm
Chart
I-21 provides 12-month percentage changes of the consumer price index from 2001
to 2022. There was no deflation or threat of deflation from 2008 into 2009.
Commodity prices collapsed during the panic of toxic assets in banks. When
stress tests in 2009 revealed US bank balance sheets in much stronger position,
cheap money at zero opportunity cost exited government obligations and flowed
into carry trades of risk financial assets. Increases in commodity prices drove
again the all-items CPI with interruptions during risk aversion originating in
multiple fears but especially from the sovereign debt crisis of Europe. There
are sharp increases in 2021-2022.
Chart I-21, US, Consumer
Price Index, 12-Month Percentage Change, NSA, 2001-2022
Source: US Bureau of Labor
Statistics https://www.bls.gov/cpi/data.htm
The trend of increase of the
consumer price index excluding food and energy in Chart I-22 does not reveal
any threat of deflation that would justify symmetric inflation targets. There
are mild oscillations in a neat upward trend.
Chart I-22, US, Consumer
Price Index Excluding Food and Energy, NSA, 2001-2022
Source: US Bureau of Labor
Statistics https://www.bls.gov/cpi/data.htm
Chart
I-23 provides 12-month percentage change of the consumer price index excluding
food and energy. Past-year rates of inflation fell toward 1 percent from 2001
into 2003 because of the recession and the decline of commodity prices
beginning before the recession with declines of real oil prices. Near zero
interest rates with fed funds at 1 percent between Jun 2003 and Jun 2004
stimulated carry trades of all types, including in buying homes with subprime
mortgages in expectation that low interest rates forever would increase home
prices permanently, creating the equity that would permit the conversion of
subprime mortgages into creditworthy mortgages (Gorton 2009EFM; see https://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/07/causes-of-2007-creditdollar-crisis.html).
Inflation rose and then collapsed during the unwinding of carry trades and the housing
debacle of the global recession. Carry trades into 2011 and 2012 gave a new
impulse to CPI inflation, all items and core. Symmetric inflation targets
destabilize the economy by encouraging hunts for yields that inflate and
deflate financial assets, obscuring risk/return decisions on production,
investment, consumption and hiring. There is sharp increase in 2021-2022.
Chart I-23, US, Consumer
Price Index Excluding Food and Energy, 12-Month Percentage Change, NSA,
2001-2022
Source: US Bureau of Labor
Statistics
https://www.bls.gov/cpi/data.htm
Chart
CPI-H provides 12-month percentage changes of the consumer price index of the
United States with 8.6 percent in May 2022, which is the highest since 8.9
percent in Dec 1981, followed by the second highest of 8.5 percent in Mar 2022
and the third highest of 8.4 percent in Jan 1982.
Chart CPI-H, US, Consumer Price
Index, 12-Month Percentage Change, NSA, 1981-2022
Source: US Bureau of Labor
Statistics https://www.bls.gov/cpi/data.htm
Both the US and Japan experienced high rates of inflation
during the US Great Inflation of the 1970s (see http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/05/slowing-growth-global-inflation-great.html
http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/04/new-economics-of-rose-garden-turned.html
http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/03/is-there-second-act-of-us-great.html and Appendix I The Great Inflation; see
Taylor 1993, 1997, 1998LB, 1999, 2012FP, 2012Mar27, 2012Mar28, 2012JMCB, http://www.johnbtaylor.com/ http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2017/01/rules-versus-discretionary-authorities.html
and earlier http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2012/06/rules-versus-discretionary-authorities.html).
It is difficult to justify unconventional monetary policy because of risks of
deflation similar to that experienced in Japan. Fear of deflation as had
occurred during the Great Depression and in Japan was used as an argument for
the first round of unconventional monetary policy with 1 percent interest rates
from Jun 2003 to Jun 2004. The 1 percent interest rate combined with
quantitative easing in the form of withdrawal of supply of 30-year securities
by suspension of the auction of 30-year Treasury bonds with the intention of
reducing mortgage rates. For fear of deflation, see Pelaez and Pelaez, International Financial Architecture
(2005), 18-28, and Pelaez and Pelaez, The
Global Recession Risk (2007), 83-95. The financial crisis and global
recession were caused by interest rate and housing subsidies and affordability
policies that encouraged high leverage and risks, low liquidity and unsound
credit (Pelaez and Pelaez, Financial Regulation after the Global Recession
(2009a), 157-66, Regulation of Banks and Finance (2009b), 217-27, International
Financial Architecture (2005), 15-18, The Global Recession Risk
(2007), 221-5, Globalization and the State Vol. II (2008b), 197-213, Government
Intervention in Globalization (2008c), 182-4). Several past comments of
this blog elaborate on these arguments, among which: http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/07/causes-of-2007-creditdollar-crisis.html
http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/professor-mckinnons-bubble-economy.html
http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/world-inflation-quantitative-easing.html
http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2011/01/treasury-yields-valuation-of-risk.html
http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2010/11/quantitative-easing-theory-evidence-and.html
http://cmpassocregulationblog.blogspot.com/2010/12/is-fed-printing-money-what-are.htm
Inflation and
unemployment in the period 1966 to 1985 is analyzed by Cochrane (2011Jan, 23)
by means of a Phillips circuit joining points of inflation and unemployment.
Chart VI-1B for Brazil in Pelaez (1986, 94-5) was reprinted in The Economist
in the issue of Jan 17-23, 1987 as updated by the author. Cochrane (2011Jan,
23) argues that the Phillips circuit shows the weakness in Phillips curve
correlation. The explanation is by a shift in aggregate supply, rise in
inflation expectations or loss of anchoring. The case of Brazil in Chart VI-1B
cannot be explained without taking into account the increase in the fed funds
rate that reached 22.36 percent on Jul 22, 1981 (http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/data.htm) in the
Volcker Fed that precipitated the stress on a foreign debt bloated by financing
balance of payments deficits with bank loans in the 1970s. The loans were used
in projects, many of state-owned enterprises with low present value in long
gestation. The combination of the insolvency of the country because of debt
higher than its ability of repayment and the huge government deficit with
declining revenue as the economy contracted caused adverse expectations on inflation
and the economy. This interpretation is consistent with the case of the
24 emerging market economies analyzed by Reinhart and Rogoff (2010GTD, 4),
concluding that “higher debt levels are associated with significantly higher
levels of inflation in emerging markets. Median inflation more than doubles
(from less than seven percent to 16 percent) as debt rises frm the low (0 to 30
percent) range to above 90 percent. Fiscal dominance is a plausible
interpretation of this pattern.”
The reading of
the Phillips circuits of the 1970s by Cochrane (2011Jan, 25) is doubtful about
the output gap and inflation expectations:
“So, inflation
is caused by ‘tightness’ and deflation by ‘slack’ in the economy. This is not
just a cause and forecasting variable, it is the cause, because
given ‘slack’ we apparently do not have to worry about inflation from other
sources, notwithstanding the weak correlation of [Phillips circuits]. These
statements [by the Fed] do mention ‘stable inflation expectations. How does the
Fed know expectations are ‘stable’ and would not come unglued once people look
at deficit numbers? As I read Fed statements, almost all confidence in ‘stable’
or ‘anchored’ expectations comes from the fact that we have experienced a long
period of low inflation (adaptive expectations). All these analyses ignore the
stagflation experience in the 1970s, in which inflation was high even with
‘slack’ markets and little ‘demand, and ‘expectations’ moved quickly. They
ignore the experience of hyperinflations and currency collapses, which happen
in economies well below potential.”
Yellen
(2014Aug22) states that “Historically, slack has accounted for only a small
portion of the fluctuations in inflation. Indeed, unusual aspects of the
current recovery may have shifted the lead-lag relationship between a
tightening labor market and rising inflation pressures in either direction.”
Chart VI-1B
provides the tortuous Phillips Circuit of Brazil from 1963 to 1987. There were
no reliable consumer price index and unemployment data in Brazil for that
period. Chart VI-1B used the more reliable indicator of inflation, the
wholesale price index, and idle capacity of manufacturing as a proxy of
unemployment in large urban centers.
Chart VI1-B,
Brazil, Phillips Circuit, 1963-1987
Source: ©Carlos Manuel Pelaez, O
Cruzado e o Austral: Análise das Reformas Monetárias do Brasil e da
Argentina. São Paulo: Editora Atlas, 1986, pages 94-5. Reprinted in:
Brazil. Tomorrow’s Italy, The Economist, 17-23 January 1987, page 25.
In his classic
restatement of the Keynesian demand function in terms of “liquidity preference
as behavior toward risk,” James Tobin (http://www.nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economic-sciences/laureates/1981/tobin-bio.html) identifies
the risks of low interest rates in terms of portfolio allocation (Tobin 1958,
86):
“The assumption
that investors expect on balance no change in the rate of interest has been
adopted for the theoretical reasons explained in section 2.6 rather than for
reasons of realism. Clearly investors do form expectations of changes in
interest rates and differ from each other in their expectations. For the
purposes of dynamic theory and of analysis of specific market situations, the
theories of sections 2 and 3 are complementary rather than competitive. The
formal apparatus of section 3 will serve just as well for a non-zero expected
capital gain or loss as for a zero expected value of g. Stickiness of interest
rate expectations would mean that the expected value of g is a function of the
rate of interest r, going down when r goes down and rising when r goes up. In
addition to the rotation of the opportunity locus due to a change in r itself,
there would be a further rotation in the same direction due to the accompanying
change in the expected capital gain or loss. At low interest rates
expectation of capital loss may push the opportunity locus into the negative
quadrant, so that the optimal position is clearly no consols, all cash. At
the other extreme, expectation of capital gain at high interest rates would
increase sharply the slope of the opportunity locus and the frequency of no
cash, all consols positions, like that of Figure 3.3. The stickier the
investor's expectations, the more sensitive his demand for cash will be to
changes in the rate of interest (emphasis added).”
Tobin (1969)
provides more elegant, complete analysis of portfolio allocation in a general
equilibrium model. The major point is equally clear in a portfolio consisting
of only cash balances and a perpetuity or consol. Let g be the capital
gain, r the rate of interest on the consol and re the
expected rate of interest. The rates are expressed as proportions. The price of
the consol is the inverse of the interest rate, (1+re). Thus,
g = [(r/re) – 1]. The critical analysis of
Tobin is that at extremely low interest rates there is only expectation of
interest rate increases, that is, dre>0, such that there
is expectation of capital losses on the consol, dg<0. Investors move
into positions combining only cash and no consols. Valuations of risk
financial assets would collapse in reversal of long positions in carry trades
with short exposures in a flight to cash. There is no exit from a central bank
created liquidity trap without risks of financial crash and another global
recession. The net worth of the economy depends on interest rates. In theory,
“income is generally defined as the amount a consumer unit could consume (or
believe that it could) while maintaining its wealth intact” (Friedman 1957, 10).
Income, Y, is a flow that is obtained by applying a rate of return, r,
to a stock of wealth, W, or Y = rW (Friedman 1957).
According to a subsequent statement: “The basic idea is simply that individuals
live for many years and that therefore the appropriate constraint for
consumption is the long-run expected yield from wealth r*W. This
yield was named permanent income: Y* = r*W” (Darby 1974,
229), where * denotes permanent. The simplified relation of income and wealth
can be restated as:
W = Y/r
(1)
Equation (1) shows that as r goes to zero, r→0, W
grows without bound, W→∞. Unconventional monetary policy lowers interest
rates to increase the present value of cash flows derived from projects of
firms, creating the impression of long-term increase in net worth. An attempt
to reverse unconventional monetary policy necessarily causes increases in
interest rates, creating the opposite perception of declining net worth. As r→∞,
W = Y/r →0. There is no exit from unconventional monetary
policy without increasing interest rates with resulting pain of financial
crisis and adverse effects on production, investment and employment.
© Carlos M. Pelaez, 2009, 2010, 2011, 2012, 2013,
2014, 2015, 2016, 2017, 2018, 2019, 2020, 2021, 2022.
No comments:
Post a Comment